The perils of preaching to the choir? Austrian economics journals and exchanges with the economics profession.
Sutter, Daniel
INTRODUCTION
Austrian economists have long been interested in the market for
academic publishing in addition to the performance of economies. Polanyi (1962) described how science resembles the market process with
decentralized decision making and feedback mechanisms to coordinate
activity, and his description applies to academic research generally.
The market for academic economic research exhibits free entry for
journals and decentralized acceptance or rejection decisions by journal
editors and book publishers. Scholarship, journals, and economists earn
reputation through a decentralized process as well. Economics
departments can hire whom they want without approval from a centralized authority, while citations play a role analogous to money in markets
(Thornton, 2004).
Many Austrian economists, however, have criticized the market for
economic research (Yeager, 1997, 2000; Block, 2000; Anderson, 2000). As
Laband and Tollison (2000) observe, the critics effectively claim market
failure in academic publishing. Laband and Tollison argue for the
efficiency of academic publishing and admonish Austrian economists for
not engaging the mainstream more aggressively:
Convincing other scholars that your scientific contribution is
substantial may indeed be difficult, especially if that
contribution is at odds with prevailing orthodoxy. However, it is
axiomatic that you cannot convince others if you do not communicate
with them. You may not convince others even when you do communicate
with them, but at least you've got a fighting chance. Like it or
not, professional communication in economics occurs primarily
through our mainstream journals. (p. 43) (1)
Laband and Tollison contend that the existence of specialized Austrian economics journals like the Quarterly Journal of Austrian
Economics (QJAE) and the Review of Austrian Economics (RAE) may
ultimately hurt Austrian economics. Specialized journals could
exacerbate the natural tendency Austrians (or any group) to speak only
to each other. The result could be an attitude of, "Who cares about
the American Economic Review? We will just chat among ourselves"
(p. 45). Over time, however, preaching to the choir wins no new
adherents, leaving Austrian economics marginalized (Rosen, 1997).
Specialized journals could result in a self-constraint problem for
Austrians: after having their arguments misconstrued and misunderstood at mainstream journals, Austrians might find the opportunity to have
their research reviewed on its merits to be as irresistible as the
Sirens' song.
Laband and Tollison effectively argue that specialized Austrian
journals may result in detrimental crowding-in. The existence of
specialty journals could benefit Austrian economics in several ways.
Refereed journals allow Austrian scholars to obtain the publications
required to pursue an academic career. Economists interested in Austrian
themes may be reluctant to specialize in Austrian economics without
specialty journals where this research (if good) can get published. And
specialty journals could also improve the quality of published
scholarship. Mainstream editors may not know appropriate referees for
the Austrian papers they receive, leading to a noisier (and not
necessarily biased) review process. The strongest papers may fail to be
published, resulting in a lower average quality of published research.
By contrast, the editors of the QJAE and RAE will be better able to
judge the value of Austrian scholarship and select more appropriate
referees. The higher average quality of published scholarship could
increase the likelihood that Austrian research changes mainstream
economists' minds. Finally, specialty journals can serve as focal
points for Austrian scholarship, lowering the cost of communication with
the mainstream. Specialty journals could lead to a stronger product more
likely to reach a mainstream audience, and not merely choir practice.
Crowding-in would likely have to be substantial to offset these
advantages of specialty journals.
I examine whether crowding-in has occurred in these Austrian
specialty journals. Specifically I first consider if authors publish
more frequently over time in the QJAE and RAE, as would be expected if
Austrians merely preached to the choir. I then focus on the economists
who published most frequently in these journals and investigate if the
proportion of their economics publications in the QJAE and RAE increases
over time. I also identify the economics journals most hospitable to
research by the top Austrian journal publishers. Finally I consider
citations to see if these Austrian publishers' papers in the QJAE
and RAE bear evidence of communication with mainstream economists.
Overall I find no evidence of crowding-in by Austrians. Authors did
not on average publish more frequently in the QJAE or RAE later in the
decade, either in total or as a proportion of their publications. In
fact, publications in each journal have become less concentrated over
time, consistent with increasing competitiveness of Austrian economics.
The mainstream journal papers of frequent Austrian publishers are cited
more on average than their QJAE or RAE papers, which suggests that
specialty journals inhibit communication with the rest of the
profession, but the difference results from a small number of highly
cited papers. Overall, the existence of specialty journals does not
appear to have resulted in Austrian economists merely engaging in choir
practice.
PUBLISHING IN AUSTRIAN JOURNALS
The Review of Austrian Economics began publication in 1987,
supported by the Mises Institute at Auburn University. In 1997, Springer took over publication of the RAE, and Peter Boettke became the
editor-in-chief. The Mises Institute inaugurated the Quarterly Journal
of Austrian Economics in 1998. These represent the two most prominent
journals in Austrian economics and are used in this study. (2)
I begin analysis in 2000, after two years for transition to the
two-journal environment. I first examine patterns of publication by
individual authors in the QJAE and RAE. To do so, I constructed a
spreadsheet from the journal's online tables of contents of all
papers published over the decade 2000-2009, along with the authors and
number of journal pages. I adjust an author's papers and pages
totals for coauthorship, so an x page paper with n coauthors counts as
1/n papers and x/n pages for each author. The two journals published 403
papers over the decade, 211 in the QJAE and 192 in the RAE, with 6,331
journal pages, divided almost equally between the two journals (3,184 in
the QJAE and 3,147 in the RAE). (3)
Table 1 reports the twenty most prolific authors based on papers
and pages published in the QJAE and RAE over the decade. Randall
Holcombe of Florida State University tops both lists, with 12 papers and
194 pages published. Walter Block and Jorg Guido Hulsmann occupy the
next two spots on both lists, with Block 2nd in papers with 10.67 and
Hulsmann 2nd in pages at 180.0. Eight authors published six or more
papers or 100 or more pages. Not surprisingly, paper and page totals are
highly correlated (+ 0.92), and 17 of the top authors based on papers
also rank in the top 20 for pages published.
To begin to evaluate the crowding-in thesis, I disaggregated the
paper and page totals by author into two five year periods, 2000-2004
and 2005-2009 to cancel out some of the year-to-year variation in
research output. If crowding-in occurs, authors should publish more
frequently in these journals during the second period. An economist who
published, for example, one paper in the QJAE or RAE over the first half
of the decade might submit all of their later papers to these journals.
The most frequent publishers in the Austrian journals over the first
half of the decade also published more in these journals during the
second half of the decade, as the correlations reported in Table 2
indicate. The correlation of page totals are around + 0.20 and the
Spearman rank correlations around + 0.45, so productive scholars tended
to remain productive. Nonetheless there are differences in publishing
over the periods.
The difference in papers or pages published between the two periods
provides evidence on crowding-in. A total of 155 authors published in
the QJAE or RAE between 2000-2004, compared with 173 over 2005-2009; 136
published more papers in the later period, 124 published fewer, and 13
published the same number.4 So only about half of the authors published
more in the Austrian journals later in the decade; the average Austrian
economist was not publishing dramatically more over time in the QJAE or
RAE. All QJAE and RAE authors over the decade include some individuals
who began their publishing careers after 2004 and others who retired
during the decade. A test of crowding-in would eliminate those who were
beginning or ending their careers during the decade and focus on the 55
individuals who published in the QJAE or RAE in both five-year windows.
Of this group, 18 increased and 24 decreased their paper total, with 13
publishing the same number of papers. (5) Less than half of these
scholars appear to be crowding-in.
The increase in the number of different authors suggests an
increase in the competitiveness of the Austrian journals over the past
decade. To explore this, Table 3 reports a Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index
(HHI) calculated using each author's market share of papers or
pages published in the QJAE or RAE over the two five year periods. Each
journal's HHI, based on either papers or pages, was lower in
2005-2009 than 2000-2004, and the HHI for the QJAE was higher than for
the RAE in each period. Publishing in the QJAE was notably more
concentrated over the first half of the decade than later, and this may
have been a consequence of authors being reluctant to submit papers to
the new journal until it had established a reputation. By the latter
half of the decade, the QJAE's HHI's were very close to the
RAE. Instead of hearing the same voices over and over, Austrian journals
have attracted research from a broader set of authors.
AUSTRIAN JOURNAL PUBLICATIONS AS A PROPORTION OF TOTAL SCHOLARSHIP
Publication totals show no evidence of crowding-in but, do not
control for Austrian economists' publishing in mainstream journals.
A more discriminating test of crowding-in would consider the
scholars' publications in Austrian journals as a proportion of
their total economics journal publications. To provide evidence on this
score, I turn to publications by top publishers in the Austrian journals
tracked in Econ Lit, an online database maintained by the American
Economics Association. I recorded career publications reported in the
"Journal Articles" category for each author of two or more
(coauthor adjusted) papers in the QJAE or RAE over the decade 2000-2009.
Econ Lit has omissions and limitations; for instance, it does not
include publications in journals in law, political science, sociology,
or other disciplines. On the other hand, Econ Lit-tracked journals
should measure communication between Austrians and mainstream
economists, which was Laband and Tollison's (2000) concern.
A total of 62 persons published two or more papers in the QJAE or
RAE. I tallied each person's author-adjusted publications in other
Econ Lit-tracked journals, over the decade as a whole and for the
2000-2004 and 2005-2009 periods. Table 4 ranks the most frequent
publishers in the Austrian journals by their total economics
publications (other Econ Lit plus QJAE and RAE papers) over the decade.
Table 4 also reports the percentage of each scholar's
publications in the Austrian journals over each five-year period, to see
if these authors were publishing a larger share of their research in
Austrian journals over time. The two most prolific publishers in this
group, Randall Holcombe and Walter Block, each published over 30
coauthor-adjusted papers during the decade, with 36 percent and 33
percent of their papers respectively appearing in the QJAE or RAE.
Neither scholar, however, trends toward publishing a larger proportion
of their research in the Austrian journals: Professor Holcombe's
share is essentially equal over the two periods, while Professor
Block's share falls from 45 percent to 23 percent. Eleven of the
twenty economists in Table 4 increased their percentage of economics
journal publications in the QJAE or RAE. Figure 1 extends the analysis
to all 53 authors who published two or more papers in the QJAE or RAE
and at least one economics paper in both halves of the decade. The
figure displays the distribution of the difference in proportion of
Austrian publications between 2005-2009 and 2000-2004. A positive
difference here indicates a greater concentration of the author's
publications in Austrian journals. Almost half of these authors had a
difference between -0.1 to +0.1, or essentially no change, while equal
numbers (15) had a decrease or increase in excess of 0.1. Individual
scholars show different patterns in their research as might be expected
of scholars at different stages of their careers, but on average, top
publishers in Austrian journals have not stopped trying to engage the
economics profession. (6)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The Econ Lit publications also reveal where the most frequent
publishers in Austrian journals publish. Arguably these are the
economics journals most sympathetic to Austrian-influenced research,
although without a careful examination (which I have not undertaken), it
may be problematic to characterize these papers as Austrian. I tallied
the number of author-adjusted papers published by the most frequent
contributors to the QJAE and RAE in Econ Lit tracked journals over the
decade. The most frequent contributors to the QJAE and RAE published
over 360 papers (adjusting for coauthorship) in 111 different journals
over the period. Table 5 reports the top twenty of these journals. The
last two columns of the table report each journal's rank based on
publications over the first and last halves of the decade, to indicate
any change in receptiveness to Austrian-themed research. The Independent
Review and Public Choice rank 1st and 2nd over the decade with about 35
papers (more than three per year), and also hold the top spots for each
half of the decade. The American Journal of Economics and Sociology is
3rd for the decade with just under 25 papers, while the 4th ranked
Journal of Private Enterprise published just over 15. The Journal des
Economistes et des Etudes Humaines ranks 5th for the decade, even though
it ceased publication in 2004. (7) The Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization and the Indian Journal of Economics and Business became
more receptive to research by Austrian authors over the decade, rising
from 29th and 72nd to 5th and 8th, while the Southern Economic Journal
appears to have become less receptive, falling from the top 10 to out of
the top 30. Table 5 does not include any of the very top ranked journals
but does include several highly regarded journals like Public Choice,
the Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, and the Southern
Economic Journal. Overall, the authors published in 9 of the 36 journals
used in the Scott and Mitias (1996) journal rankings, and 13 percent of
their papers appeared in these journals.
CITATIONS AND AUSTRIAN SCHOLARSHIP
Specialty journals may hurt the future of Austrian economics if
they inhibit communication with the rest of the profession. Whether
specialty journals inhibit communication is an empirical question,
because as discussed in the introduction, specialized journals could
improve the quality and marketing of Austrian scholarship. Citations to
papers in the QJAE and RAE provide evidence of communication with the
economics profession. I specifically examine citations to papers from
the first half of the last decade by the top publishers in the QJAE and
RAE. Because of the time lags involved for scholarship to influence
subsequent research and for these papers to be published, I limit
attention to papers that have been in print for several years. I include
only authors who had completed graduate school and published prior to
2000, because citations can be affected by an author's seniority
and standing. I use citations in the online Social Science Citation
Index (SSCI). The SSCI includes citations only in tracked journals, and
criteria for inclusion are somewhat murky (Klein with Chaing, 2004). The
SSCI excludes the QJAE and RAE, so these totals do not include citations
to the Austrian authors in the Austrian journals and thus fail to
measure the overall impact of Austrian scholarship. But SSCI citations
do measure if papers in Austrian journals are resulting in communication
with the broader economics profession. Citation counts are difficult to
interpret in isolation, and so I compare citations to the Austrian
authors' papers in the QJAE and RAE with their Econ Lit-tracked
publications between 2000 and 2004. Thus I can see if Austrian authors
were able to communicate with the profession as successfully when
publishing in the QJAE and RAE as when publishing in other economics
journals. (8) SSCI citation totals are as of August 2010. I adjust
citations for coauthorship, so a citation to a paper with n authors
counts as 1/n citation for each author. A coauthor adjustment is
necessary to prevent double counting of citations to papers authored by
Austrians, and for consistency I then adjust all citations in this
manner.
Table 6 reports citation statistics for Austrian authors for their
papers in the QJAE, RAE and other Econ Lit journals. The other economics
journal articles by these authors have been cited more often, at 2.27
per paper, compared to 1.97 for the RAE and 0.68 for the QJAE. A
difference in overall citations is not unexpected, as the SSCI omits
citations in the Austrian journals. Papers in the RAE come close to
equaling other economics journals, and a larger proportion of RAE papers
were cited at least once (63 percent), as reported in the final column
of Table 6. Normally, a small number of papers generate a large
proportion of citations, and this is true here as well. Ten papers by
these authors were cited 10 or more times and account for almost 40
percent of the total citations; only one of these highly cited papers
was in the Austrian journals. The lower citations per paper for the
Austrian journals results from a failure of any of these papers to
produce a large citation count in mainstream journals. With the papers
cited 10 or more times excluded, citations per paper in the RAE actually
exceed other economics journals (1.97 to 1.30).
Examining citations per paper for individual authors provides
further evidence on communications with the economics profession and
limits the influence of the handful of highly cited papers. If specialty
Austrian journals produce only within-group communication, most
authors' papers in mainstream journals will be cited more often
than their papers in the RAE and QJAE. I restrict attention here to top
publishers in Austrian journals who published in the QJAE or RAE and
other Econ Lit-tracked journals between 2000 and 2004. Thirty
individuals fit this description criterion, and 13 had more SSCI
citations per paper for their publications in the QJAE or RAE than for
their publications in other economics journals. Publishing in Austrian
journals does not appear to substantially reduce the likelihood that
authors communicate with mainstream economists.
Finally Table 7 reports the journals where the QJAE and RAE papers
examined here were most frequently cited. The table reports for each
journal total co-author-adjusted citations to the Austrian papers, the
number of these citations accounted for by the top Austrian publishers
(which may not reflect the true communication with the rest of the
profession), and the number of self-citations (papers by an author
citing another paper by the same author). The final row of Table 7
reports these totals for all of the SSCI citations to QJAE and RAE
papers in my analysis. Other publishers in Austrian journals account for
about one third of citations in mainstream journals, while less than 10
percent of the citations are self-citations. Four of the seven journals
most frequently citing Austrian journal papers also were among the
journals in Table 5 most receptive to Austrian authors, including Public
Choice, the American Journal of Economics and Sociology, the Independent
Review, and the Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. Thus
these journals appear hospitable to research on Austrian themes.
Austrian scholarship appears to be having as much of an impact on
scholarship in business and management as economics, as four of the 11
journals in Table 7 are business journals. Austrians are communicating
with outsiders, but scholars in business appear to be more interested in
their message.
CONCLUSIONS
Publications are essential to individual success in academe, and
specialty journals allow faculty to compile a publication record
required for tenure and promotion. Without the certainty of potential
journals to publish quality research, economists might be unwilling to
invest in research agendas on Austrian themes. But collectively, the
publications of scholars shape the future course of a school of thought.
Laband and Tollison (2000) argue that the existence of specialized
Austrian journals may be detrimental to the long-run health of Austrian
economics. The existence of specialty journals could result in
crowding-in if Austrian scholars choose to forego the frustration of
publishing in mainstream journals and have their research evaluated by
other Austrian economists. Austrian economists may pursue an
individually rational strategy which results in little communication
with the rest of the profession, consigning Austrian economics to the
periphery. In essence, Laband and Tollison suggest that specialty
journals create a prisoner's dilemma for a dissident school of
thought.
Whether crowding-in occurs is an empirical question, and I have
examined some relevant evidence on publishing by Austrian economists.
Economists have not increased their frequency of publications in the
QJAE or RAE over the past decade, either in absolute terms or as a
proportion of their publications in economics journals. Austrian
journals appear to have become more competitive over time, attesting to
the health of Austrian economics. The top publishers in Austrian
journals continue to engage the economics profession by publishing in
more mainstream journals. Publications in the QJAE and RAE also result
in exchanges with other economists, as indicated by citations in
mainstream journals by non-Austrian authors. Papers from the QJAE and
RAE do not get cited as often as these authors' papers in other
economics journals, but this is because Austrian papers appear less
likely to produce large SSCI counts. Overall, any crowding-in that might
occur seems inconsequential compared with the benefits specialty
journals provide for Austrian economics.
A question left unanswered here for future research is the role of
specialty journals in the health of a field or school of thought. Laband
and Tollison (2000) can be read as arguing against specialty journals,
and not just for Austrian economists. Yet specialty journals serve as
focal destinations for economists interested in learning more about
Austrian (or Institutional or Marxist) economics, and can improve the
average quality of published articles. Whether these factors offset any
resulting insularity is ultimately an empirical question. Specialized
journals help the practitioners in a field or adherents of a school of
thought generate the peer-reviewed publications needed for success as an
academic. The proliferation of specialty journals across economics in
recent decades demonstrates a macro trend toward specialization or even
microspecialization. Specialty journals appear to have been instrumental
in the growth of fields like public choice, and yet the Journal of
Economic Issues has not prevented the decline of institutional
economics. The insularity versus quality calculus may differ for a
specialized field of economics versus a school of thought. Future
research could investigate exactly when specialized journals lead to
excessive insularity.
REFERENCES
Anderson, William L. 2000. "Austrian Economics and the
'Market Test': A Comment on Laband and Tollison."
Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 3, no. 3: 63-73.
Beaulier, Scott, and J. Robert Subrick. 2010. "Understanding
Academic Journal Market Failure: The Case of Austrian Economics."
Eastern Economic Journal, forthcoming.
Block, Walter. 2000. "Austrian Journals: A Critique of Rosen,
Yeager, Laband and Tollison, and Vedder and Gallaway." Quarterly
Journal of Austrian Economics 3, no. 2: 45-61.
Klein, Daniel, with Eric Chiang. 2004. "The Social Science
Citation Index: A Black Box--with an Ideological Bias?" Econ
Journal Watch 1, no. 1: 134-165.
Laband, David, and Robert D. Tollison. 2001. "On Secondhandism
and Scientific Appraisal." Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics
3, no. 1: 43-48.
Polanyi, Michael. 1962. "The Republic of Science: Its
Political and Economic Theory." Minerva 1: 54-74.
Rosen, Sherwin. 1997. "Austrian and Neoclassical Economics:
Any Gains From Trade?" Journal of Economic Perspectives 11, no. 4:
139-152.
Scott, Loren C., and Peter M. Mitias. 1996. "Trends in
Rankings of Economics Departments in the U. S.: An Update."
Economic Inquiry 34, no. 2: 378-400.
Sutter, Daniel. 2007. "Austrian Economics and the Market Test
Reconsidered," Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 10, no. 1:
49-62.
Thornton, Mark. 2004. "Does Academic Publishing Pass the Real
Market Test?" Public Choice 120: 41-61.
Yeager, Leland. 1997. "Austrian Economics, Neoclassicism, and
the Market Test." Journal of Economic Perspectives 11, no. 4:
153-165.
--. 2000. "The Tactics of Secondhandism." Quarterly
Journal of Austrian Economics 3, no. 3: 51-61.
(1) The critics contend that bias against Austrian methods and
topics makes publishing in mainstream journals virtually impossible. For
further analysis of the market test for Austrian economics see Sutter
(2007). Thornton (2004) and Beaulier and Subrick (2010) also question
whether Austrian economics has demonstrated the inefficiency of the
market for economic research.
(2) The annual volume Advances in Austrian Economics provides a
regular outlet for Austrian scholarship, but as the editors and subject
vary from year to year, Advances does not provide the same type of
outlet for scholarship as the QJAE and RAE. Other outlets like
Libertarian Papers and the Journal of Markets and Morality, and several
history of economic thought journals often publish Austrian papers, so
the QJAE and RAE certainly do not constitute the entirety of
contemporary Austrian scholarship.
(3) Book reviews and editorials are omitted from these totals.
(4) A total of 140 authors increased and 133 decreased their pages
published.
(5) Twenty-two (22) of these authors published more (fewer) pages
in 2005-2009 than 2000-2004.
(6) Both of the journals examined here published special issues
during the decade, and as a referee notes, contributions to a special
issue might be solicited and not reflect an author's interest in
submitting to these journals unprompted. Overall 113 papers from the
journals appeared in special issues or symposia, or 28 percent of all
papers. I tallied coauthor-adjusted publications in these special issues
and they appear to be a representative sample of all contributors based
on frequency of publication. Overall contributors to special issues who
were also frequent contributors published a few more papers over the
first than second halves of the decade, and published 36 percent of
their economics papers over the decade in the QJAE or RAE.
(7) The journal began publication again in 2010 as a Berkeley
Electronic Press journal.
(8) The other Econ Lit-tracked journals in which Austrian authors
have published seem to be the most plausible places for these papers to
be published if the authors sought more mainstream outlets.
Dr. Sutter (dsutter@troy.edu) is Charles G. Koch Professor of
Economics at the Manuel H. Johnson Center for Political Economy, Troy
University, Troy, Ala. The author thanks two referees for helpful
comments on this paper, and claims entire responsibility for all errors
or omissions.
Table 1. Top Publishers in Austrian
Journals, 2000-2009
Rank Scholar Papers
1 Randall Holcombe 12.00
2 Walter Block 10.67
3 Jorg Guido Hulsmann 10.00
4 Mark Thornton 8.50
5 Joseph Salerno 7.33
6 William Barnett 6.77
7 Peter Boettke 6.08
8 Robert Mulligan 6.00
9 Sanford Ikeda 5.50
10 Bryan Caplan 4.50
11 John Bratland 4.00
T11 Hans-Hermann Hoppe 4.00
T11 Peter Lewin 4.00
T11 Larry Sechrest 4.00
15 John P. Cochran 3.83
16 Christopher Coyne 3.67
T17 William Anderson 3.50
T17 William Butos 3.50
T17 Steven Horwitz 3.50
T17 Richard Wagner 3.50
Rank Scholar Pages
1 Randall Holcombe 194.0
2 Jorg Guido Hulsmann 180.0
3 Walter Block 148.3
4 Robert Mulligan 138.0
5 William Barnett 114.3
6 Joseph Salerno 114.0
7 Mark Thornton 110.0
8 John Bratland 102.0
9 Peter Lewin 88.0
10 Larry Sechrest 74.0
11 John P. Cochran 68.3
12 Bruce Benson 66.0
13 Peter Boettke 63.7
14 Steven Horwitz 62.5
15 Sanford Ikeda 62.0
16 Philipp Bagus 59.0
17 Bryan Caplan 58.0
18 Peter Kurrild-Klitgaar 57.0
19 Christopher Coyne 55.5
T20 William Butos 55.0
T20 Nicolai Foss 55.0
Table 2. Correlations of Individual
Publications, 2000-04 versus 2005-09
Totals Ranks
Papers +0.231 +0.497
Pages +0.168 +0.434
Standard correlations and Spearman rank
correlations of individual authors'
papers and pages published in the QJAE
and RAE over the two periods.
Table 3. Concentration of Austrian Publishing
2000-04 2005-09
QJAE Paers 236.4 150.3
QJAE Pages 275.5 169.0
RAE Papers 153.5 143.1
RAE Pages 168.5 155.2
Numbers are a Herfhindahl-Hirschmann Index
calculated using shares of publications and
pages published by individuals authors in
each journal over each period.
Table 4. Trends Among top Austrian Journal Publishers
Scholar Total % Austrian, % Austrian,
Papers 2000-04 2005-09
Randall Holcombe 33.17 35.6 36.7
Walter Block 32.25 44.6 22.7
Bryan Caplan 27.00 14.7 20.0
Peter Boettke 26.08 33.3 16.6
Daniel Sutter 21.50 7.2 19.6
Mark Thornton 19.50 41.5 46.2
Nicolai Foss 17.67 18.5 12.0
Richard Wagner 17.50 7.1 28.6
David Levy 15.33 18.2 10.2
Tyler Cowen 15.17 14.6 18.0
Steven Horwitz 15.00 42.9 6.3
Christopher Coyne 14.50 20.0 26.4
Jorg Guido Hulsmann 14.00 81.8 33.3
Joseph Salerno 12.33 57.1 62.5
Robert Mulligan 12.00 45.5 53.8
Enrico Colombatto 11.50 22.2 40.0
Roger Garrison 10.50 9.1 18.2
Bruce Benson 10.17 21.4 18.2
Leland Yeager 10.00 42.9 0.0
William Barnett 9.83 81.0 65.7
Publication totals include papers published in the QJAE and RAE
plus publications in other journals tracked by Econ Lit.
Table 5. Other Economics Journals Publishing Authors from
the Austrian Journals
Rank Journal Papers, Rank Rank
00-09 00-04 05-09
1 Independent Review 35.00 2 1
2 Public Choice 33.50 1 2
3 American Journal of 24.67 4 3
Economics &
Sociology
4 Journal of Private 15.50 7 4
Enterprise
5 Journal des 13.50 3 T81
Economistes et des
Etudes Humaines
6 Cato Journal 11.33 5 9
7 History of Political 11.00 12 7
Economy
T8 Journal of Economic 10.33 29.5 5
Behavior &
Organization
T8 Int. Journal of 10.33 15.5 6
Socio-Economics
10 Journal of Labor 9.00 6 15.5
Research
11 Review of Political 8.67 8.5 14
Economy
12 Econ Journal Watch 7.83 19 10
13 Constitutional 6.67 23.5 11
Political Economy
14 Critical Review 6.50 23.5 12
15 Eastern Economic 6.33 10 25
Journal
16 Humanomics 6.25 23.5 12
17 Indian Journal of 6.16 72 8
Economics & Business
T18 Southern Economic 6.00 8.5 31.5
Journal
T18 Public Finance 6.00 12 25
Review
T20 European Journal of 5.00 29.5 15.5
Political Economy
T20 Journal of the 5.00 15.5 25
History of Economic
Thought
Table 6. Citations of Austrian Authors' Papers
Percentage
of Papers
Journal of Cites per with Zero
Publication Papers Cites Paper Cites
Quarterly Journal of 55.0 43.0 0.68 65.5%
Austrian Economics
Review of Austrian 33.0 65.0 1.97 37.1%
Economics
Other Econ Lit 155.5 353.7 2.27 54.8%
Tracked Journals
Table 7. Journals citing Papers in Austrian Journals
Journal Citations Citations by Self-
Austrian Citations
Authors
Public Choice 7 6 0
American Journal of 6 5 4
Economics & Sociology
Independent Review 6 3 0
Small Business Economics 6 1 0
Critical Review 5 0 0
Journal of Economic 5 1 0
Behavior & Organization
Journal of Business Ethics 5 1 0
Journal of Management 4 1 0
Studies
Organization Studies 4 2 0
Cambridge Journal of 3 2 1
Economics
Politicka Ekonomie
All Papers 98 32 8