Capital in Disequilibrium: The Role of Capital in a Changing World (2nd ed.).
Bylund, Per L.
Capital in Disequilibrium: The Role of Capital in a Changing World
(2nd ed.)
Peter Lewin
Auburn, Alabama: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2011, 277 pp.
Peter Lewin's Capital in Disequilibrium is an award-winning,
extensive survey of capital theory, which touches on and summarizes an
array of issues and phenomena. It fearlessly dives into the depths of
the vast and shifting literatures available on each of the topics.
Lewin, a former student of renowned Austrian capital theorist Ludwig
Lachmann, guides the reader through both the history and parallel
universes of capital theory in an attempt to develop a comprehensive
guide to and modern framework for the study of capital theory.
The book's eleven theory chapters are divided into three
parts. Part one provides a background and discusses fundamental
theoretical concepts related to the analysis. At the core is the concept
of equilibrium and how it, interpreted as complete plan coordination,
applies to individuals' actions: it implies that all "plan[s]
can be successfully executed" and consequently that "[m]eans
are exactly matched to ends" (p. 19). In the real market process
production takes time, and therefore there is substantial uncertainty or
ignorance and consequently there can be no full plan coordination.
Rather, Lewin argues that we "are never in equilibrium" (p.
44) and even though we see a tendency toward coherence, which may result
in convergence of expectations and even fulfillment of plans, "the
market process in general is not equilibrating" (p. 48).
Part two discusses the meaning and implications of capital, and how
it relates to interest and profit. Lewin provides a historical and
theoretical overview of our scientific understanding of these phenomena,
and stresses the importance of the flow of time in market analysis.
Indeed, Bohm-Bawerk's great contribution to capital theory, Lewin
says, is basically the addition of "a new dimension, a time
dimension, to Ricardo's theory of distribution" (p. 75). We
learn that "capital must be thought of in terms of intertemporal
plans" (p. 105) and since "[t]he passage of time has
implications for knowledge and expectations" (p. 91) the market is
forever trapped in a kaleidic state of fluctuating disequilibrium.
Part three applies this view of capital on the real market process
and the institutional environment within which individuals act. The
Lachmannian theory of capital is introduced, in which heterogeneous
assets with "multiple specificities" are combined in
ever-changing capital structures formed to attain specific ends. Lewin
especially stresses the role and function of the business firm, and uses
the inherent ignorance in a market with changing capital structures to
draft a capital-based theory of the firm and human resources. (More on
this below.)
There can be no doubt that Lewin is very well versed in the topic.
Also, the Lachmannian disequilibrium perspective is both informative and
refreshing, especially in the discussion in the second part of the book
on historical capital theories and mainstream interpretations of the
theory in Bohm-Bawerk's Positive Theory of Capital (1889). Less
obvious is the value added by using mathematical notation in attempting
to formalize Austrian capital theory, though this does offer some
illuminating points of reference when comparing with mainstream. And
such notation may be necessary in order to speak to non-Austrian
readers. Yet it seems likely those readers are lost already in the first
theory chapter in the book, "What Does Equilibrium Mean?", in
which Lewin dives into a discussion on Hayekian knowledge, plan
coordination, and equilibrium tendencies.
Neoclassical readers are likely to find it difficult to fully
comprehend Lewin's radical subjectivist, constant disequilibrium,
market process perspective. But the book nevertheless provides
interesting insights and raises important questions, many of which
should be understandable even without necessarily accepting the totality
of this Austrian perspective. Overall, the book has much to offer, and
Austrians too will find interesting tidbits and enlightening theoretical
parallels.
This being said, Lewin sometimes seems to struggle to bring all the
thoughts together into a complete and coherent whole with explanatory
power to further our understanding of the economic process. The
underlying argument appears somewhat frail or shallow at times, and to
some degree, the author fails to follow through on several of the
important points he makes. The reasoning offered to tackle economic
problems often seems to come to a halt before the explanatory power of
the framework has been sufficiently exploited, and the reader is left
wondering if there is not more to the story. As a consequence, one has
to wonder whether knowledge is suitable as the universally applied
explanans to all phenomena under investigation, or if there are possible
alternative explanations--and whether some of those could offer more
detailed explanations or greater understanding in causal-realist
analysis. There are several examples of these ostensible shortcomings
throughout the book, and they all seem to arise from the treatment of
knowledge as a lapis philosophorum of economics.
Also, readers already with an Austrian bent may suffer a foreboding
feeling while perusing the book due to the relative absence of Ludwig
von Mises and Murray Rothbard in the book's primary discussion. A
possible reason for this is the already mentioned adopted
knowledge-based framework for analysis, within which the contributions
of Mises and Rothbard may not squarely fit. Lewin relies heavily on
Hayek's theorizing on the role of knowledge in the economy and uses
this concept as the lens through which capital and the market process
are studied. The framework is almost exclusively formulated based on the
tension between knowledge and ignorance, and how this bounded
rationality of economic actors fundamentally shapes market structure
through individuals putting their plans into action. While this
perspective may indeed be advantageous for analyzing certain problems,
Lewin never substantiates this choice and the reader remains uninformed
of why this is a suitable (or perhaps the best) approach--and what are
the consequences of choosing it. In this sense, the lack of references
to more mundane causal-realist economic theorizing may appear wanting.
In the same vein, the knowledge framework Lewin utilizes seems to
rely on the entrepreneur as primarily "an all-purpose
arbitrageur" or information broker. The entrepreneur acts on
perceived price (or knowledge) discrepancies but there is no saying if
what appears like an opportunity is real, since the market is not
generally equilibrating. However, entrepreneurship may eradicate price
differences between markets and entrepreneurs may form firms to exploit
profit opportunities through establishing internal capabilities using
capital; indeed, organizational structure can be thought of as a result
of entrepreneurial innovation.
The book offers no elaborate discussion on entrepreneurship--the
word is not listed in the book's index--but it is obvious that
Lewin's entrepreneur has more in common with Kirzner (1973) than
with Mises (1949). While the former is an arbitrageur, the latter is a
forward-looking speculator, acting under the uncertainty of expected
future prices as bases for profit calculation in an open-ended market
process. Entrepreneurial bidding for resources intended to be used in
future production drives the social appraisement process of the market
toward ex post price coordination. Such market action certainly conveys
knowledge of the real supply and demand curves at a specific point in
time, but does not produce or depend on it. In contrast, plan
coordination relies on these prices as inputs and for that reason sees
the market as a means to disseminate knowledge of the particular
circumstances of time and place through those very prices. The resulting
argument seems unsatisfactory: knowledge produces prices, the knowledge
of which is the basis for plan coordination, yet time and change makes
the world "non-expectable" through essentially undermining the
value of this knowledge. So what can we expect to learn from this?
Focusing on knowledge and plan coordination, Lewin cannot say
anything conclusive about what characterizes the market process.
Instead, it is "composed of equilibrating, disequilibrating and
non-equilibrating sub processes," and consequently "the
arrival of new and better products and better methods of production is
the result of unpredictable, disequilibrating and non-equilibrating
processes." Furthermore, "[t]here is no tendency for
expectations to cohere" in the market, and therefore production
processes are "the results of a multitude of unintentional
experimentations" (pp. 44-45; emphasis added). In other words,
attempting to explain the market process in terms of knowledge produces
a rather arbitrary "kaleidic" stew of unpredictable outcomes
resulting from the actions of ignorant actors.
The issue of price vs. plan coordination has undoubtedly been
heavily debated among Austrians, and this is not the place to review
this debate. It is sufficient to note that Lewin clearly comes down on
the side of plan coordination, and that this at times seems to create
problems that it does not allow him to solve. Moreover, it is not
obvious why a general concept such as knowledge should always be deemed
appropriate in solving specific economic puzzles. In many cases, the
solutions Lewin presents appear to have more to offer were the logic to
be taken a step further. Instead of doing so, the reader is left without
further guidance yet reminded that a solution is suggested in stating
that it is primarily a knowledge problem.
A particularly telling example of this is the author's
formulation of a capital-based theory of the business firm. While it is
at times difficult to separate Lewin's argument from his discussion
of what others have said, he clearly argues that "[organization
matters for production" (p. 162) and consequently that
"organizational structure is a crucial aspect of the capital
structure in general" (p. 169). As all production processes are
both joint ventures and take time, production using complementary
heterogeneous resources is inherently uncertain. It also entails that
"the extent or value of the contribution of any [individual
resource] is wholly or partially indeterminate (difficult or impossible
to measure)" (p. 2). Integrating production processes in a firm is
thus primarily a "response to productive processes which have an
irreducible degree of indeterminateness (and arbitrariness)" (p.
158); the organizational structure of a firm can be seen as an
entrepreneurial innovation designed to solve these problems.
Lewin concludes the analysis of the purpose and nature of the
business firm by quoting Loasby saying that it is "a device for the
coordination and use of particular kinds of knowledge, including the
coordination of knowledge generation, by the imposition of an
interpretive framework" (1991, p. 59). In Lewin's words,
"[k]nowledge is a key concept in analyzing all productive activity
and its organization" (p. 175).
It may very well be the case that knowledge is an important aspect,
but it seems there is a whole world of problems in practically and
economically applying and using this knowledge in a production process
within the firm. That the firm is stated to be designed to solve the
problems offers but little guidance. Furthermore, the firm does not
exist in a vacuum, but exists in a market structure that is equally
dependent on using complementary resources in an efficient manner. Lewin
indirectly recognizes this fact through stating that the firm is an
aspect of the general capital structure. But how does the interaction
between firm and market affect the overall capital structure? And how
are firms and markets different in terms of capital? What is the effect
on resource allocation and prices? What is the role of the entrepreneur
and management within the firm? How do transactions within the firm
compare with transactions performed in the market? On what basis do
business leaders decide whether to integrate one more (or one less)
transaction? How do we explain (what are the causes of) outsourcing and
disintegration? Questions such as these are left for the reader to
figure out on their own; we know only that the firm is
"designed" to "solve" problems of knowledge. This
may or may not be very helpful in our analysis of the market, but one
gets the feeling that there is much more to be said.
Nevertheless, the Austrian view of capital as heterogeneous and
complementary--as a structure--offers an important and useful basis from
which puzzles in the economics of organizations can be approached (see
e.g., Foss and Klein, 2012). While this view has to some extent been
adopted in mainstream research, mainly in strategic management and
entrepreneurship, there is undoubtedly much value in explicating the
intricacies of such a framework. But it is not obvious in what sense
Lewin's particular approach provides meaningful insights for
solving the central questions still unanswered in management and the
economics of organizations. It is likely that the framework developed in
this book needs both elaboration and explication to be adoptable in
applied research.
Despite these sometimes puzzling shortcomings, Capital in
Disequilibrium is a work of great scholarship. Lewin masterfully
summarizes theories and perspectives to provide an extensive survey of
the literature related to capital. It is not a comprehensive survey,
which is obvious from the lack of references to, e.g., Austrian
production theory (Rothbard, von Strigl, and others), but an overview of
capital theories on which Lewin builds his own scholarship. Therefore,
it is also not limited to Austrian scholars or ideas, but includes
several discussions on mainstream thinking that is relevant for his
thesis.
While the text at times appears to be a collection of literature
summaries with a common theme, Lewin also offers several very
interesting reformulations of theories and reveals commonalities that
may not be obvious to most readers. The reformulation of parts of
Austrian capital theory in formalized notation in order to compare and
contrast--as well as show linkage--with mainstream thought offers great
insights into how the ideas are related.
As capital theory is core to economic analysis yet a severely
understudied topic--if not ignored or forgotten--this book is a welcome
and desperately needed contribution to the literature. It is worth
reading and should inspire many scholars, young and old, to pursue and
ponder questions on this important topic.
REFERENCES
Bohm-Bawerk, Eugen von. 1889. Positive Theory of Capital. South
Holland, Ill.: Libertarian Press. 1959.
Foss, Nicolai J. and Peter G. Klein. 2012. Organizing
Entrepreneurial Judgment: A New Approach to the Firm. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Kirzner, Israel M. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Loasby, Brian J. 1991. Equilibrium and Evolution: An Exploration of
Connecting Principles in Economics. Manchester: Manchester University
Press.
Mises, Ludwig von. 1949. Human Action: A Treatise on Economics. New
Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Per L. Bylund
Per Bylund (bylundp@missouri.edu), Ph.D., is adjunct professor of
entrepreneurship and strategic management in the Robert J. Trulaske, Sr.
College of Business at the University of Missouri.