The Federal Reserve and the Financial Crisis.
Howden, David
THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE FINANCIAL CRISIS
Ben S. Bernanke
Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2013, 134 pp.
Ben Bernanke, then chairman of the Federal Reserve System, gave a
series of lectures to students at George Washington University in 2012.
At the time, the American economy was amidst its weakest recovery of the
post-war period and the Fed was widely heralded as having averted a
second Great Depression. Bernanke's lectures focused on 1) the
origin and role of the Fed, 2) its performance in the post-War era
(conveniently excluding the Great Depression), 3) its policies and
performance in the lead up and as a response to the credit crunch of
2008, and finally 4) a review of its post-crisis performance.
There is trouble lurking in each of the book's four chapters.
The text gets off on a wrong foot as Bernanke overviews the origins and
purposes of the Fed. By Bernanke's reckoning, any central bank is
created to achieve stability in the economy (i.e., through low and
stable inflation and by avoiding economic swings), and in the financial
system, by preventing financial panics and freezes.
Where do such instabilities come from? Bernanke nonchalantly
attributes instability to the fact that "no bank holds cash equal
to its deposits" (p. 7). He does not refer to the possibility that
fractional reserves could breed broader instabilities, and in a bid to
underscore his point Bernanke notes that under the National Banking
System (1873-1914), banks did indeed regularly close their doors during
crises and panics. Recent research suggests that even though banking was
not especially stabilizing during this period, hamstrung as it was by
many onerous regulations, the Federal Reserve has fared far worse in
terms of both monetary and macroeconomic instability (Selgin, White, and
Lastrapes, 2012).
Not referencing the imperfections of the period prior to the Fed is
not too surprising given the sad state of historical knowledge amongst
economists. More serious is Bernanke's treatment of the Great
Depression, partly because his research of the period is what he was
best known for prior to becoming Fed chairman, and partly because it is
so misguided. In the lead up to the crash of 1929, Bernanke lists nearly
every fault possible in the global economy except a loose monetary
policy: an overhang from the World War I, nondescript
"problems" with the gold standard, a financial bubble and
contagion all figure prominently as causes of the downturn (pp. 19-20).
Recovery did not start until Roosevelt abandoned the gold standard in
1933, and deposit insurance was established in 1934. Similar to most
mainstream discussions of the Great Depression, there is little
attention paid on the pre-1929 period, nor is the thesis entertained
that the financial boom of the late 1920s was indicative of a lax
monetary policy, and a sign that deeper imbalances were being bred in
the real economy. The analysis is quite limited in comparison to, e.g.,
Rothbard (1963).
Reading the chapters dealing with the Fed's more recent
performance is the most frustrating part of the book. Bernanke fills
nearly 100 pages with reasons for the credit crunch of 2008; only once
does he concede that the Fed contributed to the instability leading up
to the crisis, or the severity of the crash.
"Psychology" played a big role in the increase in housing
prices (p. 42). Reduced lending standards and the proliferation of
nonprime loans allowed first-time buyers to enter the market who would
have been better off sitting on the sidelines (pp. 43-44). (He later [p.
113] mentions that credit scores on newly originated mortgages were not
lower during the housing boom, but does not explain how this squares
with the claim that lenders blindly pursued nonprime borrowers.) Credit
rating agencies were either wrong in their risk assessments or
manipulated to understate default risks (pp. 69-70). Insurers developed
and sold complex derivatives that bred instabilities (p. 70). There was
a lack of regulation and oversight (pp. 50-51). Only with this last
point does Bernanke concede that the Fed did not perform this role as
well as it could have and may have contributed to the crisis as a
result. But its failure in this regard was, according to him, endemic
under the former Fed Chair, Alan Greenspan, and not a failing during his
tenure at the Fed, going so far as to state that "when I became
chairman, we did undertake some of these protections but it was too late
to avoid the crisis" (p. 50). One gets the impression that Bernanke
thinks that if only he assumed the role a little sooner, a lot of pain
could have been avoided.
Bernanke spills much ink explaining research (from inside the Fed
or predominately written in association with the Federal Reserve) that
absolves the Fed of responsibility in causing housing prices to become
unhinged from fundamentals (pp. 52-54). This is not surprising coming
from the Fed's chairman. What is surprising is that he spends
almost as much time noting that the Fed's role in the housing
crisis is hotly disputed and that "this question [about the
relationship between monetary policy and housing prices] continues to be
debated" (p. 54, fn. 4). On the one hand, Bernanke goes out of his
way so many times to comment on the controversial nature of monetary
policy having no effect on housing prices that one doubts his sincerity
in making the claim. On the other hand, after the crisis the Fed pursued
monetary policies explicitly aimed at supporting asset prices, so there
can be little doubt that inside the Fed there is a belief that the
institution does affect certain assets, including housing.
As in many books, what is not written is as telling as that which
is. "Moral hazard" is not mentioned once. Bernanke does
mention "too big to fail," but not in depth or in the context
of the Fed promoting the problem (p. 86). Only when pressed by a student
during question period does Bernanke follow up on the idea, but only to
offer that the Fed's understanding of the problem is
"evolving" and more time is needed to sort out how large a
role it played in the crisis (p. 94-95). He does not mention the
prospect of unwinding the Fed's positions until pressed by another
student (p. 123), and just reiterates the standard line about reversing
the positions through the standard means without giving any attention to
the difficulties that will arise if its assets lose value or if the
banking sector does not demand them back. It seems to this reviewer that
exiting the most expansive monetary policy of the Fed's history is
as important to its success as enacting it. I would have liked to see
Bernanke voluntarily bring up the point and expand on it further.
Despite its shortcomings, there is one benefit to this book.
Because of its student audience, Bernanke explains clearly what his
thoughts are about the role of the Fed leading up to and during the
crisis. However misplaced and incomplete his thoughts may be, the
clarity of delivery gives merit to an otherwise lackluster book.
REFERENCES
Rothbard, Murray N. 1963. America's Great Depression, 5th ed.
Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2008.
Selgin, George A., William D. Lastrapes and Lawrence H. White.
2012. "Has the Fed Been A Failure?" Journal of Macroeconomics
34, no. 3: 569-596.
David Howden (dhowden@slu.edu) is chairman of the department of
business and economics and professor of economics at St. Louis
University-Madrid Campus.