Los Errores de la Vieja Economia.
Bagus, Philipp
Los Errores de la Vieja Economia
Juan Ramon Rallo
Madrid: Union Editorial, S.A., 2011, 319 pp.
The Austrian School of economics has provided the world with
devastating critics of Keynes's magnum opus The General Theory of
Employment, Interest and Money (TGT) for a long time. Friedrich A. von
Hayek, Jacques Rueff, Henry Hazlitt, Murray Rothbard, Ludwig Lachmann,
Ludwig von Mises, and William Hutt have already provided important
arguments against Keynes and Keynesianism.
Now we can add a new name to that distinguished list. In 2011, Juan
Ramon Rallo has published a new Austrian critique of TGT in Spanish with
the title Los Errores de la Vieja Economia (The Failure of the Old
Economics) in honor of Hazlitt's work The Failure of the "New
Economics."
In Hazlitt's time, Keynes's program was still
revolutionary and described by Hazlitt as a kind of "New
Economics" that broke with the insights of classical economics and
especially with Say's Law. Now, Keynesianism is mainstream.
Keynesianism, and especially its main idea that spending reduces
unemployment, is still taught in universities, applied by grateful
politicians, and prominently defended by the 2008 Nobel Prize winner
Paul Krugman.
Indeed, the immediate political response to the current financial
crisis in the Western World was inspired by TGT. A second Great
Depression was to be prevented and Keynes's insights applied.
Governments engaged in loose monetary policy combined with fiscal
stimulus in response to what, through Keynesian eyes, appeared to be a
bubble caused by reckless speculation, which was in turn inspired by
animal spirits. Thus, even if Rallo's book were just a summary of
the old arguments against TGT, the moment for publication would be more
than appropriate, since the ideas of the past are still the praxis of
the present.
Yet, Los Errores de la Vieja Economia is much more than a summary
and synthesis of the old arguments by the aforementioned Austrian
authors. Rallo builds upon, combines, and develops these arguments in a
systematic way. Most importantly, he adds his own innovative ideas to
develop a devastating case against TGT.
Rallo's critique of TGT employing Austrian theory is rigorous,
systematic and exhaustive. Significantly, Keynes's ideas are not
twisted or distorted. The absence of straw man arguments makes
Rallo's attack against the core of Keynesian beliefs stronger than
most. Rallo also does not search for terminological contradictions and
inconsistencies. In this sense, Rallo's critique is more profound
and devastating than, for example, the parts of Henry Hazlitt's
brilliant critique that emphasize Keynes's inconsistencies,
imprecision, and explanatory fuzziness. Rallo has a great and genuine
interest in giving a clear and coherent picture of Keynes's
reasoning and presents Keynes in the most favorable light.
Let us have a look of some of Rallo's arguments, beginning
with Keynes's famous critique of Say's Law. Keynes's
distorted version of Say's Law in TGT states that supply creates
its own demand. Rallo vindicates Say's Law in its original version:
In the long run, the supply of a good adjusts to its demand. Ultimately,
goods are offered to buy other goods (money included). One produces in
order to demand, which implies that a general overproduction is
impossible.
Say's Law leads us straight to the most innovative argument in
Rallo's book that addresses the old argument against hoarding. Even
harsh critics of Keynes, for example from the monetarist or neoclassical
camp, admit that Keynes was at least right in that hoarding is a
destabilizing and dangerous activity.
Rallo, however, proves and emphasizes the social function of
hoarding. To demand money is not to demand nothing from the market.
Hoarding is the natural response of savers and consumers to a structure
of production that does not adjust to their needs. It is a signal of
protest to entrepreneurs: "Please offer different consumer and
capital goods! Change the structure of production, since the composition
of offered goods is not appropriate."
In a situation of great uncertainty, it is even prudent to hoard
and not immobilize funds for the long run. Rallo provides us a visual
example. Let us assume that uncertainty increases because people expect
an earthquake. They start to hoard, i.e., they increase their cash
balance, which gives them more flexibility. This is completely rational
and beneficial from the point of view of market participants. The
alternative is to immobilize funds through government spending. The
public production of skyscrapers is not only against the will of the
more prudent people; it will also prove disastrous if the earthquake is
realized.
Hoarding is an insurance against future uncertainties. Rallo argues
that, if the demand for money increases (liquidity preference increases)
due to the precautionary motive, short-term market rates of interest
tend to fall, while long-term rates increase. People invest more short
term and less long term in order to stay liquid. This leads to an
adjustment of the structure of production. More resources will be used
for the production of the most liquid good (i.e., gold under a gold
standard), and for the production of consumer goods. The structure of
production shifts toward shorter and less risky processes, reducing
longer and riskier ones. Hoarding, therefore, does not cause factors of
production to be idle that should not be. Factors are just shifted
toward gold production and shorter-term projects. Rallo insists that it
is not irrational to hoard. Indeed, when long-term projects are
maintained and economic conditions change, projects might have to be
liquidated suddenly. For example, the earthquake would destroy the
skyscraper in progress.
It should be noted that most Austrians do not hold a hybrid
liquidity preference/time preference theory of interest. For Rallo the
interest rate, or the structure of interest rates, is determined both by
time preference and liquidity preference. Most Austrians defend the pure
time preference theory of interest. My own position on this question can
be found in "The Term Structure of Savings, the Yield Curve, and
Maturity Mismatching." (Bagus and Howden, 2010). Due to uncertainty
an actor prefers to be liquid rather than illiquid. Due to time
preference, an actor prefers to be liquid sooner rather than later.
Therefore, the yield curve tends to be upward sloping. When uncertainty
increases, the yield curve tends to get steeper. In a financial crisis,
however, another effect tends to prevail over this tendency. When
society is in general illiquid, the high demand for short-term loans,
the scramble for liquidity, tends to cause a downward sloping yield
curve.
Idle resources are another important topic in Rallo's book
since Keynes recommends inflation in the case of idle resources. Rallo
asks why factors are unemployed and comes to the conclusion that their
owners demand a price for their services that is higher than their
discounted marginal value product. In these circumstances, inflation
implies redistribution in favor of the owners of those factors, or a
frustration of attempts to restructure, i.e., the economy suffers from
forced saving or capital consumption.
In contrast, when factors of production adjust their prices, i.e.,
wages fall back to their discounted marginal value product, aggregate
demand does not fall as Keynes suggests. On the contrary aggregate
demand increases, because total production increases.
Rallo goes relentlessly after other Keynesian concepts. The famous
"investment multiplier" requires idle resources of all factors
of production. More precisely, for Keynes to be right we would need
voluntary unemployment of all factors of production plus idle capacity
in consumer goods industries. If there is no voluntary unemployment of
all factors, government stimulation of new projects will lead to
bottlenecks as factors are bid away from profitable investment projects.
If all types of factors are idle, but there is no capacity in consumer
goods industries, then government stimulus will raise prices of consumer
goods and lead to a shortening of the structure of production. If,
however, there is a general idleness of factors and idle capacities in
consumer goods industries, why is there no voluntary agreement between
owners of factors of production and entrepreneurs?
Another important Keynesian idea that Rallo tackles is the famous
liquidity trap. A liquidity trap exists when, in a depressed economy,
interest rates are very low. In such a situation Keynes regards monetary
policy as useless, because speculators will just hoard newly produced
money. Speculators will not invest in bonds because they are at maximum
prices and will fall when interest rates finally rise. At this point
monetary policy becomes impotent. Public spending becomes necessary to
stimulate aggregate demand.
Rallo shows that after an artificial boom, in a situation where
there are many malinvestments and a general over-indebtedness in the
economy, there is indeed almost no demand for loans even at very low
interest rates. We are actually faced with an illiquidity trap, as
agents struggle to improve their liquidity. They want to reduce their
debts and not take on more loans. The monetary policy of low interest
rates actually worsens the situation, because with low interest rates,
there is no incentive to prepay and cancel debts (because their present
value is raised). The solution to this situation of general uncertainty
is hoarding, stable institutions, the liquidation of malinvestment and
the reduction of debts.
High uncertainty does not imply high unemployment, since even under
high uncertainty the reduction of prices for services of factors of
production renders profitable new projects. Under high uncertainty,
these projects will be gold production (in a gold standard) and the
short-term production of consumer goods.
As Rallo points out in contrast to TGT, it is not aggregate supply
or aggregate demand that is important, but their composition. If, in a
depression with a distorted structure of production, in a liquidity trap
situation, aggregate demand is boosted by government spending, the
existing structure cannot produce the goods that consumers want most
urgently. The solution is not more spending and more debts, but debt
reduction and the liquidation of malinvestments to make new and
sustainable investments feasible.
In contrast, for Keynes, the problem is always insufficient demand.
So what can we do if consumers and investors do not buy the goods of
that companies offer, but instead hoard? Well, Keynes recommends
lowering taxes and interest rates, to devalue the currency, or that the
government buys the products for consumers. But, why, asks Rallo, should
consumers and investors buy goods they do not want?
Keynes's answer is that otherwise unemployment will increase.
Rallo responds astutely: But if a person is forced to buy with his
salary something that he does not want, why will this person work at
all? The alternative to forced buying is to lower wages to their
discounted marginal value product, which increases production and
demand. As Rallo points out, society does not get richer if the
government induces or forces people to buy goods they do not want. Thus,
for Rallo the essence of TGT is the following: when people do not want
to buy what is produced, the government should force them to act against
their will.
The insights from Rallo's book presented here are only a small
selection. Rallo also offers an analysis of Keynes's main
definitions and the theoretical errors behind them, such as their
proconsumption bias. He provides an Austrian analysis of financial
markets, discussing the interrelations between the yield curve, interest
rates, the discount rate, the structure of investment, the liquidity
trap and the stock market. He analyzes real and nominal wages, business
cycles, political implications, and intellectual predecessors of
Keynes's TGT using Austrian theory. Also very useful is
Rallo's guide for readers of TGT that makes reading and spotting
Keynes's main mistakes, chapter by chapter, easy and efficient. As
a plus, at the end of the book, Rallo also provides a critique of the
IS-LM model developed by John Hicks and Franco Modigliani which
formalized Keynes's theory and is still taught at universities
around the world.
Rallo's book on Keynes's TGT is full of brilliant
insights and provides the most powerful and complete case against Keynes
currently available. The well-written Los Errores de la Vieja Economia
will be the future reference for scholars and laymen alike looking for
errors in Keynes's thinking and today's policies. The main
downside of the book is that it is written in Spanish. Hopefully, the
work will be available in other languages soon.
REFERENCES
Bagus, Philipp, and David Howden. 2010. "The Term Structure of
Savings, the Yield Curve, and Maturity Mismatching." Quarterly
Journal of Austrian Economics 13, no. 3: 64--85.
Philipp Bagus (philipp.bagus@urjc.es) is Professor of Economics at
the Universidad Rey Juan Carlos, Madrid, Spain.