The Origins, History, and Future of the Federal Reserve: A Return to Jekyll Island.
Newman, Patrick
The Origins, History, and Future of the Federal Reserve: A Return
to Jekyll Island Michael D. Bordo and William Roberds Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 2013, 439 pp.
Recently the Federal Reserve reached its one hundred year
anniversary This milestone provided a nice occasion for economists to
analyze the Fed's performance in the past century. As a result in
the past several years there have been many conferences, special journal
issues, and books that have centered on the Fed's centennial and
its record. The present book is a collection of essays from a 2010
conference dedicated to that task. The conference marked the centennial
of the famous Jekyll Island meeting (1910), a private gathering of U.S
government officials and bankers dedicated to the formation of a central
bank. It was significant because what came out it, the Aldrich Plan,
eventually became the body of the Federal Reserve Act. The 2010
conference, which was held in the same location as the 1910 meeting,
included many monetary heavyweights, such as Fed chairmen Ben S.
Bernanke, Alan Greenspan, and Paul A. Volcker along with Michael D.
Bordo, Charles W. Calomiris, Barry Eichengreen, Alan H. Meltzer, Ellis
W. Tallman, David C. Wheelock, Eugene N. White, and more. Anyone
interested in either monetary economics or macroeconomic history will
undoubtedly have heard of these names, as they have been very
influential in these fields.
The conference itself included three sessions of papers and a
concluding panel. The first session focused on the background of the
Federal Reserve and its initial impact The second session focused on
various parts of the Fed's track record in the past 100 years while
the third focused on its future The panel included a video presentation
by Paul Volcker and a discussion between Alan Greenspan, Ben Bernanke,
and Gerry Corrigan (former president of the Federal Reserve Banks of New
York and Minneapolis). Given my own interest and relative (yet meager)
expertise, I will concentrate this review on three papers presented in
the first two sessions as well as the comments to the papers. The first,
"'To Establish a More Effective Supervision of Banking':
How the Birth of the Fed Altered Bank Supervision" is by Eugene
White and is commented by Warren Weber, the second "The Promise and
Performance of the Federal Reserve as Lender of Last Resort
19141933" by Michael Bordo and David Wheelock and commented by
Ellis Tallman, and the third "Volatile Times and Persistent
Conceptual Errors: U.S. Monetary Policy 1914-1951" by Charles
Calomiris and commented by Allan Meltzer.
White's paper provides a useful economic history of the
National Banking System and the early Federal Reserve System from the
generally overlooked angle of bank regulation and supervision He
describes the pre-Fed regulatory apparatus, juxtaposes it with the
initial Fed changes, and concludes with a brief analysis of the New Deal
overhaul to the financial sector. The theses of the paper, as succinctly
put by Weber, are that the National Banking System's flaws were not
due to its regulatory framework and that the Federal Reserve System did
not substantially improve it The main defects of the pre-Fed era were
the prohibition on branch banking and the lack of a lender of last
resort central bank (to mitigate the "inelasticity" of
national bank notes). Although briefly mentioned by White (p. 32), I was
glad to see Weber emphasize another important flaw of the National
Banking System: the pyramiding of reserves among the different layers of
banks. (1) The "pyramiding," which referred to the fact that
many of the national banks could keep part of their legal reserves as
interest earning deposits in other banks (particularly central reserve
city banks in New York), allowed for a greater expansion of credit and
an undue concentration of reserves in New York The New York banks were
often heavily invested in call loans in the stock market, so when other
banks withdrew money from their New York balances it led to multiple
contractions of deposits and could cause financial pressure on the stock
market, which possibly led to (or exacerbated an already existing)
panic. (2)
Closures of national banks caused by the panics and other events
were surprisingly not very costly to the economy In fact, the costs hold
up very well compared to estimates of some of the notable disasters
during the Federal Reserve era. White estimates that the total losses
from national banks during the period 1865-1913 totaled roughly $44
million, or the equivalent of 0.3-0.6 percent of GDP. Compare this to
the 2.4 percent of GDP lost during the 1929-33 contraction, the 3.4
percent of GDP during the Savings and Loan crisis in the 1980s, or the
whopping 11.6 percent of GDP from the 2008-09 financial crisis.
Interestingly enough, the losses of the National Banking System compare
well to the losses of the "free banking era" (1838-60) which
totaled 0. 01 percent of GDP (p. 30). Given the even laxer regulation
and greater approximation (though by no means perfect) of the banking
system to a free market, this comparison suggests that an unregulated
banking system can do well in minimizing depositor and shareholder
losses.
This is not to say that White thought the panics that occurred
during the period had no major economic consequences. On the contrary,
White argues that they had severe macroeconomic effects and that the
pre-Fed era had greater volatility in various economic aggregates and
shorter expansions, although the lengths of recessions were similar.
Without getting into too much of a discussion on various modern
GDP/Industrial production estimates of macroeconomic performance in the
pre-Fed era, it can be argued that the evidence White provides is from
too small a sample (the late 1880s onwards, which includes the
particularly rough 1890s). A legitimate argument can be made that the
macroeconomic volatility and frequency and duration of recessions in the
entire pre-Fed era (e.g. after the Civil War) has been overstated, and
that the Federal Reserve has not noticeably improved economic
performance. (3)
The prohibition on branch banking caused by federal and state
legislation led to an uneconomical amount of small single
"unit" banks that were often undiversified in their loan
portfolios and artificially propped up from an absence of competition,
making them very susceptible to business failures and panics This, along
with the lack of a central bank, is what distinguished the U.S banking
system from other European countries. White also mentions the Canadian
banking system during this time, which allowed branch banking but did
not have a central bank until 1935 and did not suffer from bank runs and
panics. This leads White to cogently suggest that Congress' first
reform should have been to allow for branch banking and then worry about
the need for a lender of last resort The comparison also suggests that
perhaps a government-instituted lender of last resort was not needed at
all.
After discussing some of the changes brought by the Federal Reserve
with regard to moral hazard and regulation (such as the discount
window), White concludes by describing the New Deal regulatory overhaul
in the early 1930s. White argues that these changes were largely
harmful, and "the New Deal swept aside [the] successful regime and
imposed a radically different one that sharply increased moral hazard
and risk taking" (p. 45). The reforms were driven mainly by small
unit bankers and investment bankers and replaced the competitive market
environment with a "loosely organized government cartel" that
had many regulations on entry and pricing (p. 46). Many of these
regulations gave quasi-monopoly grants to banks and hampered economic
performance.
White notes that it took decades for all of the consequences of the
regulations to be shown, such as the moral hazard spurred on by the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). White briefly describes
the increased moral hazard brought by the FDIC through its termination
of the "double liability" policy, an old National Banking
System regulation that was imposed on shareholders in order to protect
depositors (pp. 24-25). A more general and widespread inducement to
moral hazard, however, was the main feature of the FDIC itself that
insured depositors up to a certain amount against bank failure. With
such a guarantee, depositors are less likely to monitor banks because
they know the government will cover some of their deposits if the bank
fails.
Bordo and Wheelock's paper also provides an analysis of the
National Banking era but concentrates more on the performance of the
Federal Reserve during its initial years (1914-33). They talk about the
rationale behind the founding of the Fed, which was to serve as an
effective lender of last resort to the banking system, and enumerate
reasons why they were unable to do so as envisioned by the creators of
the system, particularly during 1929-33. These include the conventional
reasons such as the system's decentralized structure, its harmful
allegiance to keeping the U. S dollar on the gold standard and its
execution of the "Riefler-Burgess" doctrine but also its
inability to recreate the essential features found in other European
central banks and defects in the discount window apparatus (p. 83).
Bordo and Wheelock document the steps taken in the drive for a U.S
central bank, such as describing the National Monetary Commission, the
Warburg plan, the famous meeting at Jekyll Island, the Aldrich bill
which was based off of that meeting, and the eventual Federal Reserve
legislation They properly state at the beginning that "the Federal
Reserve Act of 1913 resembled the Aldrich bill in many respects"
and later that "the act almost completely replicated the key
monetary and international policy provisions of the Warburg plan and the
Aldrich bill" (pp. 60, 71). However, they also write that the
Federal Reserve Act and the Aldrich bill differed largely in terms of
organizational structure. This seems to buttress the argument found in
the introduction to the book by Michael Bordo and William Roberds:
Over years, the clandestine nature of the meeting has often been
criticized as allowing undue Wall Street influence over the
founding of the U.S. central bank. However, the meeting itself was
just one step in the process that led to the creation of the
Federal Reserve, and many details of Aldrich's original design were
changed in the legislation that was eventually passed (p. 2).
The purported "differences" in the central bank systems
would seem to allow for a convenient agnosticism of the special interest
banking involvement in the legislation. From a historical perspective as
well as to answer the ever important question of "cui bono?"
or "who benefits?" from a piece of legislation, what matters
is that private bankers wanted to form a central bank to benefit
themselves and that their main plan formed the basis for the Federal
Reserve System (Rothbard, 1984, pp. 89-103). (4)
Bordo and Wheelock also take the standard interpretation of Federal
Reserve monetary policy during the 1920s. They largely follow Friedman
and Schwartz (1993) and say the Fed's performance largely avoided
the problems found in the National Banking System and that economic
activity and the price level were stable. Movements in Federal Reserve
credit were a matter of seasonal accommodation and more or less
automatic (p. 76). The interpretation provided by Friedman and Schwartz,
as well as later monetary historians, argues that the Fed's policy
can be seen as deflationary and neutral to the economy. This view might
be misleading overall because it can be argued that the Fed's
policy during this era should be viewed as inflationary and disruptive.
Movements in member bank reserves, which were mostly responsible for the
increase in the money supply, experienced three sharp jolts upwards in
1922, 1924, and 1927 and were caused by heavy purchases of government
securities and acceptances from the Federal Reserve. Changes in Federal
Reserve credit outstanding is an inaccurate measurement of Fed policy,
because it includes the uncontrolled factor of bills repaid into the
system. (5) One could also argue that the apparent stability of economic
indicators was merely an illusion and that the Fed's expansionary
policies promoted an economic boom that eventually burst at the end of
the decade. (6)
Another problematic interpretation of their 1920s analysis appears
when they discuss the defects of the discount window They say that one
of its weaknesses was that member banks were reluctant to borrow (p.
84). Despite the Fed's attempts to dissuade banks from borrowing
and "reminding" them that they were reluctant to lend, banks
did often borrow continuously from the Federal Reserve. I was glad to
see Tallman challenge them on this point and mention that member banks
were able to effectively borrow from the Federal Reserve (pp. 104-105).
Data found in White's paper also show that many banks in the 1920s
did borrow for profit for significant periods of time (p. 43).
Calomiris also reviews the early years of the Federal Reserve
(1914-51), but from a broader viewpoint and not specifically on the
lender of last resort policies as described in the previous essay The
bulk of the paper looks at five key issues concerning the late 1920s and
1930s that monetary economists have analyzed in recent decades. They
are: the Fed's involvement in the 1929 October stock market crash,
the apparent conflict between remaining on the gold standard and
expanding the money supply from 1929-33, Friedman and Schwartz'
classification of banking panics, the liquidity trap question in the
1930s, and the connection between the Fed's increase in reserve
requirements in the mid-1930s and the subsequent recession from 1937-38.
While all of Calomiris' discussion is very insightful, I will
concentrate on his points made in the first, third, and fifth topics of
interest.
Calomiris notes that in the stock market boom and bust, stocks more
than doubled in value amidst an explosion in technological innovation
that occurred throughout the 1920s. Opinions on the cause of the rise in
stock prices were mixed (including contemporary research) as some
thought that the high prices were based off of expectations of past
revenue growth and were sustainable, while others thought they were
symptoms of an unsustainable bubble that was not grounded in
fundamentals The Fed initially tried to deal with this through a policy
of "moral suasion," or attempting to restrict loans to banks
that would be made for speculative purposes while maintaining credit for
legitimate activity. This policy was abandoned in favor of one of
outright contraction at the end of the decade. Calomiris notes that
there is evidence on both sides for whether a bubble in stocks existed,
but seems to slightly hint that the growth in the market was sustainable
(pp. 187-188, 203).
While understandably not being mentioned in the essay, Austrian
business cycle theory (ABCT) sheds important light on the stock market
bubble question in the late 1920s. In a nutshell, this theory says
expansionary monetary policy by a central bank leads to a boom in
intensive capital goods industries that is unsustainable and inevitably
turns into a bust The rapid expansion in the stock market was simply a
reflection of the higher-order boom as stocks are titles to capital
goods And the growth in these capital goods industries was not based on
fundamentals, as their profitability was artificially exaggerated by the
increase in bank credit created by Fed policy. The October stock market
crash and subsequent downturn was not caused by tight monetary policy in
the late 1920s, but was a lagged adjustment to the downturn in those
industries which began earlier in the middle of 1929. (7) And the
downturn in those industries was caused by the end of the boom that the
Fed engineered throughout the 1920s. Rather than pinpointing the Federal
Reserve's mismanagement of monetary policy starting in the late
1920s, ABCT pushes the timeframe back to the early 1920s. (8)
With regard to the third issue, Calomiris challenges the view taken
by Friedman and Schwartz (1993) that the bank failures which gripped the
country in the early 1930s were nationwide panics driven mainly by
illiquidity (positive equity but not having enough reserves to meet
depositor withdrawals) and not insolvency problems (negative equity).
According to Friedman and Schwartz, there were four major banking panics
during this period: one in late 1930, two in 1931, and one from late
1932 to early 1933. Calomiris presents evidence which suggests that
these panics were not purely exogenous instances of illiquidity issues
and were more regional in nature (except for the last one). He notes
that the bank failures were a continuation of previous bank failures in
troubled agricultural regions in the prior decade, as roughly half of
the 15,000 bank disappearances between 1920-33 came from before 1930,
and there were high numbers of bank failures that occurred outside the
panics (pp. 192-197). Perhaps the most succinct statement of the issue
can be found earlier in the essay when Calomiris writes that "the
high bank failures of the early 1930s are best seen as a continuation of
the rural bank failures that had begun in the 1920s" (p. 180).
Calomiris concludes by saying "it is probably not correct to argue,
then, that the Fed failed to detect avoidable national liquidity crises
and prevent waves of bank failures in 1930 and 1931" (p.196). (9)
This insolvency analysis nicely fits in with what was argued by Vedder
and Galloway (1997, pp. 112-127), who state that the rigid wage policy
promoted by the Hoover administration led to a profit squeeze that
reduced the value of bank portfolios and caused worried customers to
withdrawal deposits.
Lastly, Calomiris argues that the Federal Reserve's increase
in reserve requirements from 1936-37 did not have a contractionary
effect on the economy and did not contribute to the recession of
1937-38, contrary to the views of Friedman and Schwartz (1993).
Calomiris writes that one must look elsewhere for an explanation of the
recession and suggests two explanations: the gold sterilization or
contractionary fiscal policies taken at this time. Another explanation
also deserves mentioning, namely the fact that the pro-union 1935
National Labor Relations Act (the "Wagner Act") was upheld as
constitutional by the Supreme Court in 1937, leading to an enormous jump
in wages that caused a rapid increase in unemployment and decline in
business activity. (10)
Overall, despite some of my criticisms, the essays in the book are
extremely well researched and important They are all sources of a wealth
of information about U. S economic history and they cite an impressive
amount of both old and contemporary research to buttress their
arguments. They provide up to date commentary on key macroeconomic and
monetary policy questions in contemporary research, and deserve to be
read by anyone interested in these fields. Readers will find that the
writers' arguments and the cited sources can be used for future
research and will want to be well acquainted with the papers.
REFERENCES
Bordo, Michael D., and William Roberds. 2013. The Origins, History,
and Future of the Federal Reserve. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Broz, J. Lawrence. 1997. The International Origins of the Federal
Reserve System. New York: Cornell University Press.
Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz. 1993. A Monetary History of
the United States Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Klein, John J. 1982. Money and the Economy. New York: Harcourt
Brace Jovanovich.
Miron, Jeffrey. 2012. "Comment on Selgin, Lastrapes, and
White's 'Has the Fed Been a Failure?'" Journal of
Macroeconomics 34, no. 3: 631-636.
Newman, Patrick. Forthcoming. "Expansionary Monetary Policy at
the Federal Reserve in the 1920s. " Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.
com/ abstract=2518261.
Rothbard, Murray. 2008. America's Great Depression. Auburn,
Ala. : Ludwig von Mises Institute.
--. 1984. "The Federal Reserve as a Cartelization Device: The
Early Years, 1913-1930. " In Barry N. Siegel, ed., Money in Crisis:
The Federal Reserve, the Economy, and Monetary Freedom. San Francisco:
Pacific Institute for Public Policy Research.
Salerno, Joseph. 2010. "Money and Gold in the 1920s and 1930s:
An Austrian View. " In Joseph Salerno, Money: Sound and Unsound.
Auburn, Ala : Ludwig von Mises Institute.
Selgin, George, William D. Lastrapes, and Lawrence H. White. 2012.
"Has the Fed Been a Failure?" Journal of Macroeconomics 34,
no. 3: 569-596.
Vedder, Richard K., and Lowell E. Gallaway 1997. Out of Work:
Unemployment and Government in Twentieth-Century America New York: New
York University Press.
Patrick Newman, (patrick.newm@yahoo.com) is a Ph.D. student in the
Department of Economics at George Mason University.
(1) This point was also described in greater depth in the second
essay by Bordo and Wheelock (pp. 64-66).
(2) For more, see Klein (1982, 180-182).
(3) For more, see Selgin, Lastrapes, and White (2012). However also
see Miron (2012) who challenges their conclusions.
(4) For a study that argues that the organization drive for the Fed
and its public benefits was made possible through additional private
benefits (particularly international) concentrated to New York bankers,
see Broz (1997).
(5) For more, see Rothbard (2008, pp. 85-167) and Newman
(forthcoming).
(6) On the "business cycle" consequences, see below.
(7) This is not to say that ABCT explains the severity of the
1929-33 downturn.
(8) For more on ABCT and its relationship to the 1920s, see
Rothbard (2008).
(9) It must be stressed though that Calomiris did not think there
were any illiquidity problems or that the Fed did the right policy in
the early 1930s, on the contrary, he argues that the Fed should have
vigorously expanded to prevent the money supply from failing.
(10) For more, see Salerno (2010, 437-38).