Reaching the target: an investigation of salient channel attributes in consumer choice.
Choong, Peggy
INTRODUCTION
The question of how to reach target consumers is one of
considerable importance for organizations. Substantial effort is often
given to the design and choice of marketing channels which are able to
satisfy demand for a product or service as well as to stimulate demand
through the many intermediary functions that they perform. Economic
value or welfare is created for the consumer through the performance of
these functions (Lusch, 1979; Stern & El Ansary, 1988; Hanak, 1992).
When products are marketed through multiple channels the question
of how consumers make channel choices becomes more important. How are
the consumers in each channel different? What are the salient attributes
manufacturers should offer?
The industry chosen to study these issues is the mutual fund
industry. More specifically, the study focuses on the mutual fund
industry outside of managed retirement and institutional accounts.
Several reasons make this an appropriate choice. First, mutual funds
have diffused extensively and become part of the American household. It
has become one of the fastest growing categories of household financial
assets for more than a decade commanding more than $9.3 trillion. More
than half of all households own mutual funds compared to less than 6% in
1980. According to the Investment Company Institute, a trade
organization for the United States fund industry, among investors who
hold mutual funds outside work retirement plans, about 80% own mutual
funds purchased through a channel intermediary, such as financial
planners, full service brokers, banks, insurance agents or discount
brokers. Over the last twenty five years, the distribution of mutual
funds has undergone dramatic changes. Before 1980, most funds were sold
through traditional channels such as full service brokers or directly to
the consumers. Today, mutual funds can choose multiple channels to
market their mutual funds. Apart from retirement plans and institutional
accounts, 76% of mutual funds are sold through full service brokers,
financial planners, banks and insurance agents, 17% are sold through the
direct channel and 7% are sold through discount brokers (Reid and Rea,
2003).
Unquestionably, channels of distribution are an important
consideration for funds marketing their shares. The two main reasons
that contribute to how crucial distribution channels are in the
marketing decision of fund managers relate to the nature of their
customers and the remuneration system for fund sponsors. First, studies
have shown that consumers after choosing a particular channel tend not
to switch. These consumers often purchase other mutual funds through the
same channel. Thus, each new customer is viewed as a stream of future
cash flows into the fund. Secondly, fund managers are usually
remunerated as a percentage of net asset value. The economics of fund
manager compensation often results in a flat marginal revenue curve and
a downward sloping marginal cost curve. Profit maximization in these
situations usually necessitates attracting as many fresh purchases of
fund shares as possible so as to increase the total net asset value of
the fund net total redemption (Baumol et al., 1990).
Consumers in the mutual fund industry exhibit a diverse set of
characteristics. It is important for mutual fund sponsors to choose the
appropriate channel intermediary so as to effectively reach their target
customers. As such, they need to have a clear understanding of what
attributes consumers use when making their choice.
The aim of this study is to identify salient channel attributes
deemed important to consumers in their choice process and investigate
their relationship to consumer characteristics and search behavior. A
theoretical model is first developed and tested with empirical data.
METHODOLOGY
The Fishbein-Rosenberg theories of the expectancy-value model
(Fishbein, 1967) and the theories of economic choice by Lancaster (1966)
provide a theoretical rationale for the multiattribute modeling of
consumer choice. Because of the importance of the income constraint and
the trade off with the consumption of goods in other product categories,
Rosen's (1974) utility framework is adopted.
The purchase process of mutual funds includes the search for
information as well as the performance of necessary administrative tasks
to procure and dispose of the mutual fund shares. Charles Schwab, a
large discount brokerage firm has advertisements that claim that they do
the "work" so that you don't. Individuals who desire to
invest less of their own time to the purchase process would tend to
delegate these tasks to be performed by channel intermediaries such as
brokers or bankers. Others who prefer to perform these tasks would tend
to bypass channel intermediaries and purchase directly from the mutual
fund company itself. Consumers, in effect, trade off the cost of their
own time and the cost of purchasing services, which are bundled with the
explicit product (that is, mutual fund shares) from a channel.
Therefore, a time constraint is added.
Assume that the representative consumer k invests [d.sub.i]
proportion of total investment I on channel i. The total price or cost
of a mutual fund purchase is defined as:
* The share price (for channel i, initial share price is denoted by
Poi and final share price at the end of the period by [P.sub.fi]) plus
* The cost imposed by the channel in the form of annual fees
([f.sup.a.sub.i]), loads ([L.sub.i]) and fixed fees ([F.sub.i]). An
example of annual fees are the rule 12b-1 fees and of the latter is the
fixed fees paid to financial consultants for professional services rendered.
For a clearer exposition, the loads are amortized and combined with
the annual fee to form a total variable annual fee of [f.sub.i]
(amortization development is available from author), which will be used
throughout the text. Initial share price Poi and the final share price
[P.sub.fi] of the mutual fund share are exogenous to the channel and are
determined by the stock market.
The consumer has a selection of channels through which to purchase
mutual funds. The choice of channel to use is based on his or her desire
to invest personal time in the pre-purchase and purchase process. Given
that the consumer chooses the channel i through which to purchase his
mutual fund, let the initial share price of that mutual fund share be
Poi. The consumer is able to obtain [X.sub.i] number of mutual fund
shares. The channel i has characteristics [z.sub.1],
[z.sub.2],........[z.sub.n]. Assume there is a discrete number of
channels available, each described by some level of service and some
channel cost ([f.sub.i], [F.sub.i], [L.sub.i]).
The open-end mutual fund is virtually in unlimited supply because a
fund creates new shares for all new moneys entrusted. This feature makes
the flow of money into the fund interpretable as a consumer's
response to the attributes offered by the channel and fund. Mutual funds
are able to select the attributes of their fund and channel. They do
this with a knowledge of their costs and mindful of their rival's
decisions and consumer response. Thus, let the characteristics or
attributes of service in each channel be defined as [s.sub.1],
[s.sub.2],...[s.sub.n].
The consumer allocates time, [t.sub.1], [t.sub.2],........[t.sub.i]
to search for mutual fund investment products across the various
channel. Variable [t.sub.i] is the time spent searching in channel i.
The remainder of the consumer's time is devoted to work. Without
loss of generality, leisure is ignored for simplicity of exposition.
Before going further, it is necessary to define the term service as
used in this context. Service is a substitute for the own time input of
the consumer. Some important services offered by channels are research,
advice, guidance, assortment, convenience and diversification. Greater
amounts of service ([S.sub.i]) given by the channel provide information
and other time-saving functions that enable the consumer to reduce the
time spent searching and purchasing mutual fund investments.
Since a consumer's own time is reduced by the presence of
these services, they are thus willing to pay a higher fee (in the form
of higher [f.sub.i], [L.sub.i] and [F.sub.i]) for channels that offer
these service levels. In addition, since mutual fund companies cannot
provide the service without incurring more operating expenses, they will
need to be reimbursed by higher fees to provide these service levels.
For the purpose of this exposition, the case of the back end load is
considered and combined with the annual charges. Total variable fee is
represented by [f.sub.i] which is expressed as a percentage of the total
dollar value of shares. It is not included in the initial share price
[P.sub.oi] or final share price [P.sub.fi] which are determined
exogenously by the stock market.
The purpose of amortizing all the relevant expenses and returns is
to enable us to simplify the process into a one period problem. This is
similar to the methodology used by Horsky and Nelson (1992) in which
they amortized yearly installments for cars and provided the solution
for a single period situation. Thus the following relationship is
obtained:
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] [Income
Constraint]
[summation][t.sub.i]([s.sub.1]...[s.sub.n], [x.sub.i]) + [t.sub.w]
= T [Time Constraint]
where AOG refers to all other goods, ti is the time spent searching
and purchasing the mutual fund, [t.sub.w] is the time spent working, T
is total time and Y is individual income. The fees [f.sub.i] are
expressed as a percentage.
The only attributes that succinctly capture the nature of
investment goods, such as mutual fund shares, are its risk and return.
Therefore, let [R.sub.1], [R.sub.2].......[R.sub.n] refer to gross
returns on investments in each channel. The measure of risk for a
particular asset is simply taken as the standard deviation or variance
of this return.
[P.sub.oi], is the initial share price. It is noteworthy that the
initial price, [P.sub.oi] cannot be a function of services because it is
determined exogenously by the stock market and is independent of the
services performed by the mutual fund organization.
Specifying the form of the utility function
When the consumer is certain about the attribute levels, the
utility function described in Equation (1.) measures the consumer's
preference and is the objective function which consumers are normally
assumed to maximize. However, in the consumer's channel choice
decision, consumers make their decisions with some uncertainty about the
true levels of attributes that they will obtain. Essentially, they are
unable to know with any certainty the outcome of their choice. The
overall value of investments in each channel however can be described by
a distribution over its possible values. The uncertainty of the
consumer's utility requires that the consumer maximize the expected
utility of the overall value of the attributes instead. Assigning the
notation [V.sub.k]as the overall value across channels, the
consumer's utility can be described as a function of its overall
value, [U.sub.i] = f([V.sub.k]), where V is a function of the returns
and is fully defined subsequently.
The expected utility model is adopted to determine how consumers
allocate their funds across different channels under conditions of
uncertainty. Keeney and Raiffa (1976) showed that when the value
function is measurable, if the consumer obeys the Von Neuman-Morgenstern
axioms for lotteries and if the utility function exists, the value
function [V.sub.k] should have constant risk aversion. Thus, the utility
function may either be linear or negative exponential with respect to V.
Consistent with Horsky and Nelson (1992) and Currim and Sarin (1984), the negative exponential model is adopted. The utility function
for the representative consumer k, therefore becomes:
(2) [U.sub.k] = c-bexp[-[a.sub.k]([V.sub.k])] for consumer k, where
[a.sub.k] > 0 and [a.sub.k] =U"/U'.
In Equation (2.), [U.sub.k] is the utility that takes into
consideration uncertainty in the value function [V.sub.k]. The
consumer's risk aversion is represented by [a.sub.k] which is
positive and constant. c and b are scaling constants where b (3) 0.
Without loss of generality and at the same time preserving the utility
difference orderings, we set c and b equal to 0 and 1 respectively. If V
is normally distributed, the expected utility of the individual for
channel i is as follows (Horsky & Nelson 1992):
(3) E([U.sub.k]) = -exp{-[a.sub.k] (E([V.sub.k])-0.5[a.sub.k] Var
([V.sub.k]))}
Given that the consumer derives utility from the channel, he will
choose the channel for which the above equation is greatest. Looking at
Equation (3.), we see that E(Uk) is monotonic in
E([V.sub.k])-0.5[a.sub.k]Var([V.sub.k]). Therefore, maximizing Equation
(3.) is equivalent to maximizing E([V.sub.k])
0.5[a.sub.k]Var([V.sub.k]).
Defining the value function, V
Assuming back-end load, where the entire amount of investment is
used to purchase shares, the relationship between initial share price
and quantity of shares with the total dollar amount invested in a mutual
fund product, can be stated as follows: (4) [X.sub.i]
=([d.sub.i]I)/[P.sub.oi]
Equation (4.) simply states that the number of share obtained for
the mutual fund product is equal to the amount of money invested in
product one divided by the initial price of the shares at the time of
purchase. Fees and loads are additional cost to the acquisition of
mutual funds.
Defining gross returns on investments in the following manner:
(5) [R.sub.i]=([P.sub.fi]-[P.sub.oi])/[P.sub.oi] final share price
may be stated as, [P.sub.fi]=[P.sub.oi]([R.sub.i]+1).
Initial and final share prices are determined by the market and are
exogenous variables. Thus, returns here are simply the pure returns from
the stock market without taking into consideration other costs.
The choice decisions of individuals are made with some degree of
uncertainty about the final outcome of investments. This is because a
mutual fund product attribute namely returns on investment, [R.sub.i],
is a random variable which makes it impossible for a consumer to know
with certainty the outcome of the investment. Expected utilities
therefore need to be taken into consideration. The value function
[V.sub.k] is the final income from the investment in channel i and is
the total value of the investment plus the value of all other goods,
AOG:
(6) [V.sub.k] = [summation][P.sub.fi][X.sub.i] + AOG
In equation (6.) the first term on the RHS represents the total end
of period wealth from investment and the second term is the value of all
other goods. Given equations (4.) and (5.) it is possible to rewrite equation (6.) in terms of total investment I and returns R.
(7) [V.sub.k] = [summation][[R.sub.i][d.sub.i][I.sub.k] +
[d.sub.i][I.sub.k]] + AOG
From equation (1.), AOG and household income can be defined as
follows:
(8) AOG = Y--([P.sub.oi][X.sub.i] + [f.sub.i][P.sub.fi][X.sub.i] +
[F.sub.i])
(9) Also, Y = wT--w[summation][t.sub.i]
Expected utility y needs to be maximized as follows:
(10) Maximize [Psi] = E([V.sub.k])-0.5akVar([V.sub.k])
Substituting the relationship found in equations (7.) and (8.)
equation (10.) can be rewritten as follows:
(11) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Substituting equation (9.) and [P.sub.fi] = [P.sub.oi](Ri+1) into
equation (11.) yields the following equation:
(12) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Finally, because [P.sub.oi]Xi=diIk, equation (12.) becomes:
(13) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Differentiating equation (13.) with respect to d and setting to
zero, the following equation is obtained:
(14) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Re-writing equation (14.):
(15) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] for all i.
The RHS represents the marginal revenues and the LHS is the
marginal cost of investing. A corner solution comes about when the LHS
lies above the RHS everywhere for all di. In this case, returns net of
cost for one particular channel dominates for all channels. This may be
written as:
(16) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] for all I.
In most situations, it is posited that an interior solution would
prevail. Some insights are discussed in the empirical section.
EMPIRICAL
Two focus groups were conducted in January 2005. Participants in
the focus group were individuals who had purchased mutual funds in the
last six months. Among other issues, the focus group investigated
attributes respondents looked for in selecting their financial service
provider, search efforts, information sources and satisfaction. The
results of the focus groups were used to develop the questionnaire. The
mail survey was conducted in June 2005. Five thousand questionnaires
were distributed to individuals who had bought mutual funds over the
last six months.
In this survey, respondents rated a list of service attributes
according to their importance ("Please recall the reasons you
selected your particular financial service provider. Could you specify
how important the following factors are in your selection
decision," "1" denotes "Not Important" and
"7" denotes "Very Important.").
In order to uncover the underlying service dimensions demanded by
consumers in each channel, these attribute ratings are subjected to
factor analysis. This is the procedure for summarizing the information
ratings on the twenty attributes into a smaller number of dimensions,
which can then be identified as the dimensions underlying the
respondents' ratings. The analysis determined that there are four
factors.
The results of the factor analysis, after applying the varimax
rotation procedure are summarized in table 1. Varimax rotation is used
because of its assumption of orthogonality between the factors. The
factors relate to the service requirements consumers desire.
The first factor relates to the personal service offered by the
financial service provider, interpersonal interactions, familiarity as
well as the reputation and reliability of the financial service
provider. These relate in some way to a belief that a consumer's
financial needs will be safely taken care of by the financial service
provider. Thus, this dimension is termed security.
The second factor relates mainly to not requiring face to face
dealings with or financial advice from the financial service provider.
It also includes a requirement to have an economical means of
communicating with the mutual fund organization. Since these attributes
relate to performing financial transactions independently, this
dimension is termed self-service.
The third factor relates mainly to being able to deal with the
provider on a twenty-four hour basis and is labeled access.
Finally, the fourth factor relates to the performance of the mutual
fund. Therefore, this dimension is termed performance.
These are the service characteristics discerned from the importance
ratings of the respondents in each channel. In order to evaluate how
these dimensions vary with consumer characteristics and search behavior,
they are regressed against known consumer characteristics. The consumer
characteristics used are:
1. Wage: From equation (15.), it is seen that M[R.sub.i]=
w([delta][t.sub.i]/[delta][d.sub.i]), where MRi is the marginal revenues
of investing. Across all channels, it is seen that:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
When a channel provides a lot of services,
[delta][t.sub.i]/[delta][d.sub.i] is small. With higher wages,
[delta][t.sub.i]/[[delta].sub.i] needs to be smaller. Thus
individuals with higher wages tend to spend less time investing and
would require more services. The higher the consumer's income, the
greater the opportunity cost of time. This implies that the consumer
would demand more services.
To operationalize this, the variable income is used here as an
approximate measure of the opportunity cost of time. Consumers with
higher incomes have higher opportunity costs of time and would tend to
delegate functions to be performed by channel intermediaries. They would
thus place higher importance on obtaining personal service and are less
willing to expend their own time to perform tasks required for making
investment decisions or transactions. Income is therefore hypothesized
to vary negatively with the dimension of self-service and positively
with that of security and access. At the same time, because they trade
off the cost of time and effort on their part with the cost of obtaining
time saving service from the provider, they are in essence willing to
accept a lower return net of fees. Income is hypothesized to vary
negatively with performance. Discretionary income is also used to
capture purchase abilities. Respondents were asked to answer the
following question:
"Discretionary income is the amount of money left over after
taxes and all necessary expenses (e.g. food, housing, utilities,
everyday clothing, basic transportation, and other recurring expenses)
have been paid. Among the many uses of discretionary income are dining
out, savings and investment, vacations, entertainment and audio and
video equipment. What percentage of your annual household income would
you estimate is discretionary?"
Consumers with large discretionary incomes would have more
opportunities to purchase investments. It is hypothesized that consumers
with larger discretionary incomes would place greater emphasis on self
service and less on security.
2. Human
capital (HK): refers to human capital conducive to the use of
service such as time spent using a particular channel or age, which
requires more consumption of service (Patterson, 2007).
M[R.sub.i]/([delta][t.sub.i]/[delta][d.sub.i])=
M[R.sub.j]/([delta][t.sub.j]/[delta][d.sub.j])
Older consumers will have smaller
[delta][t.sub.i]/[delta][d.sub.i]. They would thus demand channels that
offer more service. The presence of such human capital would make an
otherwise expensive or inefficient investment optimal for the consumer.
It can be said that an increase in human capital increases the
productivity of using the channel. This implies that older consumer
demand channels that provide them with more service.
This is operationalized as age which captures the notion of human
capital. There is evidence that older consumers are more satisfied with
their purchase (Furse, Punj & Stewart, 1984, Ratchford, Lee &
Sambandam, 1994). The explanations put forward by Ratchford et al (1994)
is that human capital built up through years of using a particular
product results in the familiar product being perceived as more
valuable. The probability of repeat purchase is therefore higher. This
suggests that older consumers would tend to repeat using the service of
the same financial service provider. Another explanation is that older
consumers have lower information processing capacities (Cole &
Balasubramaniam, 1993). This suggests that they would search less, since
the returns to search would be less, and therefore would delegate some
functions to be performed by financial intermediaries. It is
hypothesized that age will vary positively with the dimension that
captures the notion of service and familiarity namely the factor labeled
security and negatively with the dimension that requires personal input
namely self-service.
3. Search effort: This is a measure of how much time the consumer
spends searching for information about the product class under
investigation, in this case mutual funds. An individual who uses his or
her own time to find an appropriate mutual fund to purchase, would
demand a higher return and favor more time intensive channels. This
implies that Individuals who engage in higher amounts of search would
demand channel which are more time intensive.
This is operationalized as the time spent searching for information
about a product class before purchase, larger amounts of time spent
searching for the appropriate mutual funds to purchase would reduce the
need to delegate this particular search function to the retailer. This
is used as an independent variable. It is hypothesized that higher
levels of search effort will result in the need for less personal
service and guidance from the financial service provider. Search effort
is hypothesized to be positively related to self-service and negatively
to security.
4. Familiarity:
This captures the notion of human capital. Familiarity arising from
the repeated use of a channel creates higher perceived value in that
channel. In other words, it gives rise to human capital. Individuals who
are more familiar with a channel that provides personal service would
value that aspect while others familiar with channels that offer little
personal service would be accustomed to serving themselves. Thus, this
variable is hypothesized to vary positively with security and self
service. It is measure in terms of the number of years the individual
had been investing.
5. Knowledge:
This has been recognized in the marketing literature to be
multidimensional and related to search (Huneke et.al., 2004; Harrison,
2002; Brucks 1985; Alba and Hutchinson 1987). Two kinds of knowledge are
identified. The first is knowledge of investing ([K.sub.m]) and that
refers to the understanding that consumers have of the nature, process
and possible outcomes of investing. The second refers to the knowledge
that consumers have of the channels they use and this is captured in our
human capital term (HK).
Knowledgeable consumers do not need to spend time to invest. Their
[delta][t.sub.i]/[delta][d.sub.i] is small. They would tend to demand
higher returns without having to pay a substantial amount of fees. More
time intensive channels are favored. This implies that the greater a
consumer's knowledge of investing, the less time spend investing
and the higher the demand for time intensive channels.
This is operationalized as a ten-item scale (Sample items are
"I understand how mutual funds work," "I understand what
I read in the mutual fund prospecturs," Cronbach alpha = 0.90).
More knowledge of the product class enables an individual to efficiently
perform functions which would be delegated by a less informed consumer
to intermediaries in the channel structure. Therefore, more knowledge is
associated with the use of shorter channel structures, such as direct
purchase from the mutual fund company, or with the absence of sales
personnel, such as discount brokers. It is therefore hypothesized that
knowledge is negatively related to the dimension security and positively
related to the dimensions of self-service, access and performance.
6. Education: Education facilitates the individuals ability to
collect, process and use external information (Newman & Staelin,
1972; Ratchford & Srinivasan, 1991). These abilities make it easier
to understand the purchase process when acquiring mutual funds. More
highly educated individuals have lower
[delta][t.sub.i]/[delta][d.sub.i]. They would tend to demand higher
returns without having to pay a substantial amount of fees. More time
intensive channels are favored. This implies that more educated
consumers demand channels that offer less service. It is hypothesized
that education would be negatively related to security and positively to
self service.
Two exploratory research issues involves the extent to which gender
differences and marital status differences exist in terms of influences
on the demand for services.
7. Gender: Eagly and Wood (1985) posit that the male role has an
agentic focus which gives rise to the tendency to be assertive and
controlling while the female role has a communal focus which leads to a
caring attitude for the welfare of others. Research in social psychology
has shown that males tend to be resistant to external influences while
females being more communal tend to be more susceptible (Cooper 1979,
Eagly and Carly1981, Becker 1986). Thus it is hypothesized that males
would tend to demand less amounts of security and females would require
less amounts of self service.
8. Marital Status: Gagliano and Hathcote (1994) showed that married
individuals tended to require higher amounts of reliability from their
service vendor. It is therefore hypothesized that married individuals
would require more security, access and performance. They would also be
negatively related to self service.
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION OF OLS ANALYSIS
OLS regression analysis was performed to evaluate how the 4 service
dimensions vary with consumer characteristics. The results are reported
in Table 2.
The results show that knowledge is negatively related to security
and positively related to self-service as hypothesized. Both are
significant at the 0.05 level. Individuals who possess more knowledge
are able to understand the purchase process better and require less
personal service from the financial service provider. Being more
knowledgeable, they are able to navigate the complex investment process
by themselves and do not need the "security" of guidance from
the financial service provider. Knowledgeable consumers are also found
to be positively related to access at the 0.1 level. This underscores
the importance knowledgeable consumers place on being able to monitor
and perform transactions in a timely manner.
Education is found to be significantly and negatively related to
security as hypothesized. Being more capable of collecting, processing
and using information, these individuals find it easier to understand
the purchase process. They therefore do not require the security that
service and guidance from the financial provider gives.
Familiarity is found to be positively and significantly related to
security and self service as hypothesized. Consumers who have gained
more familiarity have in essence built up a bank of human capital in a
particular activity or provider and would thus place a large emphasis on
the benefits it provides. Thus individuals who have built up a store of
human capital in a channel offering the benefit of security would value
that benefit while others who have become familiar with channels that
are characterized as being more self-service would value this quality
that they have become accustomed to.
Discretionary income is found to be negatively related to security
and postively related to self-service. Both are significant at the 0.05
and 0.1 level respectively. Discretionary income relates in essence to
"excess" income individuals have after all the essential
expenses have been paid. Individuals with higher discretionary incomes
would tend to be frequent investors. They would probably be more savvy
about the investment process and be more skilled at navigating the
purchase process. Thus, it seems quite logical that they would tend to
be less dependent on the comfort of "security" and be able to
perform more "self-service" activities.
Search effort is found to be significant at the 0.1 level and
positively related to access. Individuals who perform large quantities
of search activities would tend to be extremely interested in investment
activities and require that they be able to conveniently reach their
financial service providers to monitor and perform financial
investments.
Though not significant, it is seen that males require less security
and married individuals more. These results are in the direction
hypothesized and are quite logical depiction of consumer behavior.
In summary, individuals with greater perceived knowledge would tend
to place less emphasis on the dimension of security and more on the
factor labeled self service. Familiarity leads to repeated usage of a
channel and varies positively with both security and self service.
Access is important to individuals who perform extensive search while
education enables an individual to rely less on the security of personal
services rendered by the provider and more on self service.
Thus, consumers who tend to use channels that provide the service
of financial transaction but no guidance and advice tend to be more
knowledgeable and expand greater search efforts. They also tend to be
familiar with their financial provider and the investment process. Ease
of access is important to these consumers. If channels such as discount
brokers and direct sales outlets want to increase their market share
they need to educate the target consumers. They need to persuade the
novice target consumers that investing is not complex and is a task that
can be accomplished with ease.
Channels that are characterized as being strong in the dimension of
security, such as financial planners and full service brokers, need to
continue to improving their relationship with their consumers. Customers
who use these channels form familiarity with them and tend to stay.
REFERENCES
Alba, Joseph W. & Wesley J. Hutchinson (1987), "Dimensions
of Consumer Expertise," Journal of Consumer Research, 13 (March),
411-454.
Baumol, William J., Steven M. Goldfeld, Lilli A. Gordon &
Michael F. Koehn (1990), "The Economics of Mutual Fund Markets:
Competition Versus Regulation," eds. Karl Brunner and Paul W.
MacAvoy, New York: University of Rochester.
Becker, B.J. (1986), "Influence Again: Another look at Studies
of Gender Differences in Social Influence," in The Psychology of
Gender Advances Through Meta-Analysis, eds. J.S. Hyde and M.C. Linn, MD:
Johns Hopkins University Press, 178-209.
Brucks, Merrie (1985), "The Effects of Product Class Knowledge
on Information Search Behavior," Journal of Consumer Research, 12,
(June), 1-16.
Cole, C. & S. Balasubramanian (1993), "Age Differences in
Consumers' Search for Information: Public Policy
Implications," Journal of Consumer Research, 20 (June), 157-169.
Cooper H.M. (1984), "The Integrative Reviewer: A Systematic
Approach," CA: Sage.
Currim, I.S. & R.K. Sarin, (1984), "A Comparative
Evaluation of Multiattribute Customer Preferences and Models,"
Management Science, 30 (May), 543-561.
Doyle, John M. (1993), "SEC Considers Set of Changes in Mutual
Fund Regulations," The Buffalo News, (Thursday) December 16.
Eagly, Alice H. & L.L. Carlin (1981), "Sex of Researchers
and Sex-Types Communications as Determinants of Sex Differences in
Influenceability: A Meta-Analysis of Social Influence Studies,"
Psychological Bulletin 90, 1-20.
Eagly, Alice H. & W. Wood (1985), "Gender and
Influenceability: Stereotypes vs. Behavior," in Women, Gender and
Social Psychology, eds. V.E. O'Leary, R.K. Vager & B.S.
Wallston, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, 225-256.
Fishbein, M. (1967), "Attitude and Prediction of
Behavior," in M. Fishbein (ed.) Readings in Attitude Theory and
Measurement. New York: John Wiley and Sons.
Furse, David H., Girish N. Punj & David W. Stewart (1984),
"A Typology of Individual Search Strategies Among Purchasers of New
Automobiles," Journal of Consumer Research, 10 (March), 417-427.
Gagliano, Kathryn Bishop & Jan Hathcote (1994), "Customer
Expectations and Perceptions of Service Quality in Retail Apparel
Specialty Stores," Journal of Services Marketing, 8, 60-69.
Hanak, Ellen E. (1992), "A Service-Based Theory of Retail
Banking," Managerial and Decision Economics, 13, 183-200.
Harrison, Tina, (2002), "Consumer Empowerment in Financial
Services: Rhetoric or Reality?" Journal of Financial Services
Marketing, Vol. 7, Is. 1, 6-10.
Horsky, Dan & Paul Nelson (1992), "New Brand Positioning
and Pricing in an Oligopolistic Market," Marketing Science, 11
(Spring), 133-151.
Huneke, Mary E., Catherine Cole & Irwin P. Levin (1994),
"How Varying Levels of Knowledge and Motivation Affect Search and
Confidence During Consideration and Choice, Marketing Letters, Vol. 15,
Is. 2/3, 67-79.
Keeney, R. & H. Raiffa (1979). Decision Making with Multiple
Objective Preferences and Value Tradeoffs New York: John Wiley &
Sons Inc.
Lancaster, K.J. (1966) A New Approach to Consumer Theory, Journal
of Political Economy, 132-157.
Lusch, Robert F. (1979), "Erase Distribution Channel from your
Vocabulary and Add Marketing Channels," Marketing News (July), 12.
Newman, Joseph W. & Richard Staelin (1972), "Prepurchase
Information Seeking for New Cars and Major Household Appliances,"
Journal of Marketing Research, 9 (August), 249-257.
Patterson, Paul G. (2007), "Demoraphic Correlates of Loyalty
in a Service Context," The Journal of Services Marketing, 21(2),
112.
Ratchford, Brian T. & Narasimhan Srinivasan (1993), "An
Empirical Investigation of Returns to Search, Marketing Science, 12
(Winter), 73-87.
Rosen, Sherwin (1974), "Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets:
Product Differentiation in Pure Competition," Journal of Political
Economy, 82 (January/February), 34-55.
Sirri, Erik R. & Peter Tufano (1998), "Costly Search and
Mutual Fund Flows," The Journal of Finance, 53(5), 1589-1613.
Stern Louis W. & Adel I. El-Ansary (1988), Marketing Channels,
New Jersey: Prentice Hall.
Peggy Choong, Niagara University
Table 1: Factor Analysis of Salient Attributes
Attributes Factor 1 Factor 2
Personal service given by provider 0.72 -0.28
Reputation of provider 0.69 -0.03
Reliability of provider 0.68 -0.01
Provision of full service 0.66 -0.11
Familiarity with the provider 0.66 -0.21
Better control over investment 0.65 0.24
Convenient transaction 0.64 0.16
Ability of provider to achieve 0.64 0.09
better performance
Accurate execution of orders 0.63 0.27
Adequate variety of funds 0.61 0.30
Accurate monthly statements 0.58 0.28
Reputation of fund adviser 0.56 0.05
Availability of other services 0.53 -0.44
Easy transfer of funds 0.52 0.47
Location of provider 0.51 -0.49
Dealing face to face 0.51 -0.67
Telephone service 1-800 0.37 0.63
Quality of financial advice 0.55 -0.59
24 hours access to a representative 0.47 0.21
Performance of fund 0.42 0.40
Factor labels Security Self-service
Attributes Factor 3 Factor 4
Personal service given by provider 0.08 0.04
Reputation of provider -0.44 -0.02
Reliability of provider -0.43 -0.30
Provision of full service 0.02 -0.34
Familiarity with the provider -0.27 -0.04
Better control over investment 0.11 0.17
Convenient transaction 0.17 -0.39
Ability of provider to achieve -0.46 0.12
better performance
Accurate execution of orders -0.21 -0.22
Adequate variety of funds 0.21 0.13
Accurate monthly statements 0.11 -0.28
Reputation of fund adviser -0.24 0.48
Availability of other services 0.34 0.04
Easy transfer of funds 0.36 0.14
Location of provider 0.28 -0.02
Dealing face to face 0.25 0.13
Telephone service 1-800 0.29 -0.06
Quality of financial advice 0.00 0.17
24 hours access to a representative 0.46 0.10
Performance of fund -0.18 0.47
Factor labels Access Performance
Table 2: Ordinary Least Squares Results
Dependent Variable is: Security Self-Service
Independent Variables Beta T-ratio Beta T-ratio
Knowledge -0.02 * -6.04 0.01 * 2.32
Income 0.08 0.97 0.00 0.01
Familiarity 0.02 * 2.56 0.01 ** 1.67
Discretionary Income -0.85 * -2.37 0.64 ** 1.78
Search Effort 0.00 0.17 0.00 0.00
Gender -0.05 -0.52 -0.07 -0.72
Marital 0.07 0.46 -0.04 -0.26
Age -0.06 -0.54 -0.05 -0.48
Education -0.14 * -3.77 -0.02 -0.45
Dependent Variable is: Access Performance
Independent Variables Beta T-ratio Beta T-ratio
Knowledge 0.01 ** 1.83 0.00 1.11
Income 0.11 1.13 -0.03 -0.34
Familiarity -0.01 -1.07 -0.01 -1.05
Discretionary Income -0.45 -1.13 -0.24 -0.61
Search Effort 0.00 ** 1.70 0.00 0.74
Gender 0.02 0.18 -0.07 -0.64
Marital 0.06 0.37 0.20 1.16
Age -0.02 -0.17 -0.45 -0.42
Education -0.07 ** -1.72 -0.03 -0.77
Note: * denotes significance at the .05 level
** denotes significance at the .1 level