Jean-Baptiste Say: Revolutionary, Entrepreneur, Economist.
Dorobat, Carmen Elena
Jean-Baptiste Say: Revolutionary, Entrepreneur, Economist
Evert Schoorl
New York: Routledge, 2013, 210 pp.
The present volume is a full-length biography of Jean-Baptiste Say,
and presents a detailed account of the life and intellectual development
of the founder of the French Liberal School. The author studies three
important periods in Say's life--his youth, his activity as an
entrepreneur, and the later period of recognition of his work--which are
coincident with the French Revolution, the Industrial Revolution, and
the professionalization of economics respectively. Consequently, true to
its subtitle, the book describes Jean-Baptiste Say in all three facets
of his life and career--those of revolutionary, entrepreneur and
economist. (1)
A man of letters, Say's first job was that of secretary at an
insurance company. His employer, Ettiene Claviere, introduced him to the
writings of Adam Smith and to the fight against slavery. At the tender
age of 27, Say became co-editor of La Decade, a journal that wanted its
readers to participate "in a unity of culture and in a continued
cosmopolitanism." (p. 12) Schoorl rightly sees La Decade as
"an enlightenment organ" (p. 21) that had a significant impact
on Say's future writings, which were centered on "freedom,
universalism and progress." (p. 21)
The darkest period of Say's life is covered in chapters 4 to
7. After the publication of the first edition of his Traite
d'economie politique, Say was pressured by Bonaparte to
"rewrite certain freemarket parts in a more interventionist
vein." (p. 36) Say recalls in a letter: "Bonaparte commanded
me to attend him and offered me 40 thousand francs a year to write in
favour of his opinion. I refused, and was caught up in the purge of
1804." (p. 36) Father of four children, the 35 year-old Say had to
"go to the Conservatoire in order to learn [cotton] spinning"
(p.37), and later invested his capital in a factory in Auchy. But for
the next 15 years, his finances experienced a tremendous decline. In
1814, he hit rock bottom, and desperately tried to find a secure source
of income. Say wrote to his friends in the Talleyrand government,
begging for a job at the head "of the Post or at the head of public
works or customs," adding that "even if as a good disciple of
the Economistes, I hardly like customs; but well, we are not yet ready
for laissez faire and laissez passer." (p. 73) The French
government eventually offered him a commission in Britain, to spy on
their industrial development and report on the mechanization of farms,
on cotton spinning mills, sugar refineries and steamboats. This English
journey generated a small supplement to his finances, and occasioned his
first encounters with Ricardo and Mill.
However puzzling and inconsistent Say's attitude and decisions
during this time of his life, his biographer is kind enough to not judge
him too harshly. Say does not appear to have abandoned his laissez-faire
position though. In a letter to Jefferson dated also 1814, Say writes:
"I will admit that I am thinking seriously of settling [in America]
... feeling the need to breathe the air of a free country, and with
nothing but hope that France may be well governed ... " (p. 87)
Say's reputation--as well as his finances--experienced an
upturn and steady growth for the last 12 years of his life. The Traite
was published in six editions during his lifetime and was translated in
Germany, Great Britain, Italy and the United States. And while denied a
place in the Academie, Say was offered the chair of political economy at
College de France. The last decade of his life entailed a continually
rising popularity, national but especially international. It was marred,
however, by health problems and a pestering, suspicious government. John
Stuart Mill recalled Say as "a fine specimen of the best kind of
French Republican ... a truly upright, brave and enlightened man"
(p. 109), an opinion probably shared by most of Say's peers and
students.
This book focuses mainly on Say's life, but it is nevertheless
laced with interesting pieces of information pertaining to Say's
intellectual achievements. Chapters 10 and 11 of Schoorl's
biographical work focus on Say's economics, mapping both the
controversies that Say was involved in during his life and the ongoing
controversies about his writings and ideas, 180 years after his death.
The author nicely draws out several differences between the earlier and
later versions of Say's Traite--differences Say himself often noted
in his correspondence--that show the French liberal evolving as a
theoretical economist. The myth of Say as a simple popularizer of Smith
is refuted also by Schoorl, this time with evidence that Say himself was
aware of the detrimental effect of such opinions of his writings:
"Those who have accused me of only having made Smith's
principles more clear, have given me praise by this comment ... but they
have not rendered me justice." (p. 153)
Additionally, we find that the French economist, planning to
continue his father's dream of establishing a boarding school, was
also well aware of the importance of economic education for the
prosperity of a nation. Say noted in his first major work, Olbie, that
"[w]hoever writes an elementary treatise on political economy,
capable of being ... understood by all public bureaucrats ... by
countrymen and by artisans, would be the savior of the country."
(p. 25) His opinions on this matter were later shared by two of his
intellectual successors: Ludwig von Mises and Murray Rothbard.
While debunking several myths about the life and works of this
best-known French economist, Schoorl himself falls into some traps. For
example, he repeatedly refers to Say's method as positivist,
disregarding all evidence to the contrary presented by such writers as
Murray Rothbard and Joseph Salerno. Schoorl also fails to mention two
traditions in economics that were inspired by Say's works: the
French Liberal School--which dominated economic thought in France in the
19th century--and the Austrian School--which considers Say one of its
most important forerunners.
Though unwittingly, Schoorl does offer significant information
relevant to current research on the French Liberal School. For instance,
modern scholars will be interested to see how the disagreement between
Say and Ricardo on the "value riddle" meant in fact that
"Ricardo's theory of value was part of a paradigm altogether
alien to Say." (p. 94) At the time, the liberal school lost the
battle against "the objectivist Ricardian" school; but
hopefully the renewed interest in Say's work will soon reveal that
the "subjectivist Saysians" formed a sound tradition of
economic thought, unduly forgotten for too long.
Finally, it is worth pointing out that despite the tremendous
amount of useful information that will surely serve as basis for future
research, the present volume falls short of being a successful
biography. The chapters, albeit ordered chronologically, follow one
another abruptly and Say's life story is fragmented. The volume
reads much more like a collection of essays than a complete biographical
account of Say. In fact, Jean-Baptiste appears to be a stranger to his
biographer, although Schoorl devotes much of his scholarly work to the
French economist's writings. Unfortunately, Say remains a stranger
to the readers as well. Perhaps the intention was to let the evidence
speak for itself; but the result is a rather formal and apathetic
narrative, which fails to engage its readers in the manner in which good
biographies should.
Jean-Baptiste Say's revolutionary and unyielding spirit has
left its mark on his own life and on the history of economic thought. It
is important that his contributions be brought back to the attention of
modern scholars, as the debate with past and present Ricardian partisans
will prove to be a fruitful one. Hopefully then, this first biography of
Say in English will not be the only one.
(1) Although Schoorl's volume has been introduced to its
readers as the first biography of Jean-Baptiste Say, Institut Charles
Coquelin has published in 2005 an equally vast account on Say's
life and work. Charles Minart's book, Jean-Baptiste Say
(1767-1832): Maitre et pedagogue de l'Ecole frangaise
d'economie politique liberale was, however, written in French and
thus has benefited from a more limited audience. Nonetheless, it is a
first and fully developed endeavor to outline the life and political
economy of Jean-Baptiste Say through extensive excerpts of his works and
private correspondence, and to highlight the French economist's
continued relevance for the history of economic thought.
Carmen Elena Dorobat (carmen.dorobat@gmail.com) is a Ph.D.
candidate at the Ecole Doctorale DEGEST--University of Angers, and an
instructor in the Department of International Business and Economics at
the Bucharest Academy of Economic Studies.