Antifragile: Things that Gain from Disorder.
Howden, David
ANTIFRAGILE: THINGS THAT GAIN
FROM DISORDER
NASSIM NICHOLAS TALEB
NEW YORK: RANDOM HOUSE, 2012, 519 PP.
No two buzzwords define the present crisis more than contagion and
robustness in the world of economists and policy wonks. The current
interrelated nature of the financial system has bred a fragile situation
where the success of the greater economy supposedly hinges on its
individual components, such as banks that are too big to fail. To combat
this fragility, economists have increasingly sought to build robust
institutions. Such institutions will remain strong in the face of
adverse effects if an individual component of the economy fails--be it
subprime mortgages, sovereign debt, deposit-taking institutions or
investment banks. This prevailing approach to the crisis stresses that
if we cannot battle contagion, we had better construct strong
institutions to weather future storms.
Nassim Taleb takes great issue with this approach in his new book
Antifragile. His view is that constructing such so-called robust
institutions is not sufficient as it continually fights yesterday's
battle. Instead the focus should be in building "antifragile"
institutions. Although often confused with robustness or resilience, an
antifragile institution is not only unharmed by adverse events, but is
actually strengthened by them. Building antifragile institutions will
not only strengthen the global economic arena, but also has wide-ranging
social applications.
Taleb's latest work builds on two of his previous works,
Fooled by Randomness (2001) and The Black Swan (2007). The common theme
underlying all three books is that there are events which are
fundamentally unknowable--true uncertainties--in distinction to merely
risky outcomes. Since we cannot know in advance what these events are,
or what their effects will be, we should not exert too much effort in
constructing contingency plans.
It is at this point that my first quibble with the book arises, and
one it shares in common with its predecessor The Black Swan. Taleb
bifurcates between two definitions of uncertain events. On the one hand
he invokes random or fundamentally unknowable events. Readers of this
journal will be sympathetic to this definition of uncertainty, bearing
close resemblance to Mises's own use of "case
probabilities" (1949, pp. 110-113), or Shackle's (1949) use of
"nonseriable, non-divisible" events. On the other hand, it is
also clear that Taleb also thinks of uncertain events as merely rare
events. These are events located on the fat or long tails on a
probability distribution. Even though he thinks that these represent
true uncertainty, there is no doubt that he is referring to
fundamentally probabilistic events.
This quibble aside, one can apply much of the remaining work
cognizant that Taleb's terminology differs from that of the
Austrian economists, and also that the domain of his theory is slightly
different than he thinks.
Something is "antifragile" if it gets stronger from a
negative event. What are some examples? Taleb applies the prefix of his
book liberally to outline what choices we should be pursuing. Indeed,
the body of the book gives a long list of antifragile actions that, at
least on one level, boil down to doing the exact opposite of what you
think you should be doing.
Authors should be shocked to learn that there is almost no news
that can harm a writer's credibility, and that any publicity is
good publicity (pp. 51-52). Corporations and governments that try to
"reinstill confidence" should not be trusted because they
would do so only if they were ultimately doomed (p. 53). Children
shouldn't be on antidepressants as this removes a source of
learning from the life experience and thus make individuals less capable
of dealing with unwanted events later in life (p. 61). The sinking of
the Titanic was a positive disaster as it put shipbuilders on their
toes, and possibly avoided an even larger accident later (p. 72). The
general theme is that those who make errors are stronger than those who
don't--reliability, or antifragility--only comes when something is
regularly tested by an unwanted event.
The theory has merit. Consider this lesson applied to central bank
policies. In the wake of the dot-com bust a concerted effort by the
world's central banks flooded the global financial system with
liquidity. The liquidation of assets that should have happened never
did, and as a result lenders and borrowers didn't learn their
lesson on prudential money management. The seeds were sown for the
larger crisis starting in 2007-2008 because a simple lesson was not
learnt when the financial system's problems were still in relative
infancy.
There is much to learn from this book and much to be weary. At the
end of the day, Taleb reckons the best test of an anti-fragile
institution is Mother Nature mixed with a healthy dose of time. In
chapter 21 he criticizes the prevailing orthodoxy of
"neomania," the mistaken belief that newer is better. Those
institutions that have existed the longest are, in all likelihood, those
that will continue to exist into the future. As an example, imagine that
the year is 1988 and answer the following: which structure will last the
longest, the Berlin Wall or the Great Pyramid of Giza.
In this test, as in much of the book, Taleb asks too much and too
little. He asks too much because those institutions with the most
longevity were once upon a time also the ones with the least. There must
be a better test than longevity, as it only pushes the problem back in
time to identify the source of antifragility. It cannot be turtles all
the way down.
An applied example relevant to the present financial crisis would
involve looking for those institutions that have been strengthened by
current affairs. The crisis has taken its toll on many aspects of the
financial services industry, but some general types of products have
proven surprising resili ... antifragile. Governments with prudent
fiscal policies--e.g., Germany, Switzerland and Singapore--have fared
well and indeed been strengthened as finances deteriorate in more
profligate countries. Investment funds capitalizing on what were once
unorthodox strategies, such as gold and other precious met al holdings,
have out-performed more traditional investments as the financial crisis
worsens. Readers of this journal will also notice that their stock in
Austrian economics has increased in value over the past decade. Question
begging and failed policies developed through more mainstream theories
have led many former outsiders to the ranks of Austrian economists. An
unwanted event caused an offsetting positive outcome in all these
scenarios. That is what being antifragile is about.
Taleb asks too little in this book by not exploring the true
sources of antifragility. He comes close, alluding in many places that
market-based institutions better combat the false security that planned
institutions create. Explaining and elaborating on this link would do
much to take the fundamental merits of antifragility to the next level.
It would be, however, fodder for another book.
REFERENCES
Mises, Ludwig von. 1949. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics.
Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1998.
Shackle, G. L. S. 1949. Expectations in Economics. Westport, Conn.:
Gibson.
Taleb, Nassim N. 2001. Fooled by Randomness. New York: Random
House.
--. 2007. The Black Swan. New York: Random House.
Nassim Nicholas Taleb
New York: Random House, 2012, 519 pp.
David Howden (dhowden@slu.edu) is chairman of the Department of
Business and Economics, St. Louis University, Madrid Campus, Spain.