Pre-negotiation strategy development in uneven power situations.
Luthy, Michael R. ; Ryan, Mike H.
ABSTRACT
Negotiations between purchasing managers (acting as representatives
of the organization's buying center) and sales representatives (the
designated agent of the supplier) are characteristic of the purchase
behavior process often encountered in business-to-business marketing
settings. It is rare when the situational power of the parties is equal.
Even with the growing emphasis on the establishment and nurturing of
mutually beneficial relationships between buyers and sellers, the effect
of situational power discrepancies on negotiation planning has not been
adequately explored. This article investigates how uneven situational
power conditions and the expected length of the relationship affect
purchasing managers' pre-negotiation strategy development and how
they structure their opening offers. Responses from approximately 150
purchasing professionals to pre-tested negotiation scenarios validated
the moderating role relationship length plays in the exercise of
situational power. Additional findings provide insight to selected
negotiation factors purchasing managers consider significant.
INTRODUCTION
Researchers have conducted a considerable number of negotiation
studies in the last several decades. Scholars from disciplines as varied
as game theory, economics, psychology, sociology, international
business, and marketing have explored the tasks, processes, and
participant characteristics of negotiations. The implicit rationale for
a large number of these studies is the central role that negotiation
plays in the organizational buyer-seller exchange process. This process
is made more critical because of the strategic role buyer bargaining
power and buyer-seller collaboration can play. The relationships created
through negotiations may represent either a strong or weak competitive
force, depending on whether buyers have sufficient bargaining power to
influence the conditions of sale in their favor, and the degree and
relative importance that buyer-seller partnerships have within the
industry as a strategic advantage.
Several models of organizational buyer behavior have achieved
widespread acceptance. The principle motivation for their development
was the realization that conventional models of consumer buyer behavior
were inaccurate and insufficient to explain and predict the dynamics of
organizational buying situations. The Sheth model of industrial buyer
behavior (Sheth, 1973) focuses on the crucial elements of the decision
process and the interactions among them. Chief among its contributions
is the recognition that the expectations of the buyer, whether
represented by an individual or by a group, have an effect on
organizational buyer behavior. While the model addresses conflict
resolution, it is dealt with only from the perspective of conflict
within the organization, and not that which may occur between the buyer
and seller.
The Webster-Wind model of organizational buying behavior (1973)
incorporates task and non-task factors, as well as interactions that
potentially affect the participants, both at a broad level (such as the
environment and the organization), and at a narrow level (such as the
individual and any group decision-making unit that may exist within the
organization). A deficiency of this model is that it only examines the
determinants of organizational buying behavior up to the point of a
decision. Implementation of that decision, which would include the
negotiation process itself, is not addressed either specifically or in
general terms. In offering the model, Webster and Wind expressed the
hope that their model would be used in future research to identify
information required for planning strategies in organizational buying.
Those planning strategies would logically include ones covering the
likely event of negotiations with sellers.
Jean-Marie Choffray and Gary Lilien (1980) developed a model of
industrial market analysis; one that specifically addressed how
organizations adopt new capital equipment. Their model explored the
connections between the characteristics of the organization's
buying center, and the major stages in the industrial purchasing
decision process. In discussing these connections, the authors
recognized the impact of individual and organizational preferences to
the process. While also making a contribution, Choffray and
Lilien's model ended with the determination of a buying decision;
no implementation issues, such as negotiations with suppliers, were
considered.
From a strategic standpoint, the relative bargaining power of a
buyer can create a significant negotiating advantage. Buyers have
substantial bargaining leverage in a number of situations (Porter, 1980
and 1985). The most apparent demonstration of that circumstance is when
large buyers purchase substantial percentages of an industry's
products. Bulk purchases generally result in both price discounts and
sales terms favorable to the purchaser. The economies inherent in large
single point sales are generally seductive in themselves to produce
uneven buyer-seller relationships. Still, a seller with a product in
high demand can often redress the bargaining balance even when large
quantity purchases are involved. Other factors also can create a
strategic imperative that produces additional pressures, tilting the
relationship in one direction or the other. For example, the possibility
of critical market exposure or the perceived advantage of being
associated with a prestige customer is common to relationships that are
unequal in terms of bargaining power.
BUILDING A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
Power
The role of power as a logical determinant of outcomes in the
negotiation process has been well established with the publication of
several major works in the 1960s (Bier and Stern, 1969, Stern, 1969) as
well as reinforced by others more recently (e.g., Greenhalph, Neslin,
and Gilkey, 1985). In addition, Cadotte and Stern (1979) developed a
model for analyzing power and conflict in the marketing channel and
Bonoma (1979), created a typology of buyer-seller relationships based on
the relative power of the parties.
Common to most definitions of social power, one of the possible
sources of power, is the idea of getting the other party to do something
that he or she would not do in the absence of influence. In the case of
negotiation however, power takes the form of inducing the other to
settle for an outcome of less than their maximum utility, given their
situation, but still within their zone of acceptance. Otherwise, an
agreement will not be reached. If an agreement is reached, it can come
about either because of tactical negotiating skill or situational power
(Greenhalgh, Neslin, and Gilkey, 1985). In a paper on power and goal
setting in channel negotiations, McAlister and her associates
established that constraints established before the negotiations
commenced had an impact on the resulting process and outcomes
(McAlister, Bazerman, and Fader, 1986). Later work by Perdue and Summers
(1991), which focused explicitly on industrial purchasing agents and
their use of negotiation strategies in rebuy situations of component
parts, demonstrated the ability of contextual variables (e.g.,
uniqueness of the buying firm's specifications, buyer's
cooperative orientation, and buyer preparedness) to predict the emphasis
purchasing agents will place on each of the general individual
strategies (e.g. problem solving, manipulating perceptions about
competition, and tough tactics) they identified for use in any
particular set of negotiations.
Of principle concern to the research presented here is the issue of
preparedness. The importance of preparedness to the negotiation process
is widely acknowledged by purchasing experts (Barlow and Eisen, 1983;
Peterson and Lucas, 2001). The possession of information relevant to
negotiations and a formal plan for the interactions places the buyer in
a strong position. In addition, having this information and a detailed
plan for negotiation increases the buyer's ability to elicit concessions from the seller. This argues for greater use of aggressive
bargaining by buyers who are better prepared. This contention has long
been supported by experimental results that increasing task relevant
data causes greater bargaining "toughness" (Siegel and
Fouraker, 1960) as well as in the observation that having more
information pertinent to the purchase situation tends to produce an
aggressive posture in buying task group discussions (Krapfel, 1985).
Asymmetry
Negotiation is one strategy for a channel member to cope with
another member's power (Dwyer and Walker, 1981). While many studies
involve symmetric or balanced bargaining situations, Dwyer and
Walker's research compares the bargaining process and outcomes in
asymmetrical power structures against those of more balanced situations.
Their results indicated that when the power structure was less balanced,
the process was, in their term, more "efficient" (i.e.
agreement terms were arrived at in fewer rounds) but the outcomes were
less predictable.
Differential situational power has been manipulated in the
laboratory in a number of ways, with the observed result that the more
powerful party typically used that power (Rubin and Brown, 1975) and as
a result had a higher outcome than the weaker party. More specifically,
a negotiator motivated by immediate maximum self-gain who holds more
power than his partners will submit a more extreme initial bid, yield
less profit from his or her initial position, and send a larger portion
of demanding-threatening messages than when power is balanced (Thibaut,
1950). Others have also found support for the effects of the power
position. Dwyer (1984) found that negotiators in strong power positions
earned more than those in weak power positions in an economic task. The
results of these research works suggests the question of under what
circumstances a negotiation party in an asymmetrically powerful position
will not use (or at least moderate) the use of their power to extract
maximum self-gain.
Initial Bargaining Position, Bargaining Style, and Relationship
Orientation
Initial bargaining stance has been examined (Lawler and MacMurray,
1980) in the context of its effect on concession strategy in dyadic bargaining. Schurr and Ozanne (1985) extended this line of inquiry and
concluded that prior beliefs significantly influence perceptions of the
seller's actual behavior and that once a buyer's
preconceptions are formed, whether or not the beliefs are consistent
with the their objectives, buying behavior will be framed by these
preconceptions. Neale and Bazerman (1985) found that a positive frame
led to more successful performance than a negative frame, reinforcing
Schurr and Ozanne's conclusions. Pullins et al. (2000) explored the
early use of cooperative negotiation tactics and the impact on later
satisfaction and profits. As a demonstrated construct, framing can occur
before negotiations commence and therefore may exert an effect on the
process and ultimate outcome of a negotiation.
A competitor's motivations also can have an effect on
negotiations. Rose and Young (1991) used written instructions to
manipulate negotiators' competitive orientations in a negotiation
experiment. As a result of the instructions competitive buyers set more
ambitious price goals, made lower final offers, and viewed the seller as
more competitive and less trustworthy than cooperative buyers. In an
article dealing with the likelihood of future negotiations (Corfman and
Lehmann, 1993), the authors found that subjects recognized that to
ensure future negotiations, equity in payoffs and satisfaction with the
current bargaining experience was important. This view of the importance
of possible future negotiations was examined by Pruitt and Kimmel (1977)
in a review of the then last twenty years of experimental gaming
literature. They concluded that a critical factor determining the
behavior of a negotiator at a given point in a negotiation is the
negotiator's short-term or long-term orientation. This perspective
is taken up by Ganesan (1993). His findings suggest that channel members
who have a vested interest in the other's welfare and in
maintaining the relationship are likely to refrain from the use of
active aggressive strategies. Combined with the finding of other
research (Dwyer and Walker, 1981; Frazier, Gill, and Kale, 1989), which
found greater use of aggressive strategies under conditions of high
power, it suggests that relationship orientation may act as a moderating
variable in high power situations.
Strategic Bargaining Leverage
Although the obvious situations of purchasing large quantities,
critical market exposure, or the perceived prestige of a buyer's
outlet or a seller's product can alter the buyer-seller advantage,
there are other attributes that may also affect bargaining leverage. For
example: if a buyers' costs of switching to competing brands or
substitutes are relatively low; if the number of buyers is small or if a
customer is particularly important to a seller or vice versa; if buyers
are well-informed about sellers' products, prices, and costs or if
sellers have similar information about buyers margins, value chain or
end users; if buyers pose a credible threat of integrating backward into
the business of sellers or alternatively if sellers have the capability
of integrating forward into their buyers businesses; or if buyers have
discretion in whether and/or when they purchase the product or if
sellers have discretion in either selling or timing (Thompson and
Strickland, 2001).
The important point is that not all buyers have an equal degree of
bargaining power with sellers. Furthermore, individual sellers may
retain variable bargaining power depending upon the buyer in question.
The potential for an individual or a firm to take advantage of the
different bargaining levels and forms of the buyer-seller relationship
represents a strategic opportunity that should not be missed. Additional
understanding of this process could improve the outcomes and therefore
be of interest to parties on either side of the buyer-seller process.
Conceptual Framework
The current practical emphasis on relationship management as a key
to successful marketing negotiations, both to buyers and sellers (e.g.
Guenzi, 2003; Harwood, 2002) suggests that the ongoing relationship with
a negotiating partner might also effect pre-negotiation strategies. More
specifically, the existence of an ongoing relationship or one that will
stretch well into the future may act to lessen the
"extremeness" of opening offers and/or moderate the effect
that one party may possess because of situational power. Power however,
is not an absolute, dichotomous variable. Rather, it is a continuous
one, evaluated relative vis-a-vis some "other" (in this case
the bargaining opponent). In other words, if a buyer is negotiating two
different $10 million dollar industrial purchases with two different
sellers, the buyer will possess more situational power in the
negotiation with seller A (where this contract represents 60% of the
selling company's annual sales) than with seller B (where the
contract would represent only 2% of the selling company's annual
sales), all other things being equal. To conceptually represent relative
power negotiating scenarios three factor levels will be considered: (1)
the buyer is asymmetrically strong relative to the seller, (2) the buyer
is on roughly equal or near symmetric footing with the seller, and (3)
the buyer is asymmetrically weak relative to the seller.
The other major factor included in the conceptual framework is the
buyer's relationship orientation. Two levels of this factor are
considered: short-term and long-term. One-time relationships are rare in
today's business markets. Even for true one-time purchases, after
purchase services, upgrades, and the like typically necessitate some
type of ongoing, if peripheral, relationship between buyer and seller.
Furthermore, players in many industries are known to all. Reputations,
both good and bad, can be created in single sale situations and exert
influence over the future actions of the negotiation participants, even
if they never negotiate directly with one another again. To investigate
the effect of buyer situational power and relationship orientation,
selected elements of the opening offer are examined; ones that are
believed to reflect the perceptions (and actions) of the buyer regarding
the negotiating opponent and their relative situational power, their
reactions to such an offer, and the factors that may either exacerbate
or moderate that position (in the current research the expected length
of the relationship). In addition, this assessment will be reflected in
the bargaining stance or style that the buyer determines to present when
the negotiations begin. A current trend, pointed out by Murnighan and
Bazerman (1990), supports the value of cooperation in negotiations and
conflict management. This trend is also supported by literature
advocating the relationship marketing perspective (e.g., McKenna, 1991;
Sherlock, 1991; Burt, Dobler, and Starling, 2003; Hutt and Speh, 2004)
and the strategic aspect to managing the buyer-seller relationship
considering its role in affecting long-term outcomes (Schultz and Good,
2000). A graphical representation of these factors, the operationalized
levels, and their interrelationships is presented in Figure 1 (see
Figure 1).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Another way of expressing this model would be in terms of each of
the elements of the opening offer (e.g., buying firm power assessment,
bargaining style); taking into account the relationships and expected
interaction between and among the other elements of the model. In that
form, each negotiation strategy element would be a function of power,
relationship orientation, and any power by relationship orientation
interaction. Imputed into this model would be the buyer's expected
reaction of the seller to a particular level of an opening offer
element.
The general principle of profit maximization guides the development
of the research hypotheses. Given that both sides in the negotiation
will be seeking to extract some profit or surplus from the encounter,
those subjects that conclude their negotiating position is more
powerful, will seek to use that factor in the negotiations and as a
result design more favorable opening offer terms for himself or herself
(refer to Thibaut, 1950; Rubin and Brown, 1975). Because of the
distributive nature of the negotiations the subjects will also adopt a
more competitive bargaining stance (as measured by Likert scales) in
order to maximize their profits (refer to Perdue, Day, and Michels,
1986). The converse of this will be equally true. If the buyer perceives
their negotiating position as asymmetrically weak, they will tend to
avoid a competitive bargaining stance since it would have a lower
likelihood of success. This disadvantageous position would also
translate into the subject designing a less extreme opening offer for
themselves, in essence operationalizing a cooperative bargaining style.
Hypotheses
Hypothesis 1: Buyers (subjects) perceiving their bargaining
position as asymmetrically powerful will advocate a more competitive
bargaining style and will propose more favorable opening offer terms for
the buyer.
Unrelated to the buyer's perception of power, subjects who
perceive their negotiations with the seller to be part of a longer term
relationship are hypothesized to moderate the terms of their opening
offer and lessen the competitive nature of their bargaining stance
(refer to Corfman and Lehmann, 1993). By contrast, the perception of a
short-term relationship beyond the current negotiations by subjects
(which could include the case of no further contact) will embolden the
terms of their opening offer and the competitive nature of their
bargaining stance.
Hypothesis 2: Buyers (subjects) perceiving the current negotiation
as part of a likely short-term relationship will advocate a more
competitive bargaining style and more favorable opening offer terms for
the buyer.
Hypotheses #3a and #3b predict that relationship orientation, when
combined with perceived power will have a moderating effect at both
extremes (i.e. short-term and long-term) for bargaining stance and terms
of the opening offer (refer to Dwyer and Walker, 1981; Ganesan, 1993).
Hypothesis 3a: Buyers (subjects) perceiving their bargaining
position as asymmetrically powerful and the current bargaining encounter
to be part of a long-term relationship will moderate their competitive
bargaining style and advocate a less favorable opening offer for the
buyer.
Hypothesis 3b: Buyers (subjects) perceiving their bargaining
position as asymmetrically weak and the current bargaining encounter to
be part of a likely long-term relationship will advocate a more
competitive bargaining style and more favorable opening offer terms for
the buyer.
METHODOLOGY
Experimental Design
From the discussion of the proposed conceptual framework, and the
identification of the various levels of the factors that will be
employed, a two by three experimental design emerges (long-term vs.
short-term orientation and asymmetrically powerful vs. asymmetrically
neutral vs. asymmetrically weak). A between-subjects approach was
selected for the data collection effort. Due to the time demands
associated with the scenario evaluation task and the pencil and paper questionnaire format used for the main study, to keep likely response
rates sufficiently high to allow for meaningful data analysis, each
respondent was asked to evaluate only one negotiation scenario.
The Sample
The sample of 600 purchasing professionals was drawn randomly from
the membership of the National Association of Purchasing Management,
more specifically, those members who designated that their principle
employment is in the Standard Industrial Classification Code associated
with "Electrical Components Other than Computer Equipment."
Selection of subjects within this somewhat narrow classification allowed
for the design of experimental negotiation scenarios that were targeted
for purchasing professionals in this area.
Data Collection Procedures
Data collection was separated into two stages. Experimental
variables were tentatively selected as a result of an examination of the
relevant purchasing, negotiation, and related literature. Questions
surrounding these variables, as well as surrounding the general process
of negotiation were designed into a questionnaire. Approximately 20
telephone interviews with purchasing professionals were conducted, drawn
from the same population pool as the main sample. The purpose of these
interviews was to verify whether the selected variables played a part in
the past pre-negotiation activities of the interviewees and what cues
were important to purchasing professionals in assessing their relative
bargaining strength. In addition to specific questions about
experimental variables, they were asked to recall and discuss the last
negotiation situation they had participated in. Probing was used
extensively to draw out detail. The responses from the telephone
interviews were used to construct a framework for a series of one page
negotiation scenarios (one for each of the six experimental conditions)
that were administered as part of a pencil and paper questionnaire.
Response Rates
For the main study, 600 questionnaires were mailed to subjects in
the purchasing professionals sample with a target of one hundred fifty
responses (25%) spread evenly among the six experimental conditions. For
each of the six experimental conditions, one hundred, one-page
purchasing scenarios were mailed to subjects (one per person). A total
of 146 surveys were returned for a response rate of 24.3%. The
distribution of responses ranged from a low of 21% (asymmetrically
strong / short-term condition) to a high of 30% (asymmetrically strong /
long-term condition). More than 20 surveys were returned for each
experimental condition. Combined with the fact that these surveys were
relatively evenly spread across all 6 conditions, the use of standard
statistical calculations and interpretations is appropriate (see Table
1).
An assessment of the background characteristics of the study's
respondents, reported as averages for each experimental condition in
Table 1, indicates that they are an "expert" group. On
average, the respondents have been members of the principle professional
organization in the purchasing field, the National Association of
Purchasing Management (NAPM) for between 7 and 10 years. Additionally,
they have significant tenure with their current organizations which are
medium to large in size. New buy purchasing situations (see Anderson et
al., 1987) are routine for their firms with significant outlays (in the
millions of dollars) each year. Over half of the respondents in each
experimental condition report supervising staff, with the average being
4 and 35. While the ranges on these variables vary, the overall impact
does not limit the usefulness of the respondents' assessments on
the survey. As a whole, the respondents represent an experienced and
knowledgeable cohort concerning the experimental task they were asked to
complete.
Experimental Task
Each subject was provided a one-page scenario describing a
situation facing an organizational buyer (see Figure 2 for a sample). In
each scenario, informational elements on the location of the supplier
(domestic), nature and complexity of the product needed (moderate),
reputation of the supplier (good reputation for quality), anticipated
length of the relationship (short-term or long-term), and economic
significance of the contract for the buyer (scaled for asymmetrically
strong, balanced, or asymmetrically weak) were provided. Subjects
assessed the degree of power both the buyer and seller possessed in the
upcoming negotiation using 7-point Likert scales. After each power
assessment, respondents evaluated the extent to which the various
informational elements affected their judgments. Subjects structured
selected elements of an opening offer: price per unit they would be
willing to pay, number of days for delivery, and bargaining style
employing a 7-point Likert scale ranging from cooperative to
competitive. Again, subjects evaluated the impact informational elements
influenced their judgments.
Figure 2 Scenario Description for Asymmetrically Strong, Short-Term
Experimental Condition
As a fellow purchasing professional I am contacting you to ask your
opinion and advice on an upcoming negotiation I will be having. In
particular, I would like to draw on your past experiences and
training in the purchasing area in structuring the opening offer
and other facets of the face-to-face negotiation.
The purchasing department at ACME has recently selected a
domestic-based supplier that we have not had any experience
with in the past in conjunction with a new product ACME will
be marketing. Furthermore, the product we are interested in
purchasing from the supplier is a "new buy" for us since we
have not needed or sought such an item before.
The item we will be purchasing is a production good of moderate
complexity that is the most important component of the finished
product we will market. Because of our particular needs this
product cannot be purchased from among the number of standardized
versions currently available. A number of unique product
characteristics and specifications require us to negotiate with
a supplier for the good.
ACME managers have selected a supplier who can provide the product
unless it becomes clear that no agreement is possible. Certain
guidelines concerning the upcoming negotiation are provided on the
following pages. However, although our company has not had any
experience with the supplier I have been able to learn some things
about their firm. They have been in business in our industry a
sufficient amount of time to build up a reputation for quality
products and service. Furthermore, from speaking with some of their
other customers they are considered trustworthy suppliers.
Managers at ACME believe that the potential sales of our new product,
which will incorporate the component we will purchase from this
supplier, will be strong although only over the near term. We therefore
expect our relationship with this supplier to be short-term in nature.
The total dollar amount of this contract will be less significant to
ACME than to the supplier. It will represent approximately one and
one-half percent (1.5%) of the contract purchases ACME makes this
calendar year. According to our information the contract will be
more significant to the supplier. The dollar amount of the contract
will represent eight and one-half percent (8.5%) of the contract
sales they make this calendar year.
Data Analysis
Analysis of variance (with significance evaluated at the 0.05
level) and multiple linear regression techniques were used to analyze
the collected data. The research hypotheses test whether informational
elements contained in the scenarios, manipulated to conform to the
experimental design, affect respondent judgments concerning opening
offer terms. Beyond verifying the manipulation of power, central to the
study and the conceptual framework, ANOVA was employed to compare
experimental cell means on opening offer terms. For both opening offer
terms and power assessments, regression was used to assess which
informational elements were important to respondents acting as buyers.
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
The power manipulation used in the experimental scenarios was
successful. Cell mean scores on the buyer power question conformed to
expected patterns and were statistically significant at the 0.05 level.
Examination of cell mean scores on the question of seller power
confirmed the manipulation. In conditions where the buyer was
asymmetrically strong, neutral, or weak, the seller was judged to hold
the remainder of situational power.
To examine whether buyers, once aware they possess power in the
upcoming negotiation, uses this to their advantage in opening offer
elements (hypothesis #1) response cell mean scores were examined.
Regarding the opening offer price (in dollars per unit), subjects in the
asymmetrically powerful experimental conditions provided mixed results.
It does not appear buyers perceiving themselves as powerful use that
power to structure a shorter delivery time frame at their opening offer.
Mixed results were also obtained in terms of the bargaining stance that
subjects in the asymmetrically powerful experimental conditions
recommended. While they were more competitive in the short-term
encounter and evidenced a consistent trend, in the long-term encounter,
the asymmetrically neutral condition produced the most competitive
stance. Because observed patterns were generally as predicted by the
hypothesis, but in some instances not statistically significant at the
0.05 level, hypothesis #1 is only partially supported (see Table 2).
Hypothesis #2 compares short-term to long-term relationship
orientations across power conditions. The objective is to determine
whether respondents in the short-term relationship orientation
conditions are more competitive and seek to gain maximum advantage from
the upcoming negotiations than those in the long-term conditions. For
this hypothesis a relatively clear pattern was observed supporting the
hypothesis for lower dollar per unit offer recommendations in short-term
versus long-term situations, across all but the asymmetrically weak
power level. For delivery time a clear pattern also emerges across all
power conditions supporting the hypothesis, but the difference for some
power levels is minimal at best. Finally, for the bargaining style
issue, the trend was minimal at best to hypothesized results. On
balance, hypothesis #2 was supported.
In evaluating hypothesis #3a, a comparison of the mean scores
indicates that there is a marked difference in the dollar per unit
opening offer consistent with the idea that subjects perceiving
themselves as asymmetrically powerful will moderate their power.
Delivery time, however, does not appear to be affected and although
bargaining stance does show a difference in line with the hypothesized
effect it is minimal.
In regard to hypothesis #3b, there is a marked difference in the
dollar per unit opening offer consistent with the asymmetrically weak
experimental condition subjects trying to obtain a higher price in the
long-term condition. Delivery time, however, does not appear to be
affected. Bargaining stance by contrast reflects a pronounced difference
in line with the hypothesized effect. Taken together, there is
sufficient evidence to assert that the anticipated length of the
relationship between buyer and seller does affect the buyer's
pre-negotiation strategy development.
Results from multiple linear regression assess which informational
factors were significant in explaining the respondents' assessments
of power and opening offer terms (at least in one experimental
condition) are presented in table 3 (see Table 3). The fact that a
moderately complex product is involved in the upcoming negotiation was
most consistently reported as significant. Relationship length and
supplier reputation followed in importance. Economic significance and
geographic base were least important across experimental conditions.
Main and Interaction Effects
Table 4 presents the results of statistical tests for main and
interaction effects (see Table 4). No main effects were found for the
buyer power assessment question. There is strong evidence of a power by
economic significance of contract interaction effect. Additionally,
there is evidence of a power by product complexity interaction effect,
but only at the asymmetrically strong power level. For the supplier
power assessment question there is a main effect with regard to
relationship orientation as well as three different interaction effects.
Results from the unit price question indicate a main affect for
relationship orientation as well as a relationship orientation by
supplier reputation interaction effect. Delivery time-frame results
reflect the almost total lack of statistically significant main or
interaction effects and lend credence to the methods behind the other
effects that were deemed statistically significant. Finally, the results
for bargaining style do not reflect any main effect, however, a power by
supplier reputation interaction effect is indicated.
Taken as a whole, these results support the conclusion that the
process of pre-negotiation strategy development, as it is represented in
this research, is both complex and generally interactive. Furthermore,
the effectiveness of written scenarios to affect a power manipulation
underscores the appropriateness of the research methodology. While not
conclusive, there is sufficient evidence to warrant tentative support to
the underlying theory that situational power does affect buyers'
pre-negotiation strategy development and structure of their opening
offers. Additionally, there is support for the moderating role that the
anticipated length of the relationship between buyer and seller plays.
The lack of stronger evidence is believed to be at least partially a
result of the artificiality of the task and the exclusion of other
important variables that were beyond the scope of the current study.
MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS
This research explored the effect of uneven situational power on
managers' plans for upcoming negotiations. The implications of the
results are extensive and certainly no less complex than that of the
negotiation process itself. A more generalized application to management
practice reflects on the tendency of managers possessing significant
power advantages to moderate their behavior under some (select)
circumstances. For example, even in situations where the power clearly
resides with one party, individual managers and firms frequently refrain
from capitalizing on the full extent of their bargaining position. In
some ways, this restraint would appear to be counter-intuitive given the
expected desire to maximize outcomes that favor the party having the
greater power. In cases involving individuals there is a greater
likelihood of a "time now" versus a "time in the
future" point of view. Individuals are able to sublimate their
perceived immediate needs in order to achieve some longer term
objective. In part, this is due to their perception that the other
party, however weak they may now appear, has or may have additional
strategic value or strategic weapons that may appear in the future. Such
uncertainty can undermine a manager's perception of power--but more
important is that it alters his/her perception of the relative value of
a short-term gain in favor of a potential long-term, more strategic,
opportunity, particularly if the current negotiation is prelude to a
longer-term relationship. Strategic considerations can influence the
application of power in ways that are not always obvious.
Corporations and other organizations with many participants
involved in a negotiation-like process might be expected to take the
short-term advantage when it is offered, except in circumstances where
the strategic opportunity is especially clear and not too far removed
into the future. The average tenure of a CEO, the individual generally
driving the decision process within an organization, is effectively
quite short for most firms. Therefore, it becomes increasingly less
likely that an organization will invoke other considerations to the
extent that they fall beyond the perceived time frames deemed relevant
to the reigning CEO. Still, a firm might choose to alter its bargaining
position on the basis of a long-term relationship that while unequal in
terms of power represents a strategic synergy. The synergistic aspect of
the relationship increases the value of the less powerful participant
over a longer period of time and thereby reduces the perceived gain
available to the more powerful member in the short term. It does not pay
to take advantage of the unequal power relationship because the
strategic value resides in areas less subject to negotiation. The
complexity of most managerial decisions is sufficient that isolating
individual components is undoubtedly problematic. Regardless, it is
clear that factors other than just having the preponderance of power
affect the bargaining process. Neither managers nor firms make their
decisions in isolation. To improve the quality of negotiations it is
important to know what is being added to the decision mix and the
relative value of each component.
CONCLUSIONS AND DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH
The present research is a beginning step to more fully
understanding the influences that affect purchasing professionals'
pre-negotiation strategy development. Due to the lack of attention by
researchers to this area of negotiations, this research was, by
necessity, exploratory. The future directions of the present research
stream are three-fold: (1) expanding the nature of the conceptual
framework to include the sellers' perspectives, (2) incorporating
additional factors and special circumstances that are particularly
important in business-to-business situations thus making it more
realistic (e.g., the presence of other sellers and/or buyers not
presently involved in the negotiation), and (3) linking pre- and post-
negotiation concepts with our current understanding of negotiations,
preferably with field investigations.
The conceptual framework is selective in the factors included.
Subjects were not provided with information concerning the vendor
selection process or at what point negotiations could be broken off and
another supplier selected, if at all. In very few real-life negotiation
situations would alternate suppliers or products not be available. In
future studies, information concerning this aspect of the organizational
buying process, as well as others such as imposed organizational buying
criteria and time pressure elements, both for preparation to negotiate
and the actual amount of time allowed for the negotiations themselves,
should be included. The result will improve both the realism of the
study and the robustness of the conceptual framework.
The framework may be further developed by incorporating team
selling as well as buying center aspects. The validity and robustness of
the framework must be subjected to a variety of purchase situations to
prove its usefulness. One example would be the impact of the purchase
time horizon on the negotiation process. Organizations often have a need
for products which may be one-time specialty purchases for which the
time horizon is quite long. Different dynamics would almost certainly
apply and affect the negotiation process and pre-negotiation activities.
Put another way, how would the process function differently for an
organization's purchase of small electric motors versus a
supercomputer? Because of the globalization of many organizations'
purchasing activities the impact of different cultures' bargaining
styles should also be addressed in the framework.
Partnerships between buyers and sellers are an increasingly
important component in business-to-business activities contrasted with
business-to-consumer. Sellers and buyers have found that in a number of
areas it is to their mutual competitive advantage to coordinate and
collaborate. Specific examples include just-in-time delivery, real-time
order processing, multiple level inventory control and the ability to
provide mass customization. To the extent that cooperation is possible
and could be secured, a third research stream involves longitudinal research with a number of business-to-business buyers and sellers to
observe actual pre-negotiation, negotiation, and post-negotiation
efforts. These studies, grounded in previous theoretical and fieldwork would provide additional detail to our understanding of the entire
negotiation process and permit a meta-theory of business-to-business
negotiation to be developed.
REFERENCES
Anderson, E., C. Wujin & B. Weitz. (1987). Industrial
purchasing: An empirical exploration of the buyclass framework, Journal
of Marketing, 51 (July), 71-86.
Barlow, C. W. & G.P. Eisen. (1983). Purchasing Negotiations,
Boston: CBI Publishing.
Bier, F. J. & L.W. Stern. (1969). Power in the Channel of
Distribution, Distribution Channels: Behavior Dimensions, New York:
Houghton Mifflin Company.
Bonoma, T. V. (1979). A general theory of interaction applied to
sales management, In R. P. Bagozzi (Ed.) Sales Management: New
Developments from Behavioral and Decision Model Research, Cambridge, MA:
Marketing Science Institute.
Burt, D. N, Dobler, D. W. & S. Starling. (2003). World Class
Supply Management: The Key to Supply Chain Management, Seventh Edition,
New York McGraw-Hill.
Cadotte, E. R. & L.W. Stern. (1979). A process model of
interorganizational relations in marketing channels, in J. Sheth (Ed.),
Research in Marketing, (Volume 2), Greenwich, CT: JAI Press Inc.
Choffray, J. M. & G.L. Lilien. (1980). Market Planning for New
Industrial Products, New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Corfman, K. P. & D.R. Lehmann. (1993). The importance of
others' welfare in evaluating bargaining outcomes, Journal of
Consumer Research, 20, (June), 124-137.
Dwyer, F. R. (1984). Are two better than one? Bargaining behavior
and outcomes in an asymmetrical power relationship, Journal of Consumer
Research, 11, (September), 680- 693.
Dwyer, F. R. & O. C. Walker, Jr., (1981). Bargaining in an
asymmetrical power structure, Journal of Marketing, 45, (Winter),
104-115.
Frazier, G. L., J.D. Gill & S.H. Kale. (1989). Dealer
dependence levels and reciprocal actions in a channel of distribution in
a developing country, Journal of Marketing Research, 53, (January),
50-69.
Ganesan, S. (1993). Negotiation strategies and the nature of
channel relationships, Journal of Marketing Research, 30, (May),
183-203.
Greenhalgh, L., S.A. Neslin & R.W. Gilkey. (1985). The effects
of negotiator preferences, situational power, and negotiator personality
on outcomes of business negotiations, Academy of Management Journal,
28(1), 9-33.
Guenzi, P. (2003). Antecedents and consequences of a firm's
selling orientation, European Journal of Marketing, 37(5/6), 706.
Harwood, T. (2002). Business negotiations in the context of
strategic relationship development, Marketing Intelligence &
Planning, 20(6), 336
Hutt, M. D. & T.W. Speh, (2004), Business Marketing Management:
A Strategic View of Industrial and Organizational Markets, Eighth
Edition, Mason, OH: Thomson South-West Learning.
Krapfel, R. E. Jr. (1985). An advocacy behavior model of
organizational buyers' vendor choice, Journal of Marketing, 49,
(Fall), 51-59.
Lawler, E. J. & B.K. MacMurray (1980). Bargaining toughness: A
qualification of level-of-aspiration and reciprocity hypotheses, Journal
of Applied Social Psychology, 10(5), 416-430.
McAlister, L., M.H. Bazerman & P. Fader. (1986). Power and goal
setting in channel negotiations, Journal of Marketing Research, 23,
(August), 228-236.
McKenna, R. (1991). Relationship Marketing, Reading, MA:
Addison-Wesley Publishing Inc.
Murnighan, J. K. & M.H. Bazerman. (1990). A perspective on
negotiation research in accounting and auditing, The Accounting Review,
65, (July), 642-657.
Neale, M. A. & M.H. Bazermam. (1985). The effects of framing
and negotiator overconfidence on bargaining behaviors and outcomes,
Academy of Management Journal, 28(1), 34-49.
Perdue, B. C. & J.O. Summers. (1991). Purchasing agents'
use of negotiation strategies, Journal of Marketing Research, 28, (May),
175-189.
Perdue, B. C., R.L. Day & R.E. Michaels. (1986). Negotiation
styles of industrial buyers, Industrial Marketing Management, 15,
171-176.
Peterson, R. M. & G. H. Lucas. (2001). Expanding the antecedent component of the traditional business negotiation model: Pre-negotiation
literature review and planning-preparation propositions, Journal of
Marketing Theory and Practice. 9(4), 37-50.
Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive Strategy: Techniques for
Analyzing Industries and Competitors, New York: Free Press.
Porter, M. E. (1985). Competitive Advantage, New York: Free Press.
Pruitt, D. G. & J. J. Kimmel. (1977). Twenty years of
experimental gaming: Critique, synthesis, and suggestions for the
future, in M.R. Rosenzweig & L.W. Porter (Eds.), Annual Review of
Psychology, 28, 363-392.
Pullins, E. B., C. P. Haugtvedt, P. R. Dickson, L. M. Fine & R.
J. Lewicki (2000). Individual differences in intrinsic motivation and
the use of cooperative negotiation tactics, Journal of Business &
Industrial Marketing, 17(7), 466-488.
Rose, R. L. & M. Young (1991). Competitive versus cooperative
motives in buyer-seller negotiations, in Enhancing Knowledge Development
in Marketing: 1991 AMA Educator's Proceedings, Chicago: American
Marketing Association, 618-625.
Rubin, J. Z. & R.B. Brown. (1975). The Social Psychology of
Bargaining and Negotiation, New York: Academic Press.
Schultz, R. J. & D. J. Good. (2000). Impact of the
consideration of future sales consequences and customer-oriented selling
on long-term buyer-seller relationships, The Journal of Business &
Industrial Marketing, 15(4), 200-214.
Schurr, P. H. & J.L. Ozanne. (1985). Influences on exchange
processes: buyers' preconceptions of a seller's
trustworthiness and bargaining toughness, Journal of Consumer Research,
11, (March), 939-953.
Sherlock, P. (1991). Rethinking Business to Business Marketing, New
York: The Free Press.
Sheth, J. (1973). A model of industrial buyer behavior, Journal of
Marketing, 37, 50-56.
Siegel, S. & L.E. Fouraker. (1960). Bargaining and Group
Decision Making: Experiments in Bilateral Monopoly, New York:
McGraw-Hill.
Stern, L. W. (Ed.). (1969). Distribution Channels: Behavior
Dimensions, New York: Houghton Mifflin Company.
Thibaut, J. W. (1950). An experimental study of the cohesiveness of
underprivileged groups, Human Relations, 3, (April), 251-278.
Thompson, A., Jr. & A. J. Strickland. (2001). Strategic
Management: Concepts and Cases, 12th Edition, New York:
McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Webster, F. E., Jr. & Y. Wind (1973). A general model for
understanding organizational buying behavior, Journal of Marketing,
36(2), 12-19.
Michael R. Luthy, Bellarmine University Mike H. Ryan, Bellarmine
University
Table 1 Sample Response Rates and Characteristics
Short-Term Orientation
Written Scenarios
Buyer is Asymmetrically ...
Strong Neutral Weak
Number of scenarios distributed 100 100 100
Number of surveys returned 21 24 24
Sample Response Rate 21% 24% 24%
Years NAPM member 9.7 8.5 7.0
Years with present company 9.6 10.4 10.8
Number of company employees 2,129 7,068 2,569
Percent with supervisory role 57% 58% 67%
Number of people supervising 7 6 5
New Buy contracts per year 806 431 58
Value of annual "new buy" $10.2 $10.1 $12.6
contracts (in millions)
Long-Term Orientation
Written Scenarios
Buyer is Asymmetrically ...
Strong Neutral Weak
Number of scenarios distributed 100 100 100
Number of surveys returned 30 25 22
Sample Response Rate 30% 25% 22%
Years NAPM member 9 8.6 8.5
Years with present company 10.1 11.2 10.4
Number of company employees 8,143 17,463 6,189
Percent with supervisory role 66% 60% 57%
Number of people supervising 12 6 35
New Buy contracts per year 318 38 117
Value of annual "new buy" $15.7 $3.9 $10.1
contracts (in millions)
Table 2 Response Means by Experimental Condition
Buyer's Buyer's Supplier's
Position Power * Power *
Short-term Asymmetrically Strong (n=21) 5.24 3.19
Asymmetrically Neutral (n=24) 4.63 4.46
Asymmetrically Weak (n=24) 3.42 5.04
Asymmetrically Strong (n=30) 5.13 4.37
Long-term Asymmetrically Neutral (n=25) 4.72 4.44
Asymmetrically Weak (n=22) 3.68 5.32
Opening
Delivery
Buyer's Per Unit Time Frame
Position Price ($) (days)
Short-term Asymmetrically Strong (n=21) 118.81 33.00
Asymmetrically Neutral (n=24) 115.42 31.81
Asymmetrically Weak (n=24) 131.46 33.00
Asymmetrically Strong (n=30) 132.77 33.05
Long-term Asymmetrically Neutral (n=25) 141.50 33.00
Asymmetrically Weak (n=22) 127.30 33.20
Offer Terms
Buyer's Bargaining
Position Style **
Short-term Asymmetrically Strong (n=21) 3.62
Asymmetrically Neutral (n=24) 3.50
Asymmetrically Weak (n=24) 2.88
Asymmetrically Strong (n=30) 3.60
Long-term Asymmetrically Neutral (n=25) 3.92
Asymmetrically Weak (n=22) 3.32
* Measured with a 7-pt Likert Scale, 1=very little or no bargaining
power and 7=a great deal of bargaining power.
** Measured with a 7-pt Likert Scale, 1= cooperative and 7=competitive.
Table 3 Statistically Significant Factors in Explaining Respondent
Assessments
Product Relationship Supplier
Complexity Length Reputation
Buyer Power X X
Supplier Power X X
Unit Price X X X
Delivery X
Bargaining Style X X X
Economic Geographic
Significance Base
Buyer Power X
Supplier Power
Unit Price X
Delivery X
Bargaining Style X
Table 4 Main and Interaction Effects
Main Effect Interaction Effect
Buyer Power None Power with Economic
Significance of Contract
Power with Product Complexity
(Asymmetrically Strong)
Supplier Power Relationship Relationship Orientation with
Supplier Reputation
Orientation Power with
Relationship Orientation
(Asymmetrically Strong)
Power with Product Complexity
(Asymmetrically Weak)
Unit Price Relationship Relationship Orientation with
Supplier Reputation Orientation
Delivery None None
Bargaining Style None Power with Supplier Reputation
Relationship Orientation with
Supplier Reputation