Fractional reserve free banking: some quibbles.
Bagus, Philipp ; Howden, David
INTRODUCTION
What is the ideal monetary system? This is one of the most
important questions of our age. To address this question, George Selgin
(1988) makes an elaborate case for a fractional reserve free banking
system. (1) Selgin's argument is especially noteworthy because he
approaches this question from an economic point of view. (2) He argues
that 100 percent reserve banking (as well as central banking) has
economically detrimental effects because it cannot maintain monetary
equilibrium, thus leading to costly and unavoidable recessions. (3)
Selgin's synthesis of traditional Austrian and monetary
disequilibrium theories to justify a free banking system brought new
aspects to the debate concerning the ideal monetary system.
While other authors have provided critiques of fractional reserve
free banking (hereafter free banking) regarding economic consequences
(Hoppe, 1994, Huerta de Soto, 2006, Hulsmann, 1996), the thesis of
Selgin et al. has not been adequately scrutinized. It is one thing to
point out the detrimental consequences of fractional reserve banking yet
quite another to show that a fractional reserve free banking system is
not required to maintain monetary equilibrium and that the supposedly
stabilizing mechanisms of a fractional reserve banking system are, in
fact, destabilizing. The economic necessity for and consequences of a
fractional reserve free banking system represent a gap in the literature
that requires further review and analysis.
This study examines the remaining economic problems of a fractional
reserve free banking system while abstaining from a discussion of legal
and ethical issues. We focus our critique on Selgin (1988) due to its
clarity and completeness. We demonstrate that fractional reserve free
banking not only fails to restore the monetary equilibrium it alleges to
create, but also generates effects that most free banking advocates
consider detrimental.
MONETARY EQUILIBRIUM AND FREE BANKING
Microeconomic coordination failures caused by monetary
disequilibria were first systematically outlined by Herbert Davenport
(1913), Clark Warburton (1946, 1966), Robert Greenfield (1994) and the
series of articles contained in Yeager (1997). Selgin (1988) first
elaborated the combination of these disequilibria with the doctrine of
fractional reserve free banking. Selgin's exposition proved so
compelling that within several years, Horwitz (1996, p. 288) opined
that: "The Austrian theory [of the trade cycle] and the monetary
disequilibrium approach can be seen as explaining the consequences that
follow from the two possible cases (inflation and deflation) in which
monetary equilibrium is not maintained." The Austrian theory of the
business cycle (ABCT) developed in Vienna was seen as a more or less
compatible doctrine with the American monetary disequilibrium approach.
Monetary equilibrium is defined as "the state of affairs that
prevails when there is neither an excess demand for money nor an excess
supply of it at the existing level of prices" (Selgin, 1988, p.
54). Selgin asserts that a fractional reserve free banking system
adjusts the supply of money to changes in its demand, keeping MV
constant in the famous equation of exchange. When money holders increase
their demand for money, they are really increasing their desire to hold
bank liabilities (i.e., money substitutes). Accordingly, in an advanced
free banking system the demand for money would be the demand for inside
money or money substitutes, as commodity money would not circulate. As a
result, individuals write fewer checks on their cash balances or retain
the notes of a particular bank longer when the demand for money
increases.
By way of example, assume that a bank's clearing debits equal
its clearing credits before an increase in the demand for money occurs.
An increase in the demand for money issued by a certain bank causes a
reduction in adverse clearings against the bank. Consequently, bank
reserves increase as the clearing balance turns positive. An increased
demand by the public to hold its notes and deposits entices a
profit-maximizing bank to expand credit, thus drawing down its excess
reserves. The same process occurs when the general demand for money
increases. Gross clearings are reduced when depositors write fewer
checks or redeem fewer notes, thus reducing the bank's need to hold
precautionary reserves (Selgin, 1988, p. 66). Banks may then profitably
expand credit until their demand for reserves corresponds with their
supply of reserves. In sum, increases in the demand for money lead to
excess reserves as the volume of bank clearings falls. In such a
scenario, according to Selgin, banks can expand credit to accommodate
this increased demand for money.
The reverse clearing process unfolds when the demand for money
decreases. As depositors present checks and notes that previously
circulated to their issuers, an increase in gross clearings occurs.
Banks compensate by increasing their precautionary reserves by retiring
loans and investments. A credit contraction, thus, equalizes the supply
of money with its decreased demand.
Selgin asserts that this process restores and maintains monetary
equilibrium more efficiently than its alternatives, e.g., exogenous money supply changes by a central bank, or via changes in money's
purchasing power. Changes in money's purchasing power also satisfy
changes in the demand to hold money (i.e., the demand to hold real cash
balances). Increases in the demand for real cash balances result when
people abstain from spending, causing prices to fall. Conversely, as the
demand for real cash balances decreases, people spend their cash
balances accordingly and cause prices to rise. Selgin (1988, p. 53)
acknowledges this alternative adjustment mechanism and states that
long-run changes in money's purchasing power can satisfy changes in
the demand for money. He cautions, however, that "short-run
corrections in the real money supply require changes in the nominal
quantity of money" (1988, p. 54). In other words, changes in the
purchasing power required to satisfy changes in the demand to hold money
work only in the long run. Selgin gives two main reasons for this
disparity.
First, prices are rigid in the short run, creating a potential
excess demand or supply of money. More specifically, the downward
rigidities of certain prices will increase the demand for money leading
to a recession that is a "mirror image" of the traditional
Austrian business cycle. This is caused by higher interest rates than
the demand to hold money would normally dictate (Horwitz, 1996, pp. 291,
303). (4)
Second, there may be a "monetary misconception" in the
case of an increase in the demand for money that makes prices fall
(Selgin, 1988, p. 55). Each entrepreneur individually regards any
decline in his revenues as a decline in the profitability of his
particular business and reduces his output accordingly. A general
downturn ensues as entrepreneurs in general fall prey to this
misconception. Consequently, many free bankers believe that "a
banking system that promotes deflation disrupts economic activity"
(Selgin 1988, p. 56). Free bankers suffer from what Mark Thornton (2003)
coins "apoplithorismosphobia": a fear of deflation (or, at
least, a special strain of it). (5) They consequently welcome the
inflation provided by the fractional reserve system that, due to its
clearing mechanism, allegedly provides adequate levels of inflation at
just the right moments.
Selgin claims to have proven that a fractional reserve system is
not only harmless but is also even necessary to maintain monetary
equilibrium. The system responds to any increase in the demand for money
with a corresponding increase in the money supply. Price declines are
obstructed and recession summarily avoided.
LIMITS TO CREDIT EXPANSION IN A FREE BANKING SYSTEM
Free bankers claim that a free banking system best maintains
monetary equilibrium. One significant aspect of this equilibrium is that
an increase in the demand for money allows for credit expansion.
Consequently, any free banking system must be defended against the
charge that it enables an unlimited credit expansion when the expansion
is coordinated. Through cooperation and coordination, banks can mitigate
their adverse clearing balances and remove the brake stopping individual
banks from unduly expanding. With every bank expanding at the same
rhythm no individual bank loses reserves. Selgin (1988, p. 54) asserts
that in an advanced free banking system, notes are continually utilized
and not redeemed into commodity money. Consequently, the public's
redemption demands into commodity money cannot serve as a limit to
credit expansion.
In defense, Selgin comes up with a further limit on credit
expansion. A bank's demand for reserves consists of two components:
"average net reserve demand" (which is the anticipated total
difference of clearing debits and clearing credits in a period and which
tends to zero in a coordinated expansion) and the "precautionary
reserve demand" (Selgin, 1988, p. 72). Banks hold precautionary
reserves because the exact sum of the total of debits and credits is
uncertain during a particular clearing session. The average net reserve
demand will not increase during a coordinated expansion (as it nets to
zero). However, the growth in total clearings will bring about a higher
variance of clearing balances (both debits and credits). Banks respond
by increasing their precautionary reserve requirements, thereby placing
a limit on a coordinated credit expansion (Selgin, 1988, p. 82).
There are several reasons to doubt that the heightened
precautionary reserve requirement would effectively limit a coordinated
credit expansion.
First, negative clearing balances would not necessarily imply a
loss of reserves when banks cooperate. A bank with a positive clearing
balance could just voluntarily refrain from redeeming notes from a bank
with a negative clearing balance. These balances could instead be used
as reserves for their own expansion. Moreover, an interbank market could
develop where banks with negative clearing balances could borrow from
banks with positive clearing balances. Interest paid and received for
such loans would cancel out in the long run. Such an institution of
implicit or explicit arrangements concerning the short term interbank
financing of clearing deficits would make precautionary reserves
essentially obsolete.
A second method for banks to coordinate an unlimited credit
expansion is to lengthen the clearing period. For clearing periods as
short as an hour, or even a day, there may be important clearing balance
divergences (whether positive or negative), even within a coordinated
expansion. Prolonged clearing periods will lower any balance
discrepancies when banks coordinate their expansion. No bank will lose
reserves during a coordinated credit expansion in the long run.
Precautionary reserves are only necessary to mitigate reserve losses in
the short run. Positive and negative clearing balances will increasingly
offset each other in direct relationship to the length of the clearing
period. If the coordinating banks agree to clear debits and credits over
a longer period, say, every week, month, or year, banks may reduce
precautionary reserves accordingly.
The cooperation of banks might become so close that they account
for their debits and credits without physically clearing adverse
balances. (6) With a lengthened or unlimited clearing period, credit
expansion is limited only by the redemption demands of the public that
Selgin assumes to be nonexistent in a mature free banking system.
There is a final reason why banks might actually reduce their
precautionary reserves during a credit expansion. A rising money supply
during a credit expansion increases both the negotiability of bank
assets and, more importantly, their prices (Juan Ramon Rallo, 2009a).
Consequently, when banks engage in a coordinated credit expansion,
higher clearing balance variances do not invoke a greater danger of
illiquidity as bank assets rise in price and increase in liquidity.
Banks can use these more valuable and saleable assets to compensate for
any adverse clearing balances.
DEMAND FOR FIDUCIARY MEDIA IS NOT EXOGENOUS TO THE BANKING SYSTEM
Selgin starts his analysis by assessing changes in the demand for
money, not distinguishing between the demand for commodity money (money
proper) and money substitutes (Rallo, 2009b). Selgin's base
assumption is that all commodity money is deposited in the banking
system and remains there or, at least, that the demand for money proper
is constant. Nevertheless, there is an important difference between
commodity money and money substitutes or bank liabilities.
Bank liabilities (money substitutes) derive their value from money
proper. Bank liabilities can lose their value or liquidity while money
proper retains these qualities. Thus, the demands for money proper and
bank liabilities need not necessarily trend in the same direction.
During economic crises the demand for money proper generally increases
while the demand for bank liabilities decreases, as the former is
regarded as safer than the latter. In extreme situations there may even
be a flight from bank liabilities if the financial system finds itself
in significant illiquidity troubles: this is the common case of a bank
run.
The fractional reserve banking system actually causes booms that
turn to busts because of its inherent ability to expand credit. (7)
During a post-boom recession, bank assets lose value leading to a loss
of confidence by the holders of bank liabilities. At this point the
demand for money substitutes tends to decrease, as holders sell them in
exchange for safer money proper. The fractional reserve banking system
is the cause of the instability in the demand for money proper. To
assume a constant demand for money proper cannot be a starting point to
analyze a system that endogenously changes it.
Free bankers not only fail to distinguish between the demand for
money proper and that of money substitutes, but also between the various
reasons that money is demanded. By its macroeconomic approach, the
analysis of the demand for money conceals important microeconomic
processes. (8) The increased demand for bank liabilities may result from
a multitude of different causes.
When a company gets commercial paper discounted by a bank, this
company is effectively demanding bank liabilities. It exchanges its
commercial paper against a demand deposit liability at the bank. When a
company issues a 20-year bond, and deposits the receipts at a bank, the
company is effectively demanding bank liabilities. When a deposit holder
withdraws less money from his bank account during a certain period, he
is increasing his demand for bank liabilities. When a company issues
equity and deposits the receipts at a bank, the company is demanding
bank liabilities. The motivations for these actions are very different
and at times asymmetrical. The company that issues the 20-year bond
wants to spend more money while the deposit holder that withdraws less
money wants to spend less money.
Fractional reserve free banking analysis advocates altering the
money supply to counter changes in the demand to hold money, thus
preventing a sluggish price adjustment process. (9) Not all changes in
the demand to hold money stem from supposed imbalances between
money's equilibrium and actual purchasing powers. By not properly
distinguishing between the very reasons that individuals change their
demand for money, fractional reserve free bankers are left with a
glaring theoretical hole: when should banks alter the monetary base, and
how are they signaled that this should be done.
The free bankers' analysis of the demand for money does not
explain the reasons why the demand for money increases, instead treating
it as an exogenous variable. The demand for money tends to change
noticeably as perceived uncertainty changes, such as during times of
wars, natural catastrophes or economic crises. By not discussing the
reasons for changes in the demand for money, free bankers comfortably
set aside any discussion as to the causes of crises. In fact, the credit
expansion that a free banking system can carry out may cause
artificially low interest rates and an unsustainable lengthening of the
structure of production. (10) When this artificial expansion is
reversed, a recession sets in and the demand to hold money tends to
increase. Thus, the free banking system itself may cause an increase in
the demand for money. Paradoxically, this increase in demand is
presented as a problem to which the free banking system itself is the
solution.
Free bankers repeat the error of the old Banking School when they
treat the demand for money as exogenous to the banking system. Banking
School theorists, such as John Fullarton (1844), argued that the
"needs for trade" determine the demand for money. Expanding
credit in response to a higher demand for money is reckoned to not only
cause no harm but to also aid economic expansion. Banking School
theorists and free bankers alike neglect the fact that the actions of
the banking system can endogenously increase the demand for credit
through reduced interest rates. The institutional setup of the banking
system influences the demand for bank liabilities. Demand for future
goods is not independent of their price. By lowering loan rates or
softening credit conditions, a fractional reserve banking system can
increase the demand for credit virtually without limit (Huerta de Soto,
2006, pp. 682-683).
Moreover, the artificial boom caused by credit expansion may lead
to an increased demand for bank liabilities. As the boom fuels optimism
as nominal wealth increases, rising asset prices provide increased
collateral against which an increased demand in bank liabilities can be
issued (Bagus, 2008). When the banking system satisfies the demand for
fiduciary media through credit expansion, the boom feeds upon itself.
CONFUSION BETWEEN SAVINGS AND THE DEMAND FOR CASH HOLDINGS
Selgin states that the willingness to hold money is the willingness
to save, and that holding bank liabilities ultimately means acting as a
lender of credit (1988, p. 55). Similarly, Horwitz (1992, p. 135) states
that
Savers supply real loanable funds based on their endowments and
intertemporal preferences. Banks serve as intermediaries to
redirect savings to investors via money creation. Depositors give
banks custody of their funds, and banks create loans based on these
deposits. The creation (supply) of money corresponds to a supply of
funds for investment use by firms.
Horwitz suggests that the creation of deposits increases the supply
of savings, as depositors are lenders of real loanable funds. In other
words, the mere creation of credit and the corresponding new deposits
constitute an increase in real savings. Yet the creation of fiduciary
media is not equivalent to an increase in real savings necessary to
sustain a more roundabout production process. Real saving implies an
abstention from consumption, while the production of fiduciary media
does not; fiduciary media may be, and are, created ex nihilo. Holding
newly created money is not an increase in real saving. To think
otherwise confuses the nominal money supply with real resources. If the
U.S. government would decree to add a zero to every bank note and demand
deposit, people would very likely be willing to hold a larger nominal
balance of bank liabilities after the decree. However, this would not
constitute an increase in real savings.
Creating money to offset an increase in the demand for money or a
decrease in its velocity does not create new real resources. Increased
monetary savings does not mean that there is additional real savings.
Real savings are required to sustain the factors of production during
the production process. Increases in the money supply serve to create
only an illusion of wealth. (11)
Horwitz (1996, pp. 291-292) argues that holding fiduciary media is
equivalent to saving, relying on their supposed equivalence to outline a
"mirror image" Austrian business cycle. He argues that an
increase in the demand for money implies an increase in real savings. If
banks do not expand credit and let interest rates fall to reflect the
increase in savings, interest rates will be too high: an artificial
shortening of the structure of production results.
People hold money because it is the most liquid good and mitigates
future uncertainty. Money's utility in this role largely determines
its demand. In this respect, the complete availability of money is
crucial for it to mitigate future uncertainty. A "suspension
clause" on bank notes as advocated by free bankers (White, 1984;
Selgin, 1988, p. 137; Selgin and White, 1994, p. 1726, 1997) changes the
availability of money and forces depositors to save for the duration of
the suspension, i.e., depositors are forced to grant an obligatory loan
to the bank.
Conversely, when people have a sufficient uncertainty hedge via
their deposits, they may attempt to increase their monetary wealth by
investing. They do this directly as an investment, or indirectly by
loaning the money to someone else who desires to invest directly. The
level of investment that an economy can successfully complete depends on
its available savings. Investment projects are only carried out to
completion if a sufficient quantity of real production factors has been
made available by abstaining from consumption.
The time horizon in which people are willing to sacrifice and
reduce consumption is important for investment sustainability. Hence,
there are important differences between distinct savings instruments (or
investments): as examples, cash holdings, an equity investment, a
3-month loan, or a 30-year bond. All of these represent important forms
of savings/investments, but they involve different durations, liquidity
and risk.
The disparate maturities of savings differentiate sums of monetary
savings from each other. Horwitz (1996, p. 299) abstracts from the
duration of savings, stating that "demanding bank liabilities is an
act of savings." For him, a bank deposit of $1,000 or an investment
of $1,000 in a 30-year bond releases identical savings to be invested in
long-term projects. Can a long-term investment--a 30-year mortgage, for
example--be issued against either of these savings with equal effects on
the structure of production? The unequivocal answer is: no (Bagus and
Howden, 2010b).
Changes in time preference rates are independent of the demand to
hold money as a cash balance (Hulsmann, 2009). The corollary that arises
is that the demand for money can change without a corresponding change
in either the time preference rates or the consumption-savings
relationship.
People can abstain, for example, from reinvesting their resources
by amortizing their investments. A relative shift away from investment
projects (i.e., future goods) has occurred which increases both cash
balances and time preference. Free bankers argue that any increase in
the demand to hold bank liabilities constitutes an increase in savings.
Following the logic of their argument, they must maintain that the
divestment of capital (i.e., the tearing down of machinery and
factories, etc.), in order to increase cash balances is a sign of an
increased demand for money and represents an increase in savings.
Accordingly, banks could and should expand credit when their reserves
increase so that investors can commence investment projects (i.e.,
buying machines and building factories). (12)
This credit expansion will not correspond to individuals'
desires. Real cash balances have increased either in response to the
perception of increased uncertainty, or in preparation of future
consumption opportunities. At the same time, they have divested,
increasing the proportion of their consumption relative to real
investment spending, i.e., their time preference has increased. Carrying
out a credit expansion to entice new investments would then lead to
malinvestments, as the real quantity of savings available to sustain
investment projects has not increased.
It is also possible that the demand for cash holdings increases
while time preference decreases: people can abstain from consumption in
order to add to their cash balances. This constitutes an increase in
savings and allows the structure of production to lengthen (Huerta de
Soto, 1996, pp. 448-449). Factors of production are liberated and made
available for investment projects. The effect is the same as if the
investment were made directly into these projects. As Mises (1998, p.
519) summarizes it:
Whenever an individual devotes a sum of money to saving instead of
spending it for consumption, the process of saving agrees perfectly
with the process of capital accumulation and investment. It does
not matter whether the individual saver does or does not increase
his cash holding. The act of saving always has its counterpart in a
supply of goods produced and not consumed, of goods available for
further production activities. A man's savings are always embodied
in concrete capital goods.
A further alternative is that changes in the demand for cash
holdings do not affect time preference rates at all: investment and
consumption spending can be reduced by equal proportions with no
systematic change to time preference.
The demand to hold real cash balances can decrease while time
preference increases, decreases or remains the same, depending on how
the reduction of cash balances affects the ratio between investment and
consumption expenditures. There is no necessary relation between time
preference rates and the demand for money. Furthermore, changes in
neither the demand nor supply of money are necessarily related to
changes in interest rates. Changes in the supply or demand for money can
affect interest rates in the short-run if they act through credit
markets (for instance, during a credit expansion). Thus, the artificial
reduction of interest rates during a credit expansion is the result of
an inflated money supply through the credit markets. Banks can only
place additional loans via interest rate reductions.
Increases in the supply of money proper (i.e., gold production
under a gold standard) does not necessarily have the same effect. Owners
of gold mines may just bid up the prices of the goods and services they
buy, keeping interest rates steady. Cantillon effects and wealth
redistribution will result, but no systematic change in interest rates
need occur. (13)
The confusion between increases in savings and cash holdings is a
confusion between stock and flow variables. Saving is a flow
variable--the part of income that is not consumed. Cash holdings
(savings) represent a stock in existence. Cash holdings do not represent
saving. One may actually increase cash holdings by saving less (and
consuming more), for example, spending a smaller portion of the
available income on investments (or selling investments in order to
consume). Fractional reserve banking leads to a change in the stock
variable (cash holdings) that may create the artificial perception of a
change in the flow variable (saving). This misperception is not without
potential negative consequences as entrepreneurs may be misled into
committing malinvestments. (14)
There is yet another mystery inherent in the idea that holding bank
liabilities amounts to saving. Why would holding money proper not be
savings? Moreover, if holding money proper were an act of saving, why
would it lead to prohibitively high interest rates?
Let us assume that individual A holds a quantity of money proper,
such as gold coins (or fiat paper money), under his mattress for
safekeeping. Now he decides to transfer the coins to a bank--there has
been a crime in his neighborhood recently and he regards the bank as a
more secure warehouse than his mattress. Following the free
bankers' reasoning, bank reserves and the willingness to hold bank
liabilities now increase, and banks can and should expand credit in
response. Yet there is no increase in A's savings in this example;
the coins (cash holdings) have just changed location.
The expansion of credit leads to artificially low interest rates.
"Hoarding" unaccompanied by credit expansion does not lead to
artificially high interest rates. Increases in hoarded money that stem
from a reduction in consumption expenditures cause the interest rate to
decline; prices of consumption goods will fall. The price spread in the
time structure of production between buying and selling proceeds is
reduced accordingly (Rothbard, 2004, pp. 367-452). The demand for
present goods falls relative to the demand for future goods, causing
interest rates to fall.
The argument that an increase in the demand for money amounts to an
increase in savings (or the rate of saving) is essential for the alleged
need of a fractional reserve banking system. Yet there is no systematic
relationship between savings and the demand for money. Fractional
reserve banks face an identification problem because increases in
reserves can be caused by abstentions of both consumption and
investment. There is no way for banks to know if an increase in reserves
means that people are abstaining from consumption or divesting from
investment projects. Free bankers must still answer this mystery: how
can banks consistently discern the causes of changes in reserve levels
(either increases or decreases). Lacking an answer to this question,
free bankers must maintain that banks should react the same way to
changes in saving and divesting. Fractional reserve free bankers would
have to maintain that banks should induce credit expansion (with a
commensurate increase in investment) when there are both more savings
available and, paradoxically, when entrepreneurs are divesting (i.e.,
relatively decreasing their saving). Free bankers must identify where
the coordinating activity of inducing further investment when faced with
divesting entrepreneurs will come from. How would it be coordinating to
induce investments when people want to divest?
THE MONETARY EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH AND INDIVIDUAL DEMAND FOR CASH
BALANCES
There are some additional problems with the macroeconomic monetary
equilibrium approach defended by some proponents of the free banking
school. It must first be remembered that the demand for money is the
demand to hold real cash balances, i.e., it is a demand for real
monetary services (Hulsmann, 2003, p. 50; Mises, 1998, p. 421). An
increase in perceived uncertainty causes individuals to increase their
real cash balances in preparation.
First, the uniqueness of the perception of this uncertainty causes
the demand for cash balances to be strictly individual. When it is
claimed that the demand for money increases, it must be remembered that
it is always individuals that increase their demand, and that members of
the general population might not increase these balances in the same
proportion. Free bankers argue that a free banking system meets an
increased demand for money by increasing the supply of fiduciary media.
Yet, they overlook the microeconomic mystery concerning how the
fiduciary media will get to the same individuals who have increased
their demand for money. Furthermore, they do not explain why issuing
fiduciary media would achieve the desired result more quickly than
adjusting real cash holdings directly.
While free banking monetary equilibrium theorists face this
knowledge problem, a 100-percent reserve system does not. In fact, in a
100-percent reserve system, when individual A wants to increase his real
cash holding he just abstains from either investment or consumption
expenditures or sells assets. "Monetary equilibrium" is
restored immediately. Consequently, some prices may fall or some
services may remain unsold until prices adjust downward fully. (15)
The monetary equilibrium approach, however, recommends that the
price level be held constant by producing new fiduciary media via the
fractional reserve banking system to give to A. The mystery that remains
is how a bank will know that A has increased his demand for cash
holdings (which he has, in fact, already satisfied by abstaining from
spending). Bank B, due to positive clearing and higher reserves, may now
grant a loan to entrepreneur C. Yet, this was not necessary as A has
already satisfied his increased demand for money. Prices will tend to be
bid up if C spends the money. This will actually reduce the real cash
holdings of A, who sees his intentions frustrated. Consequently, A will
further abstain from spending, leading to an additional decline in
prices. This will be frustrated by further issuances of fiduciary media.
At some point the additional money may flow to A (although this
need not necessarily happen). When C spends his money via purchases with
other actors, the cash balances of the other actors could increase above
the level that they desire. (16) Consequently, they will make
expenditures to reduce their own cash balances, the proceeds of which
could end up in A's hands. This is, however, a convoluted and
indirect process that is more burdensome than directly increasing his
cash balance (Huerta de Soto, 2009, p. 689). There is no reason why the
indirect path of increasing A's cash balance through the issuance
of fiduciary media is favorable to directly increasing it through
increased holding of money proper.
It is thus unnecessary to increase the supply of money in the face
of increased demand; it frustrates the adjustment process. Money in this
regard is different than other goods because its services depend
directly on its purchasing power. An increase in the production of bread
satisfies an increase in the demand for bread. An increase in the demand
for money services (real cash balances) cannot be satisfied by an
increase in the production of money because an increase in the money
supply decreases, ceteris paribus, the purchasing power and consequent
services of each and every monetary unit.
Second, increases in the quantity of money proper raise problems
that must be addressed. Following the logic of monetary disequilibrium
theorists, activities that increase the quantity of money proper (i.e.,
gold mining in a gold standard), without a corresponding increase in the
demand for money would lead to an excess supply of money, artificially
low interest rates and business cycles. Increases in money (i.e., gold),
or money producing activities (i.e., minting) would be regarded as
harmful. (17) This line of argumentation does not allow for the fact
that increases in the money supply do not necessarily affect interest
rates in a systematic way. Only when new money is introduced through
credit markets are interest rates affected systematically.
Third, Selgin (1988, p. 55) invokes a monetary misperception
argument, also used by real business cycle theorists. The argument
states that entrepreneurs see the prices of their products fall and
think that the profitability of their own products is affected
negatively.
Entrepreneurs do have the ability to forecast and anticipate.
Entrepreneurs anticipate the future demand for money and the future
prices of their products when bidding for the factors of production.
They may err when estimating the demand for money, as well as the
relative demand for their products. Yet there is no reason why they
should err systematically in one direction. In fact, any monetary
misperception provides a profit opportunity for entrepreneurs to
exploit.
Free bankers fail to explain why entrepreneurs would systematically
err in one direction and not exploit these profit opportunities.
THE DETRIMENTAL EFFECTS OF A FRACTIONAL RESERVE FREE BANKING SYSTEM
A fractional reserve free banking system enables credit expansion.
This occurs via three basic mechanisms. First, increases in base money
by the production of commodity money may increase reserves and allow for
credit expansion. Second, increases in the demand for fiduciary media
enable a credit expansion as free bankers have pointed out. Third, the
cooperation of the banks within the banking system enables credit
expansion.
Any credit expansion distorts the structure of production. Credit
expansion causes artificially low interest rates, which induce
entrepreneurs to embark upon more investment projects than can be
successfully completed. (18) Thus, a fractional reserve free banking
system enables a primary cause of business cycles: artificially low
interest rates.
More investment projects are started than can be completed
successfully with the available resources. Some of these projects are
liquidated when it becomes obvious that there are not enough real
resources available to complete all projects. The liquidated projects
are malinvestments that were only undertaken because entrepreneurs were
deceived by the credit expansion. Credit expansion and the tendency for
lower interest rates makes entrepreneurs think that there are more
resources available than in reality. A discoordination is created
between savers and investors.
Fractional reserve free banking usually restricts credit expansion
more than a central banking system, a point emphasized by free bankers.
As there may be adverse clearing and customers demanding money proper,
there are limits to the boom that are narrower than in a central banking
system without cooperation between banks. Nevertheless, the promotion of
business cycles cannot be ruled out as fractional reserve free banking
still allows for credit expansion. (19) This explicitly arises because
free bankers call for credit expansion in response to increases in the
demand for money.
Mises (1928) and Hayek (1928) have pointed out that price
stabilization in times of economic growth leads to business cycles as
credit expands to compensate for the downward pressure on prices.
Economic growth coupled with a stable money supply will cause prices to
fall. If banks expand credit to stabilize prices, interest rates will be
lower than they otherwise would have been and below the level indicated
by the amount of real savings. An artificial boom may arise if more
projects are started than can be sustained by the amount of real
savings.
Similarly, a stabilization of the price level as imagined by free
bankers may also lead to an artificial boom. With an increased demand
for money, prices fall to adjust to this higher demand. Assuming that
time preferences and the level of output do not change, there are no
more savings or real resources available to begin investment projects.
As there are no more savings available, interest rates will not change
due to the increased demand for money. A fractional reserve bank that
increases credit in this situation will lower the interest rate below
what it would have been if determined solely by market forces and real
savings. More investment projects are begun than can be successfully
completed. They cannot be completed without an increase in savings.
However, no more real resources are available, as time preferences did
not change. Interest rates fell due to credit expansion and not due to a
reduction in time preference rates signaling an increased willingness to
abstain from consumption. Consumers are not willing to abstain from
consumption until the projects financed by credit expansion reach
completion. Consumers desire higher cash balances which price level
changes would have satisfied without changing the relationship between
consumption and investment spending. (20) Consequently, any policy that
increases credit in response to an increase in money demand will be
destabilizing. Boom-bust cycles will be promoted the same way as when
price stabilization during times of economic growth is pursued.
A final detrimental effect of a fractional reserve free banking
system is that it creates a tendency towards the creation of a central
banking system (Huerta de Soto, 2006, p. 713). As we have pointed out, a
coordinated credit expansion further increases the limits of credit
expansion as there is no (or only limited) adverse clearing.
Coordination leads to higher banking system profits. It is not easy to
organize, much less coordinate, such an equal credit expansion. A cartel
may break up at any moment as banks that expand credit less than the
average of the cartel will have an incentive to leave. This exodus
threatens the liquidity of the cartel's more expansive members.
Banks that are more expansive will lose reserves to the less expansive
banks because of the clearing process, eventually becoming illiquid and
insolvent. Therefore, a cartel is risky when it cannot be legally
enforced, allowing banks to leave the cartel to drive the rest into
bankruptcy.
Until the breakdown of the cartel, the coordinated credit expansion
involves very attractive profits. Consequently, there arises an
incentive to install an entity that coordinates and orchestrates the
credit expansion, such as a central bank. The central bank effectively
cartelizes the banking system and sets the rhythm of credit expansion.
It guides the banking system by interest rate signals, open market
operations, minimum reserve requirements, verbal communications and
regulatory supervision. An attractive profit-reaping rate of credit
expansion is secured with no danger of banks leaving the cartel or
excessively expanding in relation to others.
Bankers have an additional incentive to demand the installation of
a central bank as a lender of last resort. The credit expansion of the
fractional reserve banks leads to an artificial boom that inevitably
causes a recession. During recessions the assets of banks lose value
because of bad loans and asset market losses. Depositors consequently
lose confidence in specific banks or the whole banking system, demanding
redemption in money proper. As banks lose reserves, liquidity problems
feed solvency problems and bank runs or panics might ensue. During the
recessions that the fractional reserve banking system ultimately causes,
banks find themselves in liquidity trouble. If one bank goes bankrupt,
depositors may lose confidence in others. The interconnectivity of the
banking system may bring the whole system down. Distrust and bank runs
spread and losses soar. Bankers who are aware of this problem demand a
lender of last resort: the central bank.
Bankers cause booms and busts via credit expansions and later
demand the establishment of a central bank due to the problems they
experience during these self-made recessions. Advocates of free banking
have yet to demonstrate how a system prone to causing economic cycles
would not fall prey to creating the very institution they wish to avoid:
the central bank.
CONCLUSION
While Selgin's use of monetary equilibrium theory to advocate
a free banking system was certainly innovative, there remain many
quibbles. Specifically, it remains unclear why monetary equilibrium
requires free banking, and how it will avoid certain detrimental
outcomes.
A concerted expansion of the money supply cannot be obstructed as
easily as the free bankers believe. Changes to both the duration of the
clearing period and redemption restraints from banks with positive net
clearing balances allow for extended periods of monetary expansion. A
basic free banking assumption--that the demand for money is exogenous to
the banking system--rests on a conflation between money and money
substitutes. The demand for money can shift independently of the demand
for money substitutes. Demand for money is price-influenced, thus
allowing it to be endogenously determined within the banking system.
Regardless of money's purchasing power the demand for loans tends
to increase when banks lower interest rates.
We have explored the complex and oft-misunderstood relationship
between time preference, savings and the demand for money, understood as
the demand for real cash holdings. There exists no fixed relationship
between these variables. Increases in bank reserves need not solely stem
from abstaining from consuming, but may also result from a reduction in
investment. How the banking system will determine whether an increase in
the demand for money stems from disinvestment of capital or abstention
from consumption remains to be seen.
Perhaps the most troubling aspect of a free banking system is that
it leads to systematic boom-bust cycles--Austrian business cycles--that
many free bankers are trying to avoid. By expanding credit without
increased real saving, interest rates are reduced artificially. More
investment projects are undertaken than resources are available to
complete. The artificial reduction of interest rates causes
malinvestments that must later be liquidated in a recession. As bankers
become aware that their business is prone to systemic insolvencies (or
at least substantial liquidity restraints during recessions), they have
an incentive to demand a lender of last resort to aid them through these
very problems that are ultimately caused by their own credit expansion.
Distortions caused by a fractional reserve free banking system
eventually necessitate the creation of a lender of last resort: a
central bank. Moreover, bankers have another incentive to call for a
central bank. A central bank enables more highly coordinated credit
expansion, thereby preventing reserve losses and providing more stable
and attractive profits.
The free bankers have done much to demonstrate the evils of a
centralized banking system. Perhaps they should turn their attention to
the detrimental aspects of their own alternative.
REFERENCES
Bagus, Philipp. 2003. "Deflation--When Austrians Become
Interventionists." Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 6, no.
4: 19-35.
--. 2008. "Monetary Policy as Bad Medicine: The Volatile
Relationship between Business Cycles and Asset Prices." Review of
Austrian Economics 21, no. 4: 283-300.
Bagus, Philipp and David Howden. 2009. "The Legitimacy of Loan
Maturity Mismatching: A Risky, but Not Fraudulent, Undertaking."
Journal of Business Ethics 90, no. 3: 399-406.
--. 2010a. "Monetary Equilibrium and Price Rigidities: Causes,
Consequences and Remedies." Working paper, Universidad Rey Juan
Carlos and St. Louis University.
--. 2010b. "The Term Structure of Savings, the Yield Curve,
and Maturity Mismatching." Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics
13, no. 3: 64-85.
Barnett, William II and Walter Block. 2005. "In Defense of
Fiduciary Media--A Comment; Or, What's Wrong with 'Clown'
or Play Money?" Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 8, no. 2:
55-69.
Davenport, Herbert J. 1913. The Economics of Enterprise. New York:
Augustus M. Kelley, 1968.
Dowd, Kevin. 1989. The State and the Monetary System. New York:
Saint Martin's Press.
Fullarton, John. 1844. On the Regulation of Currencies, being an
Examination of the Principles on which It Is Proposed to Restrict,
within Certain Fixed Limits, the Future Issues on Credit of the Bank of
England and of the Other Banking Establishments throughout the Country,
2nd rev. ed. London: John Murray, 1845.
Glasner, David. 1989. Free Banking and Monetary Reform. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Greenfield, Robert L. 1994. Monetary Policy and the Depressed
Economy. Belmont: Wadsworth.
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1928. "Das Intertemporale
Gleichgewichtssystem der Preise und die Bewegungen des
'Geldwertes,'" Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 2: 36-76.
Published in English in Hayek, 1984. Money, Capital and Fluctuations:
Early Essays. London: Routledge, 71-118.
Hoppe, Hans-Hermann. 1992. "The Misesian Case against
Keynes." In Mark Skousen, ed., Dissent on Keynes, A Critical
Appraisal of Economics. New York: Praeger, 199-223.
--. 1994. "How is Fiat Money Possible? Or, The Devolution of
Money and Credit." Review of Austrian Economics 7, no. 2: 49-74.
Hoppe, Hans-Hermann, Jorg Guido Hulsmann and Walter Block. 1998.
"Against Fiduciary Media." Quarterly Journal of Austrian
Economics 1, no. 1: 19-50.
Horwitz, Steven. 1989. "Keynes's Special Theory."
Critical Review 3, nos. 3/4: 411-434.
--. 1992. Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order.
Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press.
--. 1996. "Capital Theory, Inflation, and Deflation: The
Austrians and Monetary Disequilibrium Theory Compared." Journal of
the History of Economic Thought 18, no. 2: 287-308.
Horwitz, Steven. 2000. Microfoundations and Macroeconomics: An
Austrian Perspective. New York: Routledge.
--. 2006. "Monetary Disequilibrium Theory and Austrian
Macroeconomics: Further Thoughts on a Synthesis." In Roger Koppl,
ed., Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager. London:
Routledge, 166-185.
Howden, David. 2010. "Knowledge Shifts and the Business Cycle:
When Boom Turns to Bust." Review of Austrian Economics 23, no. 2:
165-182.
Hulsmann, Jorg Guido. 1996. "Free Banking and the Free
Bankers." Review of Austrian Economics 9, no. 1: 3-53.
--. 1998. "Toward a General Theory of Error Cycles."
Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 1, no. 4: 1-23.
--. 2003. "Optimal Monetary Policy." Quarterly Journal of
Austrian Economics 6, no. 4: 37-60.
--. 2008. The Ethics of Money Production. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von
Mises Institute.
Huerta de Soto, Jesus. 2006. Money, Bank Credit and Economic
Cycles. Melinda A. Stroup (trans.). Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises
Institute.
Mises, Ludwig von. 1928. Geldwertstabilisierung und
Konjunkturpolitik. Jena: Gustav Fischer. In Ludwig von Mises. 2007.
"Monetary Stabilization and Cyclical Policy." In The Causes of
Economic Crisis--and Other Essays before and after the Great Depression.
Bettina Bien Greaves (trans.) and Percy L. Greaves, Jr. Auburn, Ala.:
Ludwig von Mises Institute: 53-154.
--. 1943. "'Elastic Expectations' and the Austrian
Theory of the Trade Cycle." Economica, N.S. 10, no. 39: 251-252.
--. 1949. Human Action. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute,
1998.
Rallo, Juan Ramon. 2009a. "George Selgin: La Irrefrenable
Iliquidez del Descalce de Plazos." Instituto Juan de Mariana.
Available at http://
www.juandemariana.org/comentario/3679/george/selgin/
irrefrenable/iliquidez/descalce/.
--. 2009b. "George Selgin: La Confusion entre Dinero y
Ahorro." Instituto Juan de Mariana. Available at
http://www.juandemariana.
org/comentario/3526/george/selgin/confusion/dinero/ahorro/.
Rothbard, Murray N. 1962. "The Case for a 100 Percent Gold
Dollar" in Search of a Monetary Constitution. In Leland B. Yeager,
ed., Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 94-136.
--. 1962. Man, Economy and State with Power and Market. Auburn,
Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2004.
Rozeff, Michael S. 2010. "Rothbard on Fractional Reserve
Banking: A Critique." The Independent Review 14, no. 4: 497-512.
Sechrest, Larry J. 2008. Free Banking: Theory, History, and a
Laissez-Faire Model. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.
Selgin, George. 1988. The Theory of Free Banking: Money Supply
under Competitive Note Issue. New Jersey: Rowman and Littlefield.
--. 1994. "Free Banking and Monetary Control." The
Economic Journal 104, no. 427: 1449-1459.
--. 2001. "In-Concert Overexpansion and the Precautionary
Demand for Bank Reserves." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 33,
no. 2: 294-300.
Selgin, George A. and Lawrence H. White. 1994. "How Would the
Invisible Hand Handle Money?" Journal of Economic Literature 32,
no. 4: 1718-1749.
--. 1996. "In Defense of Fiduciary Media--Or, We Are Not
Devo(lutionists), We Are Misesians!" Review of Austrian Economics
9, no. 2: 83-107.
--. 1997. "The Option Clause in Scottish Banking."
Journal of Money, Banking and Credit 29, no. 2: 270-273.
Thornton, Mark. 2003. "Apoplithorismosphobia." Quarterly
Journal of Austrian Economics 6, no. 4: 5-18.
Warburton, Clark. 1946. "The Misplaced Emphasis." In
Contemporary Business Fluctuation Theory. In AEA Readings in Monetary
Theory, Blakiston Company, New York, 1951.
--. 1966. Depression, Inflation, and Monetary Policy. Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins Press.
White, Lawrence H. 1984. Free Banking in Britain: Theory,
Experience and Debate, 1800-1845. London and New York: Cambridge
University Press.
--. 1988. "Foreword" in Selgin, George A. The Theory of
Free Banking: Money Supply under Competitive Note Issue. New Jersey:
Rowman and Littlefield.
--. 1989. Competition and Currency: Essays on Free Banking and
Money. New York: New York University Press.
--. 2007a. "Huerta de Soto's Case against Fractional
Reserves." Free Market News Network, 8 January. Available at
http://www.freemarketnews.com/Analysis/240/6709/case.asp?wid=240&nid=6709.
--. 2007b. "Huerta de Soto's View of the History of
Banking." Free-Market News Network, 30 January. Available at
http://www.freemarketnews.
com/Analysis/240/6827/soto.asp?wid=240&nid=6827.
--. 2007c. "Huerta de Soto on Attempts to Justify
Fractional-Reserve Banking." Free-Market News Network, 5 February.
Available at http://www.freemarketnews.com/Analysis/240/6877/soto.
asp?wid=240&nid=6877.
Yeager, Leland B. 1997. The Fluttering Veil: Essays on Monetary
Disequilibrium. George Selgin, ed. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.
(1) Other free banking defenses are found in Kevin Dowd (1989),
David Glasner (1989), Lawrence White (1984; 1989), and Leland Yeager
(1997). Selgin (1988) is significant as it spurred on many free banking
theorists associated with the Austrian school of economics to adopt its
arguments. See, for instance, White's (1988) laudatory foreword to
Selgin (1988), Steven Horwitz (1989; 1996; 2000; 2006), Larry Sechrest
(2008), or Selgin and White (1994; 1996). Selgin (1994, 2001) later
reinforced his own arguments. Selgin's book marked a pivotal
turning point in the spread of free banking ideas among Austrian
economists.
(2) Michael Rozeff (2010), Selgin (1988), Selgin and White (1996),
and White (1989; 2007a; 2007b; 2007c) have also made ethical and legal
arguments in favor of fractional reserve banking. The opposing viewpoint
which regards fractional reserve banking as legally and ethically
problematic is made most strongly in Philipp Bagus and David Howden
(2009), William Barnett and Walter Block (2005), Hans-Hermann Hoppe
(1994), Hoppe, Hulsmann and Block (1998), Jesus Huerta de Soto (2006),
Hulsmann (1996, 2008), and Murray Rothbard (1962). From the latter point
of view, fractional reserve free banking is partly a misnomer, because
in a "free" society such behavior would be forbidden.
Fractional reserve free banking may have many advocates among
libertarians because its name suggests freedom, even though its practice
stands in direct contrast to the legal principles of a free society.
(3) It is additionally alleged that a 100 percent commodity money
system would suffer from unnecessarily high resource costs.
(4) The argument that prices are downward rigid and that an economy
is improved with inflation if the demand for money increases is outside
the scope of this article. We deal with this argument in Bagus and
Howden (2010a). In the present paper we concentrate solely on inherent
problems of the fractional reserve banking system and the relations
among the demand for money, savings and business cycles.
(5) Bagus (2003) critically assesses differing Austrian
perspectives on deflation.
(6) Selgin (2001, pp. 297-298) relies on the assumption that such
cooperation would not occur in an attempt to demonstrate that there are
limits to an in-concert overexpansion. At this point he even invokes a
central bank to enforce a "stiff penalty-rate" in the
interbank overnight loan market to halt an in-concert credit expansion.
It is ironic that, as a free banker, Selgin must rely on the
intervention of a central bank to show that the credit expansion of a
free banking system would be restricted.
(7) We assess the free banking system's inherent ability to
expand credit in a following section: "The detrimental effects of a
fractional reserve free banking system."
(8) We owe this point to Jose Ignacio del Castillo Martinez.
(9) Yeager (1997) provides a collection of essays outlining this
process, which provides the foundation for subsequent free banking
literature.
(10) Ludwig von Mises (1943, 1998, p. 442 n. 17) emphasizes that
all credit expansion distorts the structure of production and that free
banking allows for it.
(11) Monetary equilibrium theorists must indirectly accept a
version of the Keynesian multiplier principle. When the "velocity
of money" falls, an increase in the money supply will not imply
more real savings, as it will not create any more goods or services
except to the extent that it is believed that the multiplier stimulates
spending. We thank Toby Baxendale for bringing this to our attention.
(12) Rothbard (2004, p. 788) and Hoppe (1992) criticize the
Keynesian error that the demand for money determines the interest rate,
maintaining that income can be spent on three margins: investing,
consumption and hoarding. Hulsmann (1996, p. 34) argues that one can
also save and invest in cash balances by holding money units. The two
views are in fact reconcilable when we recognize that we could still
have three margins acknowledging Hiilsmann's point: investing in
cash balances, investing in real investment projects and consumption
spending. In fact, there is a continuum as investment projects are of
different durations. Thus, individuals may invest their money for 3
months, 1 year or 30 years before they want to increase their
consumption. Changes in the spending on these indefinite margins
influence the length of possible investment projects. For instance, when
resources that were previously invested for one year are reinvested for
30 years, longer-term investment projects now become more sustainable.
(13) Although not necessary, interest rates may change along the
structure of savings due to redistributions between actors with distinct
time preference rates (Bagus and Howden, 2010b).
(14) Howden (2010) argues that entrepreneurs are further
disadvantaged as the fractional reserve banking system magnifies this
misperception, depending on the distance from the initial change in the
money supply the entrepreneurs find themselves. As knowledge concerning
the credit creation process increasingly deteriorates with the distance
from its origin, entrepreneurs receiving these funds later in the credit
creation cycle will be more prone to error than otherwise.
(15) The same happens when all individuals increase their demand
for real cash balances. They abstain from spending until prices have
come to the level that satisfies their desired real cash balance.
(16) Note that this outcome will not result if prices are bid up
faster than the increase in nominal cash balances.
(17) Of course, much free banking literature relies on a frozen
fiat monetary base to limit credit expansion (i.e., Selgin 1988: chap.
11; 1994, p. 1449). Consequently, issues arising from an excess supply
of money due to, for example, mining activities, are sidestepped.
(18) Conversely, entrepreneurs might anticipate the effect of the
additional money supply on prices and bid up interest rates accordingly
(Hulsmann, 1998). In this case, there are no artificially low interest
rates and consequently there is no artificial boom.
(19) "The notion of 'normal' credit expansion is
absurd. Issuance of additional fiduciary media, no matter what its
quantity may be, always sets in motion those changes in the price
structure the description of which is the task of the theory of the
trade cycle... Free banking ... [would not] hinder a slow credit
expansion" (Mises, 1998, pp. 442 n.17 and p. 443).
(20) Consumers might increase their cash balances by divesting and
increasing their time preference. In this case, consumers increase
consumption relative to investment spending. They strive to consume more
now at the expense of future consumption. Inducing more long-term
investment projects by credit expansion, as free bankers suggest,
discoordinates this process.
Philipp Bagus (philipp.bagus@urjc.es) is Assistant Professor of
Economics at the Universidad Rey Juan Carlos, Madrid, Spain. David
Howden (dhowden@slu. edu) is Assistant Professor of Economics at St.
Louis University-Madrid Campus, Madrid, Spain. The authors would like to
thank, without indicting, Toby Baxendale, Jose Ignacio del Castillo
Martinez, Anthony Evans, Jesus Huerta de Soto and two anonymous referees
for helpful comments.