An event study approach to evaluating the economic returns of advertising in the super bowl.
Choong, Peggy ; Filbeck, Greg ; Tompkins, Daniel L. 等
ABSTRACT
While there are several anecdotal evidence of positive outcomes
from Super Bowl advertising, there have not been any credible
measurements of returns on investing in this expensive strategy.
This paper evaluates the returns on management's strategy to
advertise during the Super Bowl using the event study methodology. This
is a useful method often used in the finance field, to capture the
market's valuation of the management decision by measuring the
abnormal returns associated with the announcement of that strategy. A
knowledge of the outcome associated with this strategy will enable
marketing managers to better allocate their advertising resources among
the array of media and media events.
INTRODUCTION
Reaching the largest proportion of prospective buyers is a problem
faced by many advertising executives in media planning. This problem has
been exacerbated in recent years by the increased fragmentation of the
market. With numerous television channels and radio stations nationwide,
programs on each of these media are consistently reaching smaller
defined audiences. To add to this problem of reach, advertising
executives are also faced with the lack of response most consumers have
toward broadcast advertising.
In response to these issues, marketers have, over the last fifteen
years, gravitated toward television programs such as the Super Bowl,
Olympics, Oscars and Grammy Awards. Among the handful of important media
events, the Super Bowl has remained one of the most coveted and
expensive advertising venues (Elliott, 1999). The annual scramble to
secure strategic time slots during the game has become a major media
event in itself. Many companies spend the bulk of their annual
advertising budget on this single costly program. A thirty-second spot
during the Super Bowl cost an average of $2.0 million dollars compared
with $1.6 million for the Oscars and $0.57 million for the Grammy Award (O'Connell, 2002).
The two reasons most advertisers cite for advertising on the Super
Bowl are its substantial reach and the high degree of audience
receptivity to commercials during the program. For example, advertising
agents for 7UP claim that their target market of 12 to 24 year-olds is
so highly fragmented that Super Bowl Sunday is one of the few television
venues that captures the highest percentage of this market. Similarly,
when executives at Philips Electronics, North America released their new
advertisement of the 64-inch hi-definition television priced just under
$10,000, they claimed that the Super Bowl was their best opportunity to
reach 40 percent of their 18 to 49 year-old target market Reaching
"the same unduplicated number of viewers" would have required
buying the equivalent of 13 or 14 prime-time spots (Elliott, C8, 1999).
Audience receptivity during the program is also reported to be
higher than during normal programming. Unlike regular programming where
advertisements are often viewed as intrusions, Super Bowl audiences are
actually paying attention to the commercials. A research conducted by
SAA/Research reported that 48 percent of respondents listed seeing the
commercials as a reason they watch (Elliott, 1999). Audiences view the
advertisements during Super Bowl as part of the entertainment.
Interestingly, reviewing the commercials the day after have become an
event in itself ranging from the informal office conversations to the
annual consumer survey known as the Super Bowl Ad Meter conducted by USA
Today. Marketing executives are loath to find themselves at the bottom
of the well-publicized meter.
There has been extensive research in marketing about advertising
and its effects. Market response models form a significant segment of
these studies on how advertising works (see Demetrios et. al 1999 for an
excellent discussion of the taxonomy of advertising effects). Generally,
this genre of studies examines the relationship between advertising and
some measure of behavioral response. Aggregate level studies typically
use sales or market share as proxies for the market response (Bass &
Clarke, 1972; Rao & Miller, 1975; Little, 1979; Blattberg &
Jeuland, 1981; Rao 1986; Zufryden 1987; Hanssens, Parsons & Schultz,
1990; Rao & Burnkrant, 1991). However, measuring the overall effect
of advertising expenditure on sales and profits is fraught with
problems. One significant problem is that the duration of advertising
effects uncovered in many studies clearly shows that the effects of
advertising accrue over time, thus making current profits or sales less
useful measures of advertising effectiveness (Winer, 1979, 1980; Dekimpe
& Hanssens, 1995; Leone, 1995; Lodish, 1995;; Mela, Gupta &
Lehmann, 1997). These problems are exacerbated when attempting to
measure the effects of a single advertising strategy. Thus to circumvent these problems and to measure the effects of a single advertising
strategy, another method of measurement is required.
The event study methodology is a feasible and useful method often
used to measure the direct effects of a strategy. Commonly used in the
finance and economics fields, this methodology captures the
market's valuation of a management decision by measuring the
abnormal returns associated with the announcement of that strategy. When
applied to the measurement of advertising effectiveness, this method is
able to capture the abnormal returns of advertising in a specific
program such as the Super Bowl.
This kind of measurement should also be of particular relevance
nowadays as marketing managers are increasingly pressured to provide
evidence of economic returns to their strategic decisions. An oft quoted
remark attributed to John Wanamaker, founder of the first U.S.
department store (1838-1992), "Half the money I spend on
advertising is wasted, the trouble is, I don't know which
half," underlines the skepticism corporate America still has for
how advertising works (Lee & Lade, 2001). While there are several
anecdotal evidence of positive outcomes from Super Bowl advertising, in
the form of increased sales, phone inquiries and hits on Web sites of
advertisers, there have not been any credible measurements of the
returns on investing in this expensive programming. Just as companies
seldom make major capital expenditures without estimating the likely
financial returns, so too is corporate America increasingly demanding to
know the returns on their advertising strategy.
The purpose of this paper is to evaluate the returns on
management's strategy to advertise during the Super Bowl using the
event study methodology. Knowledge of this will enable managers to
better allocate their advertising resources among the array of media and
media events.
EVENT STUDY METHODOLOGY
The event study methodology is a statistical procedure to examine
the effect that the release of information has on the stock market
returns of the firm. It has been used extensively in the economics and
finance literature. In the marketing field, it has been used to examine
strategies such as product innovation, change in a company's name,
bad publicity associated with a product introduction and recall,
announcements of green activities and introduction of e-commerce (Horsky
& Swyngedouw 1987; Capon, Farley & Hoenig, 1990; Szymanski,
Bhardwaj & Varadarajan, 1993; Mathur & Mathur 2000; Subramani
& Walden 2001).
The theory underlying this procedure is the efficient market
hypothesis, which states that a firm's stock price is the present
value of the stream of future cash flows. At any point in time, this
stock price reflects all known information pertaining to the firm's
current and future profits. In this way, stock prices reflect the true
value of the firm because they reflect the discounted value of future
earnings as well as all relevant information known in the market. New
information that will impact on the firm's current and future
profitability will result in a change in security price. The purpose of
this methodology is to determine whether the announcement of some
upcoming event produces a significant stock price reaction around the
time of the announcement. For example, the announcement of new
information in the form of the company's strategy to advertise on
the Super Bowl constitutes new signals about the present and future
earnings of the company. This signal will impact its stock price. If the
market views this strategy as worthwhile, the perceived value of the
firm is likely to increase and be reflected in a simultaneous increase
in the market price of the stock. To conduct such tests, daily stock
returns are measured around the announcement or event date and are
compared with the expected return. The change in the price of the stock,
or abnormal returns, after the event reflects the unbiased market
valuation of the economic value of the event. This methodology provides
a unique opportunity to evaluate the financial effect of a corporate
strategy. By examining a sample of firms over a period of years, it is
possible to evaluate the overall market valuation of a particular
business strategy.
The hypothesis in this paper is tested using the standard event
study methodology (see e.g., Brown & Warner, 1985). The expected
return is generally based on the Capital Asset Pricing Model or some
other suitable market based return generating mechanism. The market
model is specified as:
(1.) [R.sub.j, t] = [[alpha].sub.j] + [beta].sub.j] [R.sub.mt] +
[u.sub.jt], j = 1, ... , N; t = -325, ... , -71,
where N is the number of issues in the sample, [R.sub.j, t] is the
return on stock j for day t, [R.sub.m, t] is the return on market proxy
m for day t, [u.sub.j, t] is the random error for stock j for day t
normally distributed with E|[u.sub.j, t] | =0, [[alpha].sub.j] is the
estimated intercept term for stock j, and [[beta].sub.j] is the
estimated risk coefficient for stock j. The market model is estimated by
using the equally-weighted market returns from CRSP files as the market
proxy.
The prediction errors are calculated for each day in the test
period, which begins 50 days before the announcement day and ends 50
days after the announcement day. The prediction error for stock j for
day t is defined as
(2.) [PE.sub.j, t] = [R.sub.j, t] - ([[alpha].sub.j] +
[[beta].sub.j][R.sub.m,t]), 1,....,N t = [T.sub.1], [T.sub.1] +
1,....,[T.sub.2]
such that E|P[E.sub.j]| =0, i.e., the prediction error is not
expected in an efficient market in equilibrium. If E|P[E.sub.j]| [not
equal to]0 , then we infer that some unanticipated information had come
to the market and was used by well-informed individuals.
The cross-sectional average prediction error for day t for a sample
of size n is
(3.) SP[E.sub.1] = [i.summation over (j=1)] P[E.sub.j,t],
and the cumulative average prediction error is
(4.) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
The time-series of CAPEs tells us whether prediction errors would
have occurred had investors bought the test portfolio in day T1 and held
until day I, i=[T.sub.1], [T.sub.1]+1,...,[T.sub.2].
Following Patell (1976), tests of statistical significance are
based on standardized prediction errors. The standardized prediction
error for stock j in day t, is calculated as
(5.) SP[E.sub.j,t] = P[E.sub.j,t]/[S.sub.j,t]
where
(6.) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Where [[sigma].sup.2.sub.j] is the residual from the market model
estimation for stock j, T is the number of days in the period used to
estimate the model and [??] is the mean market return in the estimation
period.
The average standardized prediction error for day t is:
(7.) ASP[E.sub.t] = 1/N [N.summation over (j=1)] SP[E.sub.j,t].
For each day, the Z-statistic is calculated as
(8.) . ASPE N = Z t t *
The limiting distribution of [Z.sub.t] is the unit normal, under
the null hypothesis that the mean normalized, standardized prediction
error equals zero. Over the testing period, which begins with [T.sub.1]
and ends with [T.sub.2], the cumulative normalized, average standardized
prediction error is
(9.) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Then, the Z-statistic is calculated as
(10.) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and has a unit normal limiting distribution under the null
hypothesis that the cumulative normalized, average standardized
prediction error over the period from [T.sub.1] through [T.sub.2] equals
zero.
DATA
Data was collected for ten years from 1990 to 1999. Announcement
day is defined as the date in which the company's announcement of
its intention to advertise in the upcoming Super Bowl was published in
the print media. Major newspapers (e.g. The Wall Street Journal and New
York Times) were consulted as well as leading advertising outlets such
as Advertising Age and AdWeek. A search was also conducted on
Lexis/Nexis data files to search for possible leaks to alternative
sources.
A pre-requisite of the event study methodology is the availability
of market data for the firm under investigation. The sample of firms
with well-defined announcement dates during the ten-year period totaled
112 or about 80% of total firms. Daily stock prices were obtained from
the University of Chicago's Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) tape.
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
Following Brown and Warner (1985), the event day is defined as day
'0' (t=0). Using the standard estimation duration of 255 days
(t= -325 to t=-71), the parameters of the market model in equation (1.)
is estimated. These estimated parameters are then used to calculate
expected returns for each of the firms for the specified event window.
Abnormal returns are simply obtained by comparing these to the actual
returns observed in the event window as shown in equation (2.).
Two events were identified and analyzed. Event 1 is defined as the
date that the firm announced its intention to advertise during the Super
Bowl and Event 2 is defined as the first trading day after the Super
Bowl.
Event 1: Announcement of the Strategy
Results for the 112 announcements for this event, for a window of
-10 and +10 are exhibited in Table 1. The results indicate that a
firm's announcement of their intention to advertise on the Super
Bowl is associated with statistically insignificant negative excess
returns. On the event day itself, firms experience an average of a 0.23
percent decline in excess returns. These results are only significant at
the ten-percent level.
Cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) are calculated to capture any
possibility that the effects may be spread over a few days due to the
gradual spread of information and their implications on future cash
flows. Results for different windows are exhibited in Table 2. The CAR
associated with the announcement of the strategy, is negative and
statistically significant for the (-1; 0) and (-1; +1) windows,
indicating that there is a pattern of information leak before the
announcement date. Cumulative abnormal stock price across the windows -1
and +1 average negative 0.67 percent. This result together with the
previous result of insignificant negative abnormal returns (p=0.1)
suggests that the market is somewhat pessimistic about the firm's
strategy. The announcement of the firm's decision to advertise on
the Super Bowl does not result in any significant positive abnormal
returns. This indicates that the market believe the strategy will not
result in any future flows of positive earnings. A possible reason could
be that the market has at that point no credible means of measuring the
probability of success in this strategy. The market has little
information about the advertising campaign and has indeed not seen the
broadcast of the campaign. Thus, it reacts accordingly and does not
reward the firm with positive and significant abnormal returns. The
significant CAR results merely indicate that the information flows are
gradual and there are leaks in the market. Bearing in mind that many
Super Bowl advertisers are repeat advertisers, the CAR results probably
indicate that investors have simply anticipated that the firms will
again participate in yet another Super Bowl.
Event 2: First trading day after Super Bowl Sunday
Event 2 was specified to investigate the market reaction subsequent
to the actual broadcast of the advertising campaign. It is defined as
the first trading day after Super Bowl Sunday. Results of this analysis
exhibited in Table 1 indicates that on the event date, firms experience
on average a 0.16 percent positive excess returns. This is statistically
significant at the five-percent level. The results indicate that on
average firms who advertise on the Super Bowl experienced a gain of 0.16
percent in excess returns on the first trading day following the
broadcast. The size of excess returns is in line with the magnitudes
obtained in other event studies investigating the impact of marketing
strategies on share price responses. Agrawal and Kamakura (1995) found
that the announcement of new celebrity endorsers resulted in a 0.44
percent positive abnormal returns, Chaney, DeVinney and Winer (1991)
showed that the announcement of new products resulted in a positive
abnormal return totally 0.25 percent.
Looking at the event subsequent to the airing of the Super Bowl,
CARs, exhibited in table 2, are seen to be not significant between days
-1 and +1. This together with the positive average abnormal returns
obtained on the first trading day after Super Bowl Sunday suggest that
the market reacts in a positive direction to the advertisements
broadcast during the game. Having seen the actual execution of the
strategy and the reaction of the audience to the advertisement, the
market reacts in a positive manner and rewards the firms with an
increase in stock prices on average.
CONCLUSION
Two interesting results have emerged from the analysis. The first
is that the market considers the announcement of the firm's
intentions to advertise on the Super Bowl as a non-news event with
insignificant effects on the future cash flows and profits of the firm.
The second and more interesting finding is the positive and
statistically significant average abnormal returns recorded on the first
trading day after the airing of the advertisement on the Super Bowl. The
market obviously rewards firms adopting this strategy at this point. The
message as well as the reaction of the audience to the advertisement is
viewed to positively impact on the firm's future cash flows and
profits and stock prices rise accordingly.
These results suggest that the market does not reward the firm on
its announcement of its strategy to launch an advertising campaign
during the Super Bowl due probably to investors' lack of
information about the campaign's probability of success. Therefore,
it is in the marketing manager's interest at the announcement date
to offer information that will help the market assess the outcome of
their forthcoming campaign. Managers should also provide investors with
"reminders" of the success of similar campaigns they launched
in the past. These additional sets of information will enable investors
to more effectively gauge the potential for success of their current
campaign.
Future research should include measuring the returns on advertising
in other major programs such as the Academy Awards and Grammy awards.
Results from these studies can be pooled together to obtain a clearer
picture of whether it makes economic sense to target advertising dollars
to these specific programs.
REFERENCES
Agrawal, J. & Kamakura, W.A. (1995). The economic worth of
celebrity endorsers: an event study analysis. Journal of Marketing, 59,
56-62.
Bass, F.M. & Clark, D.G. (1972). Testing distributed lag models
of advertising effects. Journal of Marketing Research, 9, 298-308.
Blattberg, R.C. & Jeuland, A.P. (1981). A micro-modeling
approach to investigate the advertising-sales relationship. Management
Science, 27, 988-1005.
Brown, S. J. & J. B. Warner. (1985). Using daily stock returns:
The case of event studies. Journal of Financial Economics, 14, 205-258.
Capon, N., Farley, J. & Hoenig, S. (1990). Determinants of
financial performance: A meta-analysis, Management Science, 36, 1143-59.
Chaney, P.K., Divinney, T. & Winer, R.S. (1991). The impact of
new product introduction on the market value. The Journal of Business,
64(4), 573-611.
Dekimpe, M.G. & Hanssens, D.M. (1995). The persistence of
marketing effects on sales. Marketing Science, 14(1), 1-21.
Demetrios, V. & Ambler, T. (1999). How advertising works: What
do we really know. Journal of Marketing, 63(1), 26-43.
Elliott, S. (1999, January 28). Trying to score big in 'ad
bowl' companies jostle to reach consumers on super Sunday. The New
York Times, C1/C8.
Hanssens, D.M., Parsons, L.J. & Schultz, R.L. (1990). Market
Response Models: Econometric and Time Series Analysis. Boston, MA:
Kluwar Academic Publishers.
Horsky, D. & Swyngedouw, P. (1987). Does it pay to change your
company's name? A stock market perspective. Marketing Science, 6,
32-34.
Kim, P. (1992). How advertising works: A review of the evidence.
The Journal of Consumer Marketing, 9(4), 5-9.
Lee, M. & Lade, D.S. (2001). Demystifying advertising
investments. The Journal of Business Strategy, 22(6), 18-22.
Leone, R.P. (1995). Generalizing what is known about temporal
aggregation and advertising carryover. Marketing Science, 14(3), 141-50.
Little, J. (1979). Aggregate advertising models: The state of the
art. Operations Research, 27.
Lodish, L.M. (1995). A summary of fifty-five in-market experimental
estimates of the long-term effects of advertising. Marketing Science,
14(3), 133-40.
Mathur, L.K. & Mathur, I. (2000). An analysis of the wealth
effects of green marketing strategies. Journal of Business Research,
50(2), 193-200.
Mela, C.F., Gupta, S. & Lehman, D.R. (1997). The Long-term
impact of promotion and advertising on consumer brand choice. Journal of
Marketing Research, 34, 248-61.
O'Connell, V. (2002, January 28). Super bowl gets competition.
The Wall Street Journal, B1.
Patell, J. M., (1976) Corporate forecasts of earnings per share and
stock price behavior: Empirical tests. Journal of Accounting Research,
14(2), 246-276.
Rao, R.C. (1986). Estimating continuous time advertising sales
model. Marketing Science, 5(2), 125-142.
Rao, U.H. & Burnkrant, R.E. (1991). Effects of repeating varied
ad executions on brand name memory. Journal of Marketing Research, 28,
406-416.
Subramani, M. & Walden, E. (2001). The impact of e-commerce
announcements on the market value of firms. Information Systems
Research, 12(2), 135-154.
Szymanski, D.M., Bharadwaj, S.G. & Varadarajan, P.R. (1993). An
analysis of the market share-profitability relationship. Journal of
marketing, 57, 1-18.
Winer, R.S. (1979). An Analysis of the time-varying effects of
advertising: The case of Lydia Pinkham. Journal of Business, 52(4),
563-76.
Winer, R.S. (1980). Estimation of a longitudinal model to decompose the effects of an advertising stimulus on family consumption. Journal of
Consumer Research, 21, 708-718.
Zufryden, F.S. (1987). A model for relating advertising media
exposures to purchase incidence behavior patterns. Management Science.
Peggy Choong, Niagara University Greg Filbeck, Schweser Study
Program Daniel L. Tompkins, Niagara University Thomas D. Ashman, Union
College
Table 1: Abnormal Returns of Announcements
Average Abnormal Returns (%)
(A.) Event 1: Announcement (B.) Event 2: After Super Bowl
-10 -0.03 0.03
-9 -0.22 * 0.33 **
-8 -0.55 ** -0.20 *
-7 -0.22 (+) -0.14 (+)
-6 -0.50 ** -0.39 **
-5 -0.05 -0.14
-4 -0.19 0.01
-3 0.11 0.32
-2 -0.29 * -0.51 **
-1 -0.41 (+) -0.33 **
0 -0.23 (+) 0.16 *
+1 -0.05 -0.29 *
+2 -0.19 -0.10
+3 -0.39 * 0.01
+4 0.04 -0.63 **
+5 -0.14 0.03
+6 -0.13 -0.35 **
+7 0.13 -0.25
+8 -0.15 -0.12
+9 0.06 -0.31
+10 -0.34 0.26
** Significant at the p=0.01 level
* Significant at the p=0.05 level
(+) Significant at the p=0.10 level
Table 2: Cumulative Abnormal Returns for Announcement Event Dates
Windows Cumulative Abnormal Returns (CAR) (%)
Event 1: Announcement Event 2: After Super Bowl
-10; -6 -1.51 ** -0.37
-10; -1 -2.35 ** -1.02 *
-5; -1 -0.83 * -0.65 (+)
-2; 0 -0.93 ** -0.67 *
-1; 0 -0.64 * -0.16
-1; +1 -0.69 * -0.46 (+)
0; +2 -0.46 * -0.22
+1; +5 -0.72 (+) -0.96 **
+1; +10 -1.15 * -1.73 **
+6; +10 -0.43 -0.76 **
** Significant at the p=0.01 level
* Significant at the p=0.05 level
(+) Significant at the p=0.1 level