How entrepreneurship theory created economics.
Brown, Christopher ; Thornton, Mark
1. INTRODUCTION
Richard Cantillon (168?-173?) is widely considered the father of
economic theory for providing the first theoretical analysis of commerce
in his Essai sur la Nature du Commerce en General, posthumously and
anonymously published in 1755. (1) The Essai was the springboard for the
first-generation of economists, including David Hume, Adam Smith and the
Physiocrats. However, Cantillon and the Essai were soon forgotten, only
to be rediscovered by economist William Stanley Jevons in the late 19th
century. He dubbed the book, "more emphatically than any other
single work, the cradle of political economy" (1931 [1881], p.
342). His assessment comes from the recognition of Cantillon's
myriad theoretical contributions, ranging from basic methodology to
complex macroeconomic models that include the circular-flow model and
the price-specie flow mechanism.
In addition to the economic contributions of the Essai, Cantillon
is credited for developing an important--and in many ways wholly
modern--theory of entrepreneurship (the forerunner to Knight and Mises).
Indeed, Cantillon has received increased attention and recognition,
primarily in the entrepreneurship literature, as the original thinker on
entrepreneurship (Murphy et al., 2006). Although the introduction of the
term "entrepreneur" was originally attributed to Jean-Baptiste
Say, it is now known that Cantillon was the "first significant
writer to make frequent and obtrusive use of the term in a semblance of
its modern form" (Hebert and Link, 2006, p. 589; also see Ebner,
2005; Formaini, 2001; Hamilton and Harper, 1994) and particularly as a
concept for formal theoretical purposes (Hebert and Link, 2006; Long,
1983). Despite this deserved recognition, Cantillon's theory of
entrepreneurship has long been thought of as merely one isolated
component of his many contributions to economics rather than as the
basis of his method and construction of economic theory. We believe that
understanding the indispensable role of the entrepreneur in
Cantillon's economic treatise provides a "new" way to
approach economic problems.
While most scholars recognize that entrepreneurship is the driver
of economic growth and progress (Bosma, Wennekers & Amoros, 2011),
Holcombe (2007) points out that it also creates information, knowledge,
and even economic wisdom. Although he does not link entrepreneurship
with the development of economic theory, he does identify a problem of
entrepreneurship and its relationship to modern economic theory:
The problem, then, is not that no economists recognize the role of
entrepreneurship, but rather that entrepreneurship remains outside the
basic framework of mainstream economic analysis, and especially the
mainstream economic analysis of growth. (Holcombe, 2007, p. 5)
It is hardly the case that the concept of the entrepreneur merely
became antiquated and was replaced with a better and more modern concept
or technique. Holcombe (2007, p. 8) finds that the absence of
entrepreneurship strikes at the raison d'etre of economic analysis
and that, "because of its assumptions, the neoclassical framework
has serious deficiencies for analyzing the underlying causes of
prosperity. The neoclassical model does not provide the appropriate
vantage point for looking at this issue." With the exception of the
work of Knight, Mises, Kirzner, and Foss and Klein, few attempts have
been made within economics to "fit" entrepreneurship into an
economic framework. We have discovered evidence that Cantillon should be
credited with redefining the term entrepreneur to its modern conception
and that he did so based on personal experience long prior to writing
his Essai. It is not a great leap of faith to imagine that he must have
developed at least a rough theory of entrepreneurship before undertaking
the writing of the Essai (Brown and Thornton, 2013).
In this paper, we seek to understand the role that Cantillon's
theory of the entrepreneur plays in the development of his theoretical
contributions to economics. We give an overview of Cantillon's
contributions to economic and entrepreneurship theory, followed by an
examination of a sample of five cases from the Essai that illustrate how
Cantillon used his theory of entrepreneurship to construct economic
theory. We provide evidence that Cantillon's theory of
entrepreneurship is not merely an isolated brick in his system of
economics, but in fact is better understood as the tool used to build a
brick wall. Not only is the entrepreneur critical for building his
economic models, but in the absence of the entrepreneur, none of
Cantillon's theoretical constructions would work. Therefore, his
theory of the entrepreneur should not be viewed simply as one aspect
among many, but rather as the foundation for understanding economic
phenomena. This point, we believe, is not currently recognized in either
the economics or entrepreneurship literatures.
At first this might seem like a "chicken and egg"
circular argument in that you cannot separate his view of
entrepreneurship from his perspective on the economy. However, we show
that our central finding is a matter of cause and effect, and thus it is
more like a lock and key proposition. It is his theory of the
entrepreneur that unlocks the mystery of how Cantillon created so much
of the foundation of economic theory.
2. CANTILLON'S CONTRIBUTIONS
Historians of economic thought have dusted off an important and
long neglected year on the historical timeline--1730--that is just as
crucial as 1776 (Adam Smith), 1871 (the Marginal Revolution), 1936
(Keynes), and 1947 (Samuelson). Before 1730, when Richard Cantillon is
thought to have completed his Essai sur la Nature du Commerce en
General, there was precious little in the economics literature that
could be described as economic theory; after 1730, there was a
burgeoning output of economic writings that became increasingly more
theoretical and systematic. During this ensuing progress, the
Physiocratic, French Liberal, and British Classical schools developed,
all having acknowledged roots in Cantillon's influential work.
Prior to Cantillon, the economics literature consisted largely of
the reflections of religious thinkers and philosophers. Noteworthy among
them were the Spanish Scholastics. They were among the first to
systematically incorporate economic issues into their philosophical and
religious paradigms. Also noteworthy were the Mercantilists, but they
suffered from a dearth of theory and organizing principles. The
Mercantilist writings are generally thought to have been motivated by
their self-interest in business and trade and they did not produce a
systematic approach for understanding and describing the nature of
commerce. Anti-mercantilists also made contributions to economics, most
notably in France, but they also lacked theory and a systematic approach
for explaining economic phenomena. The anti-mercantilists'
galvanizing force was their opposition to the mercantilist policies of
the ruling elite. They were like the Scholastics in that they were
motivated by the fairness of things, such as taxes, rather than with
economic questions, such as the efficiency of different tax systems.
Cantillon should be seen as having made a revolutionary break with
these schools of thought. He removed the ethical and political concerns
in order to focus specifically on "the economic features of human
action" (Rothbard, 1995, p. 348). When the Essai was finally
published in 1755, economics took a giant step forward and became a more
scientific, systematic discipline in its own right. (2) In addition, it
helped inaugurate the Physiocratic School of economics in 1756.
Cantillon was also an acknowledged influence on the French liberals,
including Turgot and Condillac, as well as Classical economists David
Hume and Adam Smith (Thornton, 2009b). Arguably, many of those
influenced by Cantillon took their economic thinking in wrong directions
and ended up in intellectual dead ends, but this should not diminish the
fact that it was Cantillon who placed economics on scientific
foundations (Thornton, 1998 and 2007b). Thanks to Murphy (1986) we know
a great deal about why Cantillon wrote the Essai, but it has remained a
puzzle as to how he was able to independently create so much of what
economic theory would come to be.
Cantillon's Essai represents a deep reflection on and
rejection of existing economic knowledge. In Part 1 of the Essai, he
began by discarding the mercantilist notion that money was wealth and
then began to build his analysis of commerce from the ground up with an
analysis of the property rights of landowners and the establishment of
villages, market towns, and cities. Next, he provided an analysis of
labor and wage rate differentials that concludes with the remarkable
finding that the true cost or "intrinsic value" of something
is its opportunity cost. He showed that there was a mutual
interdependence among the economic classes and that the economy would be
self-regulating because entrepreneurs would obey the command of price
signals. He then provided a population theory that predates and exceeds
that of Malthus and integrated it into his theory of wealth. In Part 2
he analyzed barter, market prices, money and its velocity, and changes
in the quantity of money and its relation to changes in the interest
rate. Part 3 explains foreign trade, exchange rates, banking, inflation,
and the business cycle.
Cantillon is credited with many contributions, including location
theory, population theory, the price-specie flow mechanism, the
circular-flow model, business cycle theory, methodological individualism and subjectivism, abstraction, the ceteris paribus assumption, closed-
and open-economy models, as well as methodological innovations like the
separation of positive and normative economics. We argue that
Cantillon's wide-ranging experience as an entrepreneur led him to a
theory of the entrepreneur that he then used to construct economic
theory. It is in his theory of entrepreneurship that Cantillon seems to
have had no prior influence (Brown and Thornton, 2013).
There are three main actors in Cantillon's economy. Property
owners are the main consumers and all production in the economy (supply)
is an attempt to meet their desires (demand). The two remaining actors
are primarily distinguished by the nature of their income, which leads
to the major characteristic of Cantillon's entrepreneur: living on
uncertain income, rather than on fixed income. While wage laborers are
on fixed wages, entrepreneurs have no guaranteed income. In addition to
this feature, the entrepreneur is responsible for the production,
circulation, and exchange of goods in the economy as they attempt to
meet the demands of property owners and other consumers. Thus
Cantillon's theory of the entrepreneur is distinctly supply-side
(Hebert and Link, 2006). In this capacity the entrepreneur acts on
perceived arbitrage opportunities: "[Entrepreneurs] will buy at a
low price the products of the villages and will [transport them] to the
Capital to be sold there at a higher price" (Cantillon, 1931, p.
151).
Cantillon's theory of entrepreneurship is that entrepreneurs
function by bearing risk under uncertainty. They buy goods at known
(fixed) prices in the present to sell at unknown prices in the future.
According to Hebert and Link (1988, p. 21):
An important aspect of Cantillon's theory is that it stresses the
function, not the personality of the entrepreneur. His idea is
sweeping in its application, embracing many different occupations
and cutting across production, distribution, and exchange.
For Cantillon, entrepreneurship is pervasive in the economy. The
term "entrepreneur" is mentioned over 100 times in the Essai
and is widely applied to both producers and exchangers (Hebert and Link,
2006), including entrepreneurial activities all along the supply chain,
from the production of raw materials to the retail distribution of
finished products. For example, he considers as entrepreneurs producers
of all kinds, including farmers, wholesalers of wool and grain, and
manufacturers. Retailers, such as restaurateurs and shopkeepers, were
considered entrepreneurs. Owners of mines, theaters, and buildings are
entrepreneurs as well, as are merchants of myriad varieties, including
artisans, bakers, butchers, and drapers. Entrepreneurs of all kinds are
mentioned in the Essai: chimney sweeps, shoemakers, tailors, carpenters,
painters, physicians, lawyers, supervisors, miners, and brewers.
Cantillon's theory of entrepreneurship is therefore narrowly
defined but broadly applicable. Anyone who invests (in the sense of
acquiring and employing resources) with the purpose of selling goods in
the future at an uncertain price is an entrepreneur. Therefore, his
theory is in the same lineage as Knight and Mises, but differs greatly
with Schumpeter and others.
3. USING ENTREPRENEURSHIP TO DEVELOP ECONOMICS
Let us now take Cantillon's general theory of entrepreneurship
and see how it is the key that Cantillon used to unlock the door to
economic theory, which he then used to explain phenomena of the real
world. We proceed by describing and evaluating five examples of economic
phenomena that Cantillon developed in the Essai. As we examine
Cantillon's contributions to economics we will highlight three
features. First, entrepreneurship plays a pivotal and necessary role in
his theoretical constructions. Second, Cantillon illustrates his
theoretical constructions with examples of entrepreneurial plans,
actions, and constraints. Third, absent the entrepreneur the theoretical
constructions or models would fail.
Economic Geography and the Entrepreneur
Cantillon offers four short chapters (3-6) in the Essai on economic
geography and location theory. It is in chapter 4 in particular where
Cantillon first employs the term entrepreneur in referring to the
entrepreneur's crucial role in spatial economics. For Cantillon,
there are villages, market towns, and cities in a state, all of which
are interrelated and depend upon the decisions of the entrepreneur for
their size, location and proximity to one another.
The size and location of a village is determined by the
entrepreneurial production decisions of the property owners. These
decisions determine both the types of production and the quantity of
labor required. They also determine the number of farmer-entrepreneurs
and the number and type of artisan-entrepreneurs that will live in the
village. If the owner decides to live in the village then this will also
affect the size and composition of the population of the village. Thus,
in order to satisfy the demand of the property owners, villages are
located in surrounding areas with their size and location determined by
entrepreneurial decisions. Cantillon also highlights the role of
transportation costs in economic geography:
To whatever cultivation land is put, whether pasture, corn, vines,
etc. the farmers or laborers who carry on the work must live near at
hand; otherwise the time taken in going to their fields and returning to
their houses would take up too much of the day. (Cantillon, 1931, p. 9)
The size and location of villages are therefore the result of the
entrepreneurial decisions of property owners, farmers, artisans, and in
this case even the common wage laborer, largely based on the goal of
reducing transportation costs and maximizing productive time. If the
property owner decided not to produce anything, the village would not
exist.
Market towns develop in the center of a group of villages and have
a marketplace that operates at least one day a week. The location of the
market town is determined by the entrepreneurial decisions of artisans
regarding where to locate their business. The size of the market town is
a function of the aggregate size of the surrounding villages. Market
towns provide a benefit by reducing overall transportation costs,
facilitating exchange by reducing uncertainty and transaction costs, and
by providing an auction-like environment that facilitates the setting of
prices. As Cantillon explained:
A market town being placed in the centre of the villages whose
people come to market, it is more natural and easy that the villagers
should bring their products thither for sale on market days and buy the
articles they need, than that the merchants and factors should transport
them to the villages in exchange for their products. (Cantillon, 1931,
p. 11)
Thus market towns develop as a result of entrepreneurial activity.
The entrepreneur's function consists of three exchanges: (a)
purchasing products from the villagers for local resale and export to
the cities; (b) purchasing products in the city in order to sell them to
the villagers; and (c) producing goods and services to be sold in the
market town.
Cities are a further step in geographical agglomeration that appear
when property owners find a particular location to their liking and
cause a larger and more diverse group of entrepreneurs to collect at
that location. Cantillon observed that bakers, butchers, and brewers are
entrepreneurs who will locate in cities in order to serve the noblemen
and exchange with other entrepreneurs. Therefore the size of a city is a
function of the number of property owners who choose to live there as
well as the size of surrounding market towns and villages.
Cantillon's contributions to economic geography, location
theory, and transportation economics are all related to the decisions of
the entrepreneur about where to profitably locate. While the property
owner is responsible for the initial production decisions in
Cantillon's economic framework, the entrepreneurs determine how to
carry out such decisions and where villages and market towns will be
located. Indeed, when enough entrepreneurs settle down and locate in a
village to serve the villagers, Cantillon says it becomes a market town.
Most importantly, the driving force of the size and location of
villages, towns and cities is the transport and transaction cost
decisions of entrepreneurs. Absent the entrepreneur there would be no
factor in the model to make the necessary decisions that determine the
size and location of settlements. Therefore, it should be clear that
entrepreneurs are the fundamental driver in urban economic development
and that their absence would make the provisioning of large concentrated
population centers difficult, if not impossible, to imagine. (3)
Labor Markets and the Entrepreneur
In chapters 7-9 of Part One of the Essai we can see how the
entrepreneur and entrepreneurship also play the role of prime movers in
labor markets. Cantillon states that skilled labor is better paid than
unskilled labor because there is an opportunity cost of time in learning
the skill. Within the skilled labor category, incomes will differ based
on quality, cost of training, the risks and dangers of a profession, and
the amount of trust that must be placed into the worker's hands.
For Cantillon, risks go hand-in-hand with rewards. Therefore the amount
and type of training to obtain a certain skill in the present must be
offset by enhanced, although uncertain, wages in the future.
Artisan-entrepreneurs, for example, are at risk that market wage rates
for their profession might be lower in the future once additional
artisans are trained and ready to trade. Thus, the number of artisans in
a particular line of work must be proportioned to the demand so that if
too many exist in a particular location, income will fall and some of
them must either leave to find work elsewhere or find another line of
work. Cantillon explained:
It often happens that laborers and handicraftsmen have not enough
employment when there are too many of them to share the business. It
happens also that they are deprived of work by accidents and by
variations in demand, or that they are overburdened with work according
to circumstances. Be that as it may, when they have no work they quit
the villages, towns or cities where they live in such numbers that those
who remain are always proportioned to the employment which suffices to
maintain them. (Cantillon, 1931, p. 25)
For Cantillon, then, employment and wages are the result of the
interplay of decision-making by various entrepreneurs.
Cantillon illustrates his theory of labor and wages with the
example of a father's decision to have his son trained in a
profession. Here the father has to evaluate the present costs of
training versus the projected future income earned in the profession,
which is uncertain. He remarks later that if the king had many people
trained in high paying jobs, it would be useless if there were no demand
for them, and that if there were demand, it would be supplied by
entrepreneurs. The entrepreneur obviously plays many essential roles in
labor markets and it would be difficult to imagine a labor market functioning in the absence of Cantillon's entrepreneurs.
Entrepreneurship, which takes account of costs and benefits,
produces balance and harmony in labor markets and makes adjustments to
changing conditions over time. At a time when the economy was
transitioning from a relatively static feudal order to the more dynamic
economy of emerging capitalism, Cantillon's explication of labor
markets driven by entrepreneurship was a breakthrough.
"Intrinsic" Value
There was a long-standing debate over the nature of
Cantillon's theory of value. Was it a labor theory, a land theory,
or a labor and land theory of value? Or was it similar to Adam
Smith's distinction between market price and natural price? The
history of this debate is described by Thornton (2007a). Through a
combination of Cantillon's own description of intrinsic value, the
definition of "intrinsic" circa 1730, and the examples of
intrinsic value given by Cantillon, Thornton concludes that
Cantillon's concept of intrinsic value is actually opportunity cost
and that Cantillon had a subjective theory of value.
In Chapter 10 Cantillon makes a useful distinction between the
"intrinsic value" of a product and its market price. For
Cantillon, the intrinsic value of any good or service is the amount of
and quality of the land and labor required to produce goods and the
values of these inputs are related to their alternative uses. Therefore
intrinsic value, the anathema of the modern economist, is actually the
equivalent to the modern concept of opportunity cost. For Cantillon, the
intrinsic value of a product never changes once it has been produced,
but the market price changes according to "the humors and fancies
of men" (Cantillon, 1931, p. 29) and is uncertain since it will
occur (or possibly not occur) in the future. The difference between the
actual market price and the opportunity cost is the true measure of
profit and loss for the entrepreneur. Therefore, not only is Cantillon
credited with the discovery of the concept of opportunity cost, but we
find it in the essence of his theory of entrepreneurship.
Cantillon uses several examples of entrepreneurs to illustrate the
concept of intrinsic value-opportunity cost. In one important case,
Cantillon discusses a farmer-entrepreneur who invests in land and labor
to produce crops. Farmers could earn profits or losses based on the
crops planted, growing conditions, and changing market prices. The land
and labor are the farmer's intrinsic value-opportunity cost and the
quality of the land and labor are important considerations. The
farmer's income is dependent on future market prices and is
therefore uncertain.
In another important example, Cantillon wrote about a homeowner who
could profit or lose from the improvements made to his land upon selling
his property:
If a gentleman cuts canals and erects terraces in his garden, their
intrinsic value will be proportionable to the land and labor; but the
price in reality will not always follow this proportion. If he offers to
sell the garden possibly no one will give him half the expense he has
incurred. It is also possible that if several persons desire it he may
be given double the intrinsic value, that is twice the value of the land
and the expense he has incurred. (Cantillon, 1931, p. 29)
Cantillon's concept of intrinsic value-opportunity cost fits
hand-in-glove with his theory of entrepreneurship. Intrinsic value is
not simply a certain quantity of land and labor but also accounts for
quality and is therefore the true opportunity cost of making a good. The
difference between intrinsic value-opportunity cost and market price
yields economic profit or loss. The distinction between intrinsic value
and market price is so intimately related to his theory of
entrepreneurship that it rules out the absence of entrepreneurship.
The Circular-Flow Model
The final chapters of Part One of the Essai examine how everyone in
a given state is "dependent" upon the property owner. The real
point of the chapter is that working people do not just serve the
property owners but also each other, and that there is a mutual
interdependence between the property class and laborers. In Chapter 3 of
Part 2, Cantillon developed his circular-flow model of the economy to
explain distribution. Here the entrepreneur is what gives impetus to the
flow of goods where "each branch of the circulation in the cities
is carried out by entrepreneurs" (Cantillon, 1931, p. 129).
Cantillon describes how the tastes of the property owners drive the
market as a prime mover on the demand side of the economy. He then
derives a circular-flow model of the economy involving goods, incomes,
and expenditures to illustrate the mutual interdependence of the
different economic classes. He begins with his model of the isolated
estate, initially directed by the estate owner who has nothing until he
hires labor, and whose return increases with the amount of labor that
can be profitably employed. In short, the estate owner is only
advantaged if he supports people who will carry out his
"demands."
As part of the labor force employed by the estate owner, Cantillon
points out the role of supervisors of farm and artisan labor. The
supervisors of labor act like entrepreneurs in satisfying the demands of
the estate owners (see Foss et al., 2007 for further development of the
Cantillonian idea of "proxy" entrepreneurship). Cantillon then
changes the model so that everyone actually becomes an entrepreneur in
their profession. Here nearly everyone but the property owner and wage
laborer is an entrepreneur: wholesalers of wool and grain, bakers,
butchers, transporters, manufacturers, and merchants of all kinds. As
entrepreneurs, they are "working at risk, [and] some get rich and
gain more than double their subsistence, [while] others are ruined and
become bankrupt" (Cantillon, 1931, p. 41).
Cantillon used the farmer as an example of an entrepreneur:
"The farmer is an entrepreneur who promises to pay the property
owner, for his farm or land, a fixed sum of money [...] without
assurance of the profit he will derive from this enterprise"
(Cantillon, 1931, pp. 48-49). The farmer-entrepreneur hires and
supervises labor and also buys goods from other entrepreneurs.
Cantillon described the entrepreneur as someone who uses
"judgment, without being able to foresee which [product] will pay
the best price" (Cantillon, 1931, p. 55), depending on factors of
supply and demand. Cantillon also specified that the entrepreneur can be
seen as the owner of an enterprise operating under uncertainty.
Entrepreneurs are those who "adjust themselves to risks in a
state" (Cantillon, 1931, p. 53), namely bankruptcy and starvation.
Next, Cantillon induced a change in demand by the estate owner and
explained how entrepreneurs working with the incentives provided by the
profit and loss framework restore the model to equilibrium. With his
model of the isolated estate he was able to show the circular flow of
goods, incomes, and expenditures between property owners, farmers, farm
labor, and entrepreneurs of all sorts. Indeed, Cantillon wrote that
"all the exchange and circulation of the state is conducted by the
actions of these entrepreneurs" (Cantillon, 1931, p. 57).
Interestingly, this is where Adam Smith found the model for his
"invisible hand" (Thornton, 2009a). Ironically, the model is
driven by entrepreneurship, though Smith himself downplayed the role of
the entrepreneur within his own system and the entrepreneur is absent
entirely in the modern-automatic circular flow model. Cantillon's
circular flow nature of the economy is dependent on entrepreneurs who
are directed by prices to carry and adjust or regulate the flow to
restore equilibrium. With the model of the isolated estate, Cantillon is
able to show that in the absence of entrepreneurs society must revert
back to feudalism where all decisions are made by the estate owners and
their proxies.
The Price-Specie Flow Mechanism
Part Two of the Essai opens with a discussion of barter, money and
market prices. For Cantillon, prices are based on supply and demand but
are ultimately determined by the haggling of buyers and sellers. In the
example he provided, price is set between two groups of entrepreneurs.
Entrepreneurs also establish a system regarding the flow and timing of
payments where, for example, farmers receive large payments from
wholesalers and make large rent payments to property owners.
Entrepreneurs make payments to wholesalers for their products after
having collected numerous small payments from their customers. Cantillon
even used the system set up by entrepreneurs to theoretically calculate
the quantity of money.
Unlike the mercantilists who viewed money as wealth, Cantillon
showed that an increase in the quantity of money had both seemingly
beneficial effects as well as dangerous negative effects. By basing his
analysis on entrepreneurs he was able to show that an increase in the
supply of money could alter relative prices depending on how and where
the money was injected into the economy rather than simply causing an
overall increase in prices. Whoever received the new money would spend
it, and what they spent it on would increase in price. As the price
increased, domestic entrepreneurs would then begin changing the
structure of production in the economy to address the new pattern of
demand. These structural changes created by entrepreneurs are now called
"Cantillon effects."
Furthermore, by explaining how money penetrated into the economy
through entrepreneurs Cantillon was able to construct the price-specie
flow mechanism. If money is relatively abundant, prices of domestic
goods increase and people tend to buy more imports. Gold is then
exported to pay for the increase in imports. The exportation of gold
would cause domestic prices to fall and thereby bring the domestic money
supply into equilibrium with the foreign money supply. Entrepreneurs
adjust and coordinate their plans and actions to relative changes in the
money supply. Therefore the price-specie flow mechanism is actually
dependent on widespread entrepreneurial activity. Without entrepreneurs
the mechanism would obviously fail to function.
3. IMPLICATIONS FOR THEORY AND PRACTICE
The examination of a variety of examples from the Essai shows that
Cantillon's theory of entrepreneurship plays a key role in his
construction of economic theory. We have found that insights derived
from examples in the Essai have important implications for modern
economics and entrepreneurship theory. However, despite Cantillon's
treatise, the entrepreneur was later removed from economic theory
beginning with Leon Walras (1870). Modern economics has continued this
unfortunate trend where the entrepreneur is now largely missing from its
models and textbooks (Kent and Rushing, 1999), to the point where
economics has arguably become a sterile and unrealistic discipline.
Neoclassical economic theory, despite some attempts (e.g., Baumol, 1993;
Kihlstrom and Laffont, 1979; Lazear, 2005), rarely even mentions the
entrepreneur. We believe that economics can benefit from
Cantillon's theory of entrepreneurship by viewing the actions of
entrepreneurs as critical to an economy.
Also, our findings should provoke greater caution when using models
of the economy that do not account for the entrepreneur. This is
especially true as one goes from pure theory to economic analysis and
the construction of economic policy. Economic models that exclude
entrepreneurship will likely have important defects if used for
"real world" policies. This is especially important given that
many economists have removed the entrepreneur from their modeling
because of the mathematical difficulties inherent in equilibrium
frameworks (Cassis and Minoglou, 2005). When such equilibrium models are
used for economic and policy analysis they will inherently contain
defects that could be significant when applied in the "real
world." Our finding provides one answer for the deficiency of such
models and indicates a path towards improvement. Economic policy
analysts would also be wise to visit Cantillon's treatise to
understand economic phenomena as it actually occurs. Indeed, Professor
Antoin Murphy (2010) provides a modern example of this when he uses the
Essai to explain economic growth in China, stating that "Richard
Cantillon can provide assistance in unlocking the paradox of China and
its entrepreneurial class."
Cantillon's insights also provide important lessons for the
teaching of basic economic concepts like supply and demand. In order to
understand such economic models, students must understand the prime
mover in the system--the entrepreneur--and static models of the economy
do not fully depict the continuous changes and dynamic nature of the
real world. Allowing for the entrepreneur (real people) and
entrepreneurship (risk, uncertainly, profit and loss) to be a central
focus of economics, it will be easier to give everyday examples of
entrepreneurship to students who are required to take economics classes.
Cantillon's robust theory of the entrepreneur helps resolve the
problem of making economics lively and relevant to students and is able
to explain everyday events.
Finally, we also believe that entrepreneurship scholars will
benefit from this "new" perspective provided by Cantillon. For
entrepreneurship scholars, a greater attention to basic economic theory
should result in better research and studies of entrepreneurs. They can
also benefit from the knowledge of how pervasive entrepreneurship is
throughout the economy. Such a view shows the relevance and importance
of understanding the widespread effects of entrepreneurship. It can
inspire confidence in those doing research in entrepreneurship, and it
demonstrates the need for future studies.
REFERENCES
Baumol, William J., 1993. "Formal Entrepreneurship Theory in
Economics: Existence and Bounds," Journal of Business Venturing 8,
no. 3: 197-210.
Brown, Chris, and Mark Thornton. 2013. Turning the Word Upside Down: Richard Cantillon and the Meaning of Entrepreneurship. Working
Paper.
Bosma, Niels, Sander Wennekers, and Jose E. Amoros. 2011. Global
Entrepreneurship Monitor 2011 Global Report. Babson College, Babson
Park, Mass.
Cantillon, Richard. 1755. Essai Sur la Nature du Commerce en
General, H. Higgs, ed. and trans. London: Macmillan, 1931.
Cassis, Youssef, and Ioanna Minoglou, eds. 2005. Entrepreneurship
in Theory and History. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Ebner, Alexander. 2005. "Entrepreneurship and Economic
Development, from Classical Political Economy to Economic
Sociology," Journal of Economic Studies 32, no. 3: 256-274.
Formaini, Robert L. 2001. "The Engine of Capitalist Process:
Entrepreneurs in Economic Theory," Economic and Financial Review, Q
(IV), 2-11.
Foss, Kirsten, Nicolai J. Foss, and Peter G. Klein. 2007.
"Original and Derived Judgment: An Entrepreneurial Theory of
Economic Organization," Organization Studies 28, no. 12: 1893-1912.
Hamilton, Robert T., and David A. Harper. 1994. "The
Entrepreneur in Theory and Practice," Journal of Economic Studies
21, no. 6: 3-18.
Hebert, Robert, and Albert Link. 2006. "The Entrepreneur As
Innovator," Journal of Technology Transfer 31: 589-597.
Holcombe, Randall. 2007. Entrepreneurship and Economic Progress.
New York: Routledge.
Jevons, William Stanley. 1881. "Richard Cantillon and the
nationality of political economy." In Richard Cantillon, Essai Sur
la Nature du Commerce en General, London: Macmillan, 1931, pp. 133-157.
Kent, Calvin A., and Francis W. Rushing. 1999. "Coverage of
Entrepreneurship in Principles of Economics Textbooks: An Update,"
Journal of Economic Education 30, no. 2: 184-188.
Kihlstrom, Richard E., and Jean-Jacques Laffront. 1979. "A
General Equilibrium Entrepreneurial Theory of Firm Formation Based on
Risk Aversion," Journal of Political Economy 87, no. 4: 719-748.
Kirzner, Israel M. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago,
Ill.: University of Chicago Press.
Lazear, Edward P. 2005. "Entrepreneurship," Journal of
Labor Economics 23, no. 4: 649-680.
Long, Wayne. 1983. "The Meaning of Entrepreneurship,"
American Journal of Small Business 3, no. 2: 47-56.
Marshall, Alfred. 1920. Industry and Trade: A Study of Industrial
Technique and Business Organization; and of Their Influences on the
Conditions of Various Classes and Nations, 3rd ed. London: Macmillan.
Murphy, Antoin E. 1986. Richard Cantillon: Entrepreneur and
Economist. New York: Oxford University Press.
--. 2010. "Theories of 18th-Century Irishman Key in
Today's China," Irish Times, January 10, 2010.
Murphy, Patrick J., Jianwen Liao, and Harold P. Welsch. 2006.
"A Conceptual History of Entrepreneurial Thought," Journal of
Management History 12, no. 1: 12-35.
Rothbard, Murray N. 1995. Economic Thought Before Adam Smith.
Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
Thornton, Mark. 1998. "Richard Cantillon and the Origins of
Economic Theory," Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines 8,
no. 1: 61-74.
--. 2007a. "Richard Cantillon and the Discovery of Opportunity
Cost," History of Political Economy 39, no. 1: 97-120.
--. 2007b. "Cantillon, Hume and the Rise of
Anti-Mercantilism," History of Political Economy 39, no. 3:
453-480.
--. 2009a. "Cantillon and the Invisible Hand," Quarterly
Journal of Austrian Economics 12, no. 2: 27-46.
--. 2009b. "Cantillon and the Rise of Anti-Mercantilism,"
Procesos de Mercado: Revista Europea de Economia Politica 6, no. 1:
13-42.
Walras, Leon. 1870. Elements of Pure Economics. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
(1) For a complete biography of Cantillon, see Murphy (1986).
(2) The Essai circulated in manuscript form among many individuals,
including David Hume, prior to its publication.
(3) In Cantillon one can find all three aspects of Alfred
Marshall's theory of agglomeration. Marshall (1920) put forth three
theories of industrial agglomeration that include transportation costs,
the labor force, and intellectual spillovers. Cantillon included all
three aspects in his location theory, including the obvious emphasis he
placed on transportation costs and labor force determination. In terms
of intellectual spillovers, Cantillon's discussion of how prices
are set on market days is clearly a reflection of an intellectual
spillover or "meeting of minds." Cantillon's analysis is
in terms of a pre-industrial economy, as we understand it, and is
entirely choice motivated. Marshall's analysis is in terms of the
modern industrial economy and is partly driven by random constraints.
Christopher Brown, MBA, Ph.D., (chrisbrown77@gmail.com) is owner of
Smile Right Solutions, a dental practice management company. Mark
Thornton, Ph.D., (mthornton@mises.org) is Senior Fellow at the Ludwig
von Mises Institute and serves as book review editor of the QJAE.