Too big to fail and too big to save: dilemmas for banking reform.
Barth, James R. ; Wihlborg, Clas
'Too big to fail' traditionally refers to a bank that is
perceived to generate unacceptable risk to the banking system and
indirectly to the economy as a whole if it were to default and be unable
to fulfill its obligations. Such a bank generally has substantial
liabilities to other banks through the payment system and other
financial links, which can be sources of 'contagion' if a bank
fails. The main objectives in this paper are to identify the different
dimensions of too big to fail and evaluate various proposed reforms for
dealing with this problem. In addition, we document the various
dimensions of size and complexity, which may contribute to or reduce a
bank's systemic risk. Furthermore, we provide an assessment of
economic and political factors shaping the future of too big to fail.
Keywords: financial crises; too big to fail; systemically important
banks; Dodd-Frank Act; Financial Stability Board; regulation and
supervision
JEL Classifications: G18; G21; G28
I. Introduction
'Too big to fail' traditionally refers to a bank that is
perceived to generate unacceptable risk to the banking system and
indirectly to the economy as a whole if it were to default and unable to
fulfil its obligations. Unlike non-financial firms banks generally have
substantial liabilities to other banks through the payment system and
other financial links, which can be sources of contagion if a bank
fails.
In the United States, the practice of treating troubled big banks
differently from troubled small ones dates back to the 1984 bailout of
Continental Illinois Corporation. That taxpayer-funded rescue was based
on fears that a bank collapse of Continental's magnitude would
destabilise the entire financial system (see, for example, Kaufman,
2002; Shull, 2010; and Barth, Prabha, and Swagel, 2012). Those same
fears prompted far bigger bank bailouts, both in the US and Europe,
during the recent global financial crisis. In the wake of that
experience, regulators and banking experts almost unanimously agree that
regulatory reform is essential to ensuring that no bank is ever again
too big to fail.
After the Great Recession too big to fail has become a concern for
financial firms more broadly, since there is substantial
interconnectedness among financial institutions involved in financial
market trading activities that generate liquidity in the markets for a
variety of financial instruments. The financial crisis in 2007-9, which
contributed to the Great Recession, originated outside the traditional
banking system when the liquidity in and value of financial instruments
held by and issued by banks and financial institutions dropped
dramatically.
Outside the US the policy responses to banking crises have long
been characterised by general bailouts of banks' creditors (and
sometimes shareholders as well) in the form of, for example, blanket
guarantees, unlimited liquidity support or state nationalisation, as
documented in Caprio et al. (2005) and Honohan and Klingebiel (2003).
One explanation is that few countries outside the US have had
established special legal procedures for bank insolvencies until very
recently. Failing banks in most countries had to be resolved under
general corporate insolvency law. Resolution under such laws is
time-consuming and not suitable for failing banks with liabilities that
support liquidity in the economy. (1)
After the Continental Illinois failure the US resolution procedures
for banks were strengthened with the implementation of the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act in 1991. Under these
procedures small and midsized banks in the US have been allowed to fail
with consequences for banks' uninsured creditors. The bailout of
large banks but not small and midsized banks during the financial crisis
established too big to fail and the differential treatment of such
banks.
Financial reforms outside the US since the crisis include the
implementation of special procedures for bank resolution, in particular
in the EU, with the intention to address the too big to fail problem as
well. In the US the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer
Protection Act (Dodd-Frank Act) includes procedures for resolving large
banks. We argue that the credibility of these procedures is critical for
the future of too big to fail.
The differential treatment of large banks has been formalised in
the designation of banks as globally systemically important banks
(G-SIBs) and a larger number of systemically important financial
institutions (SIFIs). These designations have implications for their
regulation and supervision, as well as for the degree to which these
financial institutions may enjoy implicit subsidies.
We use the concept of too big to fail to incorporate 'too
complex to fail' as well. We discuss factors affecting complexity
and the impact of these factors on systemic risk. Although complexity
and size are far from perfectly correlated, increased complexity
essentially implies that a financial institution can become too big to
fail at a smaller size.
Our main objectives are to identify the different dimensions of too
big to fail and evaluate various proposed reforms for dealing with this
problem. In addition, we document the various dimensions of size and
complexity, which may contribute to or reduce a bank's systemic
risk.
Some observers argue that the size of an individual bank failing is
less important for a government's decision whether to bail out a
bank than the share of the banking system under stress. For example,
Brown and Ding (2011) emphasise 'too many to fail.' There are
reasons to believe in a separate effect of too big to fail. One is that
the too big to fail bank can be an independent source of crisis.
Furthermore, many small banks are unlikely to fail at exactly the same
time in response to a large shock outside the banking system. A
resolution authority may be able to manage the failures of many banks
one by one over some time without having to fear the same degree of
contagion as in the case of one large bank's failure.
One major cost generated by banks being too big to fail is that
competition between banks of different sizes and degrees of complexity
becomes distorted. If the non-insured creditors of some banks perceive
that these banks are less likely to fail than other banks, the costs of
funding for the relatively safe banks become relatively low. The
International Monetary Fund (April 2014) estimates that the implicit
subsidies given just to G-SIBs in 2011-12 represent $15-$70 billion in
the US, $25--$110 billion in Japan, $20-$110 billion in the United
Kingdom, and up to $90-$300 billion in the Euro Area.
The existence of an implicit subsidy implies also that banks have
strong incentives to achieve sufficient size and/or complexity to enjoy
this competitive advantage. The importance of these incentives relative
to incentives generated by economies of scale and scope as explanations
for the trend towards increased size and complexity is an open question
that we will come back to.
A second cost is associated with 'regulatory capture.' A
few very large banks are likely to have a very strong influence on
regulators, supervisors and legislatures. Regulatory capture may be the
result of explicit lobbying efforts of politicians and financial support
in elections. Less deliberately, regulators and supervisors have a
tendency to develop shared objectives and values with those being
regulated and supervised. (2)
A third cost associated with too big to fail is that it creates a
link between bank risk and sovereign risk. The fiscal costs of bailing
out a large bank can be enormous and, thereby, contribute to a
country's fiscal crisis. For example, the fiscal cost of injecting
capital in the Anglo-Irish bank in Ireland in 2009 amounted to 35 per
cent of Ireland's GDP. Bank rescues in Spain in 2011 similarly
contributed to the debt crisis in that country.
The capital injections in relation to GDP in the US banking system
during the financial crisis were far from the magnitudes of the Irish
and the Spanish rescue operations but the political resistance to
government aid to banks grew strong from both ends of the political
spectrum. A political consensus that banks must never be too big to fail
developed. This consensus is reflected in the Dodd-Frank Act. It
explicitly states that no bank must be too big to fail but there is
widespread scepticism whether the specific reforms are sufficiently
strong to allow a large bank to be resolved in such a way that uninsured
creditors must share in losses. (3) There are similar questions with
respect to the credibility of so-called bail-in rules in the EU Bank
Recovery and Resolution Directive. (4)
The fiscal and political costs associated with bank bailouts during
the financial crisis 2007-9 and the euro debt crisis thereafter suggest
that the large banks in many countries are not only too big to fail but
also 'too big to save.' This view is reflected in the many
proposals to eliminate the too big to fail problem.
The dilemma facing policymakers is that if ongoing reforms do not
credibly eliminate the too big to fail problem the too big to save
problem may become the cause of an inability to deal effectively with
the resolution of large banks in another crisis. The problem may become
particularly acute for banks with large operations in several countries
with conflicting interests with respect to bearing the burdens of crisis
management.
Relatively small countries with large banks with international
operations are particularly vulnerable to the too big to save problem.
The Icelandic banking crisis in 2009 is so far the prime example of too
big to save. Iceland simply did not have the financial resources to
rescue three banks with large international operations.
The paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we present a brief
history of too big to fail. In Section 3 we describe how banking systems
in a number of countries and globally have become increasingly
concentrated and dominated by relatively few giant banks. In Section 4
we focus on complexity as it contributes to systemic risk and discuss
the link between too big to fail and complexity. We present measures
that describe different dimensions of complexity. The criteria developed
by the Financial Stability Board (FSB) to identify G-SIBs are discussed.
Section 5 reviews various policy proposals with the objective to reduce
size and complexity of banks. Costs and benefits of proposals are
discussed. These depend to a large extent on what factors have been
driving the development towards size and complexity. We emphasise that
an efficient organisation of the financial system requires that the
ongoing regulatory reforms strengthen market discipline on banks.
Section 6 concludes with an assessment of economic and political factors
shaping the future of too big to fail.
2. The big keep getting bigger: a brief history of too-big-to-fail
In view of all the concern today over some banks being too big for
regulatory comfort, it is instructive to look back at the circumstances
that gave rise to the decision that bank size per se could be a key
factor in treating big banks that encounter financial difficulties
differently from smaller banks.
The concept of too big to fail seems to have been established in
the US as a result of the $4.5 billion bailout of Continental Illinois
National Bank & Trust Co. of Chicago in 1984. The Wall Street
Journal reported that the Comptroller of the Currency, C. Todd Conover,
told Congress that "the federal government won't currently
allow any of the nation's 11 largest banks to fail." The
article noted that the response to Conover's statement was that the
"government had created a new category of bank: the
'TBTF' bank, for Too Big To Fail". The article pointed
out that this was the first time a government official acknowledged the
existence of such a policy (Carrington, 1984).
The origin of too big to fail in the US may be explained by the
observation that the US was the only advanced country where banks were
allowed to fail at the time. The much more concentrated banking systems
in Europe were generally viewed as akin to public utilities before the
setting of interest rates and the allocation of credit were liberalised
during the 1980s. The banks dominated the financial systems and a
special insolvency law for banks did not exist or was not applied.
Heavily regulated banks were assumed not to fail. (5)
Even when banking crises erupted in Europe after liberalisation in
the early 1990s it was taken for granted that banks would not be allowed
to fail. For example, in the early 1990s the Scandinavian countries used
a combination of nationalisation, blanket guarantees of bank liabilities
and capital injections to manage banking crises.
The attitude in Europe towards bank bailouts did not change until
after the Great Recession in 2007-9. This crisis also triggered an
awareness among taxpayers, policymakers and regulators that too big to
fail was an issue in the public interest that needed to be addressed.
Going back to US developments, the original eleven banks
subsequently shrank to four, while the eleven BHCs were reduced to five.
Only Citibank and Wells Fargo remain with their original holding
company. Continental Illinois was eventually seized by the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corp. and sold to Bank of America. This meant that
despite the earlier bailout of a too-big-to-fail bank, regulators
eventually allowed the same bank to be acquired by a bigger bank, which
became even bigger. The four remaining BHCs accounted for nearly 50 per
cent of the total assets of all BHCs at year-end 2013. In contrast, at
year-end 1983 the holding companies of the eleven original
too-big-to-fail banks accounted for 33 per cent of the total assets of
all BHCs.
3. Just how big are the world's biggest banks?
There are several different ways to measure 'big'. The
relevance of each particular measure depends on the objective of the
analysis. Size per se does not necessarily inform us about the
importance of a bank within the financial system or about the
vulnerability of the real economy from a bank's failure.
We start by focusing on the 100 biggest publicly traded banks in
the world by their total assets, as of the second quarter, 2015. The
banks are headquartered in 25 different countries and the biggest is
Industrial & Commercial Bank of China, with $3,667 billion in
assets. The smallest is Charles Schwab Corporation of the United States
with $164 billion in assets. The biggest bank is therefore 22 times the
size of the 100th biggest bank in the world. There are 22 'trillion
dollar banks' in the world, and four are US banks.
Focusing on total assets, however, does not produce an
apples-to-apples comparison. There is no uniform worldwide accounting
standard for measuring assets. Most of the home countries for banks rely
on International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS), but the US and
others rely on their own Generally Accepted Accounting Principles
(GAAP). Countries that use IFRS, and some that use GAAP, report
derivatives on a gross rather than a net basis. When an adjustment is
made to measure total assets on a comparable basis, the result is a
significant change for several of the world's biggest banks. In
particular, JP Morgan Chase reports total assets of $2.5 trillion under
US GAAP, but $3.3 trillion under IFRS, and the bank jumps from sixth
place to second place among the world's largest banks. Likewise,
Bank of America leaps from ninth place to fifth. More importantly, US
GAAP treatment may be understating the assets of all US banks by a total
of $3.4 trillion.
There are a total of 1,226 publicly traded banks in the 25
countries with total assets of $94 trillion. The 100 biggest banks
account for 8 per cent of all the banks, but 83 per cent of the total
assets. The US has the most publicly traded banks of any nation, with
736 banks. Japan and Russia rank second and third with 97 and 60 banks,
respectively. China is the country whose banks collectively have the
most total assets--$19.2 trillion. The banks in the United States and
Japan are ranked second and third in terms of total assets at $18.2
trillion and $10.0 trillion, respectively. The total assets of the banks
in these three countries total $47.4 trillion, or 50 per cent of assets
of all the banks.
Another way to view the world's 100 biggest banks is not
simply in terms of total assets but their total assets relative to the
total assets of all banks. This may be viewed as a measure of
concentration in banking. In terms of individual countries, the ratio of
the total assets of the biggest banks to total bank assets ranges from a
low of 28 per cent in Taiwan to a high of 99 per cent in Sweden and the
United Kingdom. In the case of the United States, the comparable ratio
is 67 per cent.
Still another way to view the world's 100 biggest banks is by
measuring total assets as a share of GDP in order to measure the burden
on the economy of the failure of large banks. By that measure, Swiss big
banks are by far the world's biggest, with assets equal to 340 per
cent of Switzerland's GDP. Russia's banks would be the
smallest, with assets equal to only 52 per cent of GDP. The fifteen
biggest US banks are at the lower end of the range, with assets equal to
105 per cent of US GDP.
Now consider the distribution of the world's 100 biggest banks
by number and total assets across the 25 countries. The United States
and China, with fourteen, have more banks than any other nation on the
list. Japan ranks second with eight banks and Canada and Spain tie for
third with six banks. The remaining 20 countries account for 52 banks.
Measured by total banking assets, however, China's big banks lead
the world with $19 trillion. The United States' banks come in
second, with combined assets of $12 trillion, and the United Kingdom
ranks third with $8 trillion. Banks in the remaining countries have $39
trillion in assets, or 50 per cent of the worldwide total.
To provide a more historical perspective on the importance of big
banks, one can focus on just the 50 biggest banks in the world. Doing
so, one finds that their total assets relative to world GDP increased to
83 per cent in the second quarter of 2015 from only 15 per cent in 1970.
For purposes of comparison, the ratio of total assets of the 50 biggest
US banks relative to US GDP increased to 83 per cent in the second
quarter of 2015 from only 25 per cent in 1970. These figures illustrate
what has been called the financialisation of many advanced economies in
the form of expansion of market-oriented financial activities that are
not directly linked to intermediation. (6)
Turning to concentration in the banking industry, the largest 25
banks account for about half of the total assets of all banks worldwide.
The assets of the same banks are almost two-thirds of world GDP. A
relatively few of the world's 1,862 publicly traded banks are truly
big in terms of either their share of the global bank assets or global
GDP.
There are still other ways in which to rank the size of banks. Two
of these ways are to measure individual banks by their assets as a share
of either total banking assets in their home countries or as a share of
their home-country GDP. There is a weakness with these figures in that
they do not allow us to distinguish between domestic and foreign assets
of the banks. To measure the importance of a bank within a
country's banking system we should include only domestic assets but
this figure is not available for all banks. We return to banks'
cross-border activities in the next section on complexity.
We now consider the size of individual banks relative to total
banking assets in their respective countries. ING Groep NV is at top
with 88 per cent of Netherland's total banking assets. Among US
banks, JP Morgan Chase was in first place with 13.5 per cent of the
total. In the global context, however, JP Morgan Chase ranks only 57th
among the world's biggest 100 banks. This means that the biggest US
banks are relatively small when compared to the world's other 100
biggest banks on the basis of the share of an individual bank's
total assets relative to all the banking assets in the bank's home
country.
The other way to compare individual banks is by their total assets
relative to the home country's GDP. (7) In this case, Danske Bank
ranks number 1 with assets equal to 178 per cent of Denmark's GDP.
JP Morgan Chase, with total assets equal to 13.6 per cent of US GDP,
ranks 67th worldwide. In short, the biggest US banks are relatively
small players in their own country when compared to many of their
counterparts elsewhere in the world. Thus, US banks are less likely to
be considered too big to save than many smaller banks in smaller
countries.
Regardless of how they are organised, most of the world's big
banks have a mix of businesses with very different kinds of assets as
well as different involvement in cross-border activity. The mix of
business areas within a bank is one factor affecting its complexity.
4. Dimensions of complexity
4.1. Complexity and systemic risk in the literature
In this subsection we discuss the link between complexity in our
terminology and systemic risk, and review recent literature on this
topic. We then discuss different dimensions of complexity with the
FSB's criteria for G-SIBs as a starting point.
Not surprisingly, financial markets assess the value of big banks
in very different ways. In the United States, for example, the ratio of
market value to book value for the fifteen biggest banks ranges from a
high of 3.66 for American Express, with a close second of 3.47 for
Charles Schwab Corporation, to a low of 0.74 for Bank of America, as of
the end of the second quarter, 2015. The markets clearly recognise that
the fifteen big US banks represent a range of different business models,
which suggests that they should not be viewed as the same when it comes
to tackling the problem of too big to fail, especially any proposals to
break them up. (8)
An important aspect of the complexity of a bank is lack of
consistency between legal, functional and financial organisation.
Carmassi and Tierring (2015) emphasise that most banks are organised
functionally with little resemblance to the legal organisation. As a
result, the valuation and identification of a failing (legal)
entity's assets and liabilities becomes time-consuming and complex.
(9) The operations of a failing functional entity may be conducted in a
large number of different domestic and foreign legal entities, which at
the same time serve other functional entities. Thus, one functional
entity may not be easily resolved in insolvency proceedings without
dragging other functional entities into the proceedings. The complexity
of resolution is amplified if the bank operates cross-border in
different legal jurisdictions.
Lack of financial independence of functional and legal entities can
be added as another source of complexity in resolution. It is common
that a BHC issues a large part of the debt that is being allocated to
different functions and subsidiaries. It is also common that equity
investment in subsidiaries is debt financed by the parent. This
financial complexity is a source of financial contagion between separate
legal entities.
Most large banks in the US and Europe are legally organised in
hundreds, sometimes thousands, of legally separate subsidiaries with
little resemblance to the functional organisation. In order to solve
problems of excessive size and complexity we have to understand why
banks have grown to the size and complexity they have. Carmassi and
Herring (2015) refer to a number of possible reasons, including
economies of scale and scope, regulation and tax rules.
Carmassi and Herring (2013) and Laeven et al. (2014) use the number
of subsidiaries of a BHC as an important indicator of complexity. This
measure clearly cannot capture all dimensions of complexity. Its value
as a proxy can be related to the lack of correspondence between legal
and functional organisation. If the legal subdivision into subsidiaries
had corresponded to the functional subdivision of the firm, a large
number of subsidiaries could have been an indicator of a simplified and
more transparent organisation since each legal and functional unit could
be resolvable as a stand-alone unit.
4.2. Dimensions of complexity across countries and banks
The FSB uses 'complexity' as one of several factors
capturing systemic risk effects and for the designation of some banks as
G-SIBs. The same criteria for identifying G-SIBs are used by the BCBS to
determine the stricter regulatory capital requirements for such banks.
The G-SIB designation is based on five separate characteristics: size,
interconnectedness, substitutability and financial institution
infrastructure, cross-jurisdictional activity, and complexity.
Complexity in the terminology of the FSB depends only on OTC derivatives
activity, trading and available-for-sale (AFS) securities, and Level 3
assets (BCBS, 2014).
Complexity in the FSB's terminology is strongly related to
interconnectedness since derivatives as well as trading activities,
which are captured in complexity, explain a large share of the number of
links to other financial institutions. The FSB measures
interconnectedness using the wholesale funding ratio, and
intra-financial system assets and liabilities. Cross-jurisdictional
activity is also treated as separate from complexity. Such activity
contributes strongly to complexity as measured by the number of
subsidiaries in the literature noted above.
Complexity also includes Level 3 assets, which are assets that are
not traded in markets and can be assessed in terms of 'fair
value' only by means of a bank-specific valuation model.
Traditional bank loans would be included in this category. They cannot
be easily valued and sold in bankruptcy. Thus, systemic risk arises both
in traditional bank loans and involvement in securitisation and
market-based activities more generally. The weights of different factors
contributing to systemic risk are therefore important for the relative
systemic risk ranking of banks with different business models.
Substitutability captures that contagion to the financial and real
sectors which depends on the structure of the financial system and the
existence of other institutions and services that may substitute for
operations of a failing bank. Substitutability would decline if a large
bank provides, for example, credit services through traditional bank
lending as well as an underwriter of securities. The separation of
commercial and investment banking would increase substitutability.
There is no similar international standard for the designation of a
bank as a Systemically Important Financial Institution (SIFI), as
discussed in Chouinard and Ens (2013). Each country chooses what is a
SIFI and the specific regulation and supervision they are subject to. In
the US the Dodd-Frank Act specifies an asset size of $50 billion as the
borderline for being subject to special regulation and resolution
procedures. There is an inconsistency between the criteria for
designations of SIFIs and G-SIBs (see Barth and Sau, 2015).
As already noted, cross-border comparisons of complexity and
systemic risk are difficult at either the individual or aggregate bank
level. Largely because of differences in regulation between countries,
the assets of big banks can include different mixtures of bank loans,
securities, insurance policies and other products (see Barth, Caprio and
Levine, 2006). This diversity is wide even among US BHCs. When one
examines the composition of assets and liabilities of the world's
100 largest banks, it is found that the share of traditional bank assets
(loans) and liabilities (deposits) varies even more across countries
than across banks. The composition of revenues varies as well.
Non-interest revenues and gains from trading and derivatives activities
play a much greater role for US and UK banks than for most other large
banks with the exception of the two large Swiss banks and Deutsche Bank.
Items that can be used to describe complexity according to our more
general terminology incorporating organisation takes the form of
subsidiaries, cross-border activity, interconnectedness and involvement
in market-oriented, non-traditional banking activities. In particular,
we find using complexity factors that are available for the 100 largest
banks that size and the number of subsidiaries are significantly and
positively correlated. Further results confirm the findings of Laeven et
al. (2014) that size is not correlated with complexity in all its
dimensions. The only significant positive correlations are with the
number of subsidiaries, and derivatives and trading positions. Other
dimensions of complexity are correlated to some extent with each other
indicating that banks with relatively little involvement in traditional
banking are strongly involved in securities markets, and in derivatives
and trading.
We ask next if the factors associated with size and complexity also
affect banks' risk of failure. This is done by performing
regressions with each bank's accounting based Z-score and ROA as
dependent variables, and with data for the 100 banks in 2014. We find
that several variables indicating high complexity are associated with
relatively high bank risk as well as systemic risk. Laeven, et al.
(2014) found that size, number of subsidiaries and involvement in
market-based activities increased systemic risk. With the exception of
size, our results indicate that these variables are also associated with
greater bank risk.
5. Addressing too big to fail and complexity
The purpose of the regulatory reforms being proposed or already
being carried out is to prevent future banking crises whenever possible
and to lessen the severity of those that do occur. (10) Too big to fail
is viewed as a source of implicit protection of banks' creditors
and, thereby, excessive risk-taking that contributes to the likelihood
of a crisis. This situation is exacerbated, moreover, due to the moral
hazard that arises when bank depositors are protected from losses by a
government deposit insurance system. Complexity of bank organisations is
also viewed as a source of excessive risk-taking as a result of
opaqueness to supervisors and resolution authorities, as well as to
other actors in the financial system. The problems associated with the
resolution of large and complex banks may increase the severity of a
crisis and the fiscal costs of crisis management.
The reforms attempt to tackle too big to fail in four ways: 1)
restricting the size of banks; 2) restricting the scope of bank
activities through separation of different activities into separate
legal and functional entities (ring-fencing); 3) requiring higher
capital levels for systemically important institutions; 4) providing an
orderly framework for shutting down and resolving troubled banks while
minimising the risk of contagion. The different approaches are not
entirely independent. Restrictions on scale and scope can be difficult
to separate. Some reform proposals may have effects in more than one of
these dimensions. For example, so-called 'living wills' may
affect both the scope and scale of activities, and the ability of
authorities to resolve a failing bank.
5.1. Restricting the size of banks
The first type of reform involves restricting the size of banks.
The Dodd-Frank Act limits the size of banks by prohibiting bank mergers
or acquisitions if the resulting bank would hold more than 10 per cent
of total nationwide bank deposits or more than 10 per cent of the
aggregate consolidated liabilities of all financial companies. These
limits could impede future mergers and acquisitions in the banking
industry. (11)
As regards the potential impact of the merger restriction based on
deposits in the US, only the largest US bank, JP Morgan Chase, already
exceeds the limit on deposits and, therefore, would be prohibited from
any further external growth. Other banks still have room for expansion,
but it would be limited. Meanwhile, US Federal Reserve Governor Tarullo
(2009) has suggested limiting non-deposit liabilities of US banks to a
specified percentage of US GDP. If those liabilities were limited to 2
per cent of GDP, as proposed by some lawmakers in the Safe, Accountable,
Fair and Efficient (SAFE) Banking Act of 2012, (12) five banks would be
immediately prohibited from any further mergers and acquisitions.
Another ten banks would have some leeway for further external growth.
Johnson and Kwak (2010, pp. 214-15) also state that "the
simplest solution [to the TBTF problem] is a hard cap on size: no
financial institution would be allowed to control or have an ownership
interest in assets worth more than a fixed percentage of US GDP".
They add that "as a first proposal, this limit should be no more
than 4 per cent of GDP, or roughly $570 billion in assets today".
For investment banks, they state that "as an initial guideline, an
investment bank (such as Goldman Sachs) should be effectively limited in
size to 2 per cent of GDP, or roughly $285 billion today." Based
upon GDP in the second quarter of 2015, 4 per cent amounts to $716
billion. JP Morgan Chase and Bank of America are the only two banks that
have assets that exceed this amount. Moreover, Goldman Sachs and Morgan
Stanley both have assets that exceed 2 per cent of GDP, or $358 billion.
The problem, of course, is that there is no bright line that
enables one to distinguish easily between big banks that pose a systemic
risk and those that do not pose such a risk. To the extent that the
demarcation line that is chosen is then adjusted to account for
different degrees of 'bigness', the end result might once
again lead back to a too big to fail problem. Indeed, the G-SIBs are of
different asset sizes and some of these banks are smaller than other
banks not identified as so. Moreover, some of the US banks are
identified as G-SIBs even though their asset size is substantially less
than 4 or even 2 per cent of US GDP.
A potential cost of limits on size is that they could reduce
economies of scale in banking, not to mention economies of scope since
increasing size often is associated with diversification from, for
example, traditional banking to more market-based activities. Thus, size
limits could increase the cost of banking services unless economies of
scale and scope are not generated by reduced funding costs from being
too big to fail. In this regard, Wheelock and Wilson (2012, p. 171)
found that "... as recently as 2006, most U$ banks faced increasing
returns to scale, suggesting that scale economies are a plausible (but
not necessarily the only) reason for the growth in average bank
size". In addition, Hughes and Mester (2011, p. 23) found "...
evidence of large scale economies at smaller banks and even larger
economies at large banks....". They added that these measured
economies of scale did not result from implicit subsidies from being
considered too big to fail. To the extent that US banks are limited in
size, they may also be at a competitive disadvantage to the big banks in
other countries that do not impose such limits. The implication is
clear: one should not rush to limit bank size unless one can be
confident that the benefits outweigh the costs. (13) International
comparability of limits to bank size should also be considered.
To the extent that increasing scale is associated with
diversification into additional financial services we must consider the
evidence with respect to economies of scope.
5.2 Restrictions on the scope of activities
The second type of reform involves requiring banks to legally and
functionally separate certain particularly risky activities or simply
barring banks from those activities altogether. The Liikanen report
produced by the European Commission proposes the separation of
proprietary trading of securities and derivatives, and certain other
activities linked to those markets, from deposit-taking banks within a
banking organisation. The Vickers report proposes
'ring-fencing' of retail banking from wholesale/ investment
banking in the UK. The ring-fenced banks would take retail deposits,
provide payments and services, and supply credit to households and
businesses. In the US, the Volcker Rule prohibits an insured depository
institution or its affiliates from engaging in 'proprietary
trading'. It also prohibits insured institutions from sponsoring or
acquiring ownership interests in hedge funds or private equity funds.
There are several theoretical arguments underlying the mentioned
separation proposals. One is that simpler banks pose less risk to the
financial system and the broader economy, because some activities are
inherently more risky and simpler organisations are more transparent for
both market participants and bank supervisors. A second argument is that
banks involved in, for example, investment banking and trading benefit
from deposit insurance systems, which are intended primarily to protect
creditors in the retail banking system. A third argument is that
operational and financial separation of non-traditional banking
activities would simplify resolution and allow entities involved in
these activities to fail without the need to bailout creditors. Thereby,
market discipline on risk-taking in these activities would be
strengthened. In this sense restrictions on activities can be viewed as
complementary to resolution procedures.
If these arguments in favour of restrictions on activities are
accepted, it is still necessary to balance the benefits against
potentially lost economies of scope. According to Laeven et al. (2014)
there is evidence that there are diseconomies of scope when banks move
from traditional commercial banking into market-based activities. These
diseconomies would be generated by agency costs (Boot and Ratnovski,
2012) and potential conflicts of interest (Schmid and Walter, 2009). On
the other hand, a large literature following Kroszner and Rajan (1994)
points to information advantages of banks involved in both traditional
banking and market-based activities.
The verdict on economies of scope and which particular activities
benefit from them is still out. This is an argument for allowing the
market to determine the most efficient organisational structure.
However, the market will accomplish this only if there are no implicit
subsidies in banking and banks are allowed to fail with consequences for
shareholders and creditors.
The argument that ring-fencing of commercial banking from
market-based financial services would enhance market discipline by
removing explicit and implicit government support from market-based
activities can also be questioned. The argument is based on the premise
that governments are compelled to bail out commercial banks as sources
of contagion but not financial firms involved in market-based
activities. The financial crisis demonstrated that financial system
contagion occurs through market-based activities as much as from
traditional commercial banking. The pressure on governments to bail out,
for example, investment banks may be as large as the pressure to bail
out commercial banks. The Lehman Brothers experience may have
strengthened this pressure. If so, the remaining benefits from
ring-fencing could be increased transparency and lower resolution costs,
while the costs could be reduced economies of scope.
Goodhart (2014) notes that proposals to dismantle universal banks
into separate retail and wholesale parts are based on a "misreading
of causes of the financial crisis". Similarly, the Volcker rule has
been motivated by an opinion that proprietary trading was a significant
factor in the recent financial crisis. However, the losses that led to
problems at Lehman Brothers, Bear Stearns, IndyMac, Washington Mutual
and other failed institutions were mainly connected to mortgage-backed
securities and real estate, rather than to losses from the kind of
trading that would be targeted by the Volcker Rule. (14) Nor is there
clear evidence that separating commercial banking from investment
banking as suggested by the Vickers report would increase safety.
Despite strong separation between the two businesses in the 1980s under
the Glass-Steagall Act, several big banks nevertheless almost failed
because of bad loans in Latin America. Likewise, legions of
savings-and-loans failed due to real estate loans. This suggests it is
unlikely that simply reinstating Glass-Steagall would prevent problems
at big banks in the future. In a sense, it is not even easy to pinpoint
the problem that the Volcker Rule would solve. This is not to say that
there could not be benefits from it. On the face of it, simpler
institutions may become more transparent, less prone to excessive
risk-taking and less subject to conflicts of interest. On the other
hand, regulated reorganisation may lead to a conflict relative to
incentives to exploit economies of scope. If so banks may try to avoid
consequences of regulation in non-transparent transactions and
activities.
Some evidence regarding trading losses might be helpful in this
regard (see Barth and McCarthy, 2012). Since 1990, there have been
fifteen instances when traders at different firms lost at least $ 1
billion (in 2011 dollars). The losses totalled nearly $60 billion and
ranged from a low of $1.1 billion on ill-fated foreign exchange
derivatives at a Japanese subsidiary of Shell Oil to a high of $9
billion on credit default swaps at Morgan Stanley. Four of the firms
were banks, two were investment banks, two were hedge funds, one was a
local government, and six were manufacturing or petrochemical firms. In
other words, almost half the losses were not at financial services firms
but at institutions that typically use financial products for hedging
purposes.
Look at the same fifteen losses above in relation to the equity
those institutions had at the time. The losses at the banks were less
threatening to financial stability than those at the non-bank firms.
Relative to equity, the largest losses were at non-banks. Thus, the
Volcker Rule may be targeting the wrong firms. The more regulators limit
banking activities, moreover, the more likely they are to create
incentives for those same activities to take place in the so-called
shadow banking system. In the process, however, risks may also shift
from the banking industry to the shadow banking system.
The post-crisis regulatory regime embodied in the Dodd-Frank Act
does not seek to break up big banks or to reinstitute Glass-Steagall
barriers between commercial and investment banking. This perhaps
reflects the observation that the failures of banks in the crisis are
not well correlated with the end of the Glass-Steagall restrictions.
Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers both suffered failures but both were
essentially pure investment banks. By contrast, JP Morgan Chase combined
investment and commercial banking but weathered the crisis well. An
alternative to Glass-Steagall-like restrictions would be for regulators
to focus on activities that appear to pose particular risks, and to act
more pre-emptively to head off systemic problems. This approach is
embodied in the creation of the Financial Stability Oversight Council,
an umbrella group of federal regulators that is meant to watch over the
entire financial system. One, however, is right to question whether this
new approach will indeed be successful. (15)
The relatively strong case for separation in the form of
operational and financial ring-fencing exists for cross-border banking
since there is no agreement on how to coordinate conflicting interests
and resolution procedures. The case for economies of scale and scope
across borders appears weak. Operational ring-fencing would make it
possible to allow an entity in one country to fail without serious
operational repercussions for other parts of a financial group. New
Zealand has implemented an operational ring-fencing rule stating that
subsidiaries of foreign banks must be operationally separable within 24
hours. Financial ring-fencing would protect the capital of a bank in one
country from failures in other countries. Several countries including
the US have implemented such ring-fencing for foreign branches as well
as subsidiaries.
As a general observation, complexity would be reduced by greater
correspondence between functional and legal organisation. To achieve
such reorganisation based on scale and scope economies among functions
it is necessary to obtain a better understanding of why banks choose to
organise with great complexity. As noted, Carmassi and Herring (2015)
refer to banks' ability to take advantage of regulatory frameworks
and tax rules in combination with economies of scope and scale to
explain the current structure, but explicit knowledge of this issue is
lacking.
5.3. Requiring higher capital levels for systemically important
banks
The third type of reform involves requiring banks to hold
additional equity capital. This is meant to ensure that firms have a
bigger buffer against losses and a greater ability to survive a crisis.
More equity capital would also provide more protection for taxpayers
against future bailouts. The guidelines for new and more stringent
capital requirements under Basel III are phased in over the period 2013
to 2019. The leverage ratio will be 3 per cent in 2019, while the
risk-based capital requirement will be as high as 13 per cent for some
banks, and even as high as 16.5 per cent for G-SIBs. The FSB, moreover,
has confirmed its final proposal for Total Loss Absorbing Capacity
(TLAC) calling for G-SIBs to hold, on top of the required minimum CET1
of 4.5 per cent, an additional 11.5 per cent of 'loss
absorbency' in the form of Tier 1 and Tier 2 capital relative to
risk-weighted assets, rising to 13.5 per cent by 2022. Importantly, TLAC
is focused on meeting this requirement in part through long-term,
unsecured debt that can be converted into equity when a bank fails or
reaches a critical market-value trigger (contingent convertible debt or
CoCos) (16). This is meant as an additional measure to put an end to too
big to fail by forcing bondholders to inject capital into a big bank
that fails rather than taxpayers.
In a first, the Basel III agreement among international bank
regulators, as just noted, calls for a minimum leverage ratio. This
ratio is not risk-based, like the other capital guidelines. According to
Haldane (2012, p. 19), "... the leverage ratio [should play] the
frontstop role [in Basel III] given its simplicity and superior
predictive performance". He adds that "the more complex the
bank, the stronger is this case". Furthermore, we concur with
Hoenig (2012), who states that "an effective capital rule should
result in a bank having capital that approximates what the market would
require without the safety net in place. The measure that best achieves
these goals is what I have been calling the tangible equity to tangible
assets ratio". During the US financial crisis, this seemed to be
the only ratio that anyone paid attention to insofar as banks in general
were amply capitalised by nearly all the other capital ratios.
Additional capital requirements for big or systemically important
banks provide a disincentive for size (and perhaps also for complexity
or interconnectedness). These requirements might also be seen as a
'tax' that offsets the possible funding advantages of big and
complex banks - a disincentive for size and complexity as defined by the
criteria for G-SIBs and SIFIs. How blunt this 'tax instrument'
is as a disincentive for size and complexity depends on how capital
requirements depend on size and complexity. SIFIs are so far identified
primarily by size, while G-SIBs are identified by complexity
characteristics as well. We have discussed the difficulty of analysing
the relation between complexity and systemic risk. Another difficulty is
to specify a relationship for the marginal tax (capital requirement) of
increasing size and complexity. If a tax is imposed only at specific
size and complexity triggers, the marginal tax of increasing size and
complexity beyond the trigger is zero. In this case the capital
requirement tax is ineffective as a disincentive to increase size and
complexity. The extra capital requirement tax becomes primarily a
payment for the latent negative externality, though the implicit revenue
from the tax accrues to private suppliers of capital rather than to the
government.
As already noted, it should be kept in mind that big banks provide
benefits as well as costs to society, a point discussed by the Clearing
House Association (2011). Moreover, the capital charge, as usual with a
tax, results in a deadweight loss in the form of reduced lending and
economic activity. The quantitative importance of this impact remains a
subject of considerable debate. Admati et al. (2010, 2013) see little
negative impact of higher capital requirements and recommend an equity
ratio as high as 30 per cent. Miles et al. (2013) argue along with
Admati et al. that an optimal capital ratio is much higher than current
levels. But Kashyap, Stein, and Hanson (2010) see a meaningful impact on
bank funding costs during the transition period as banks raise
additional equity capital, and then a modest ongoing impact. Research by
regulators points to modest impacts, while banks and their associations
point to greater impacts. In the wake of the recent crisis, it is
certain that big banks will hold more capital, both at the insistence of
regulators and of their own volition. Given the considerable changes in
the banking industry and its more stringent regulation, the ongoing
impacts of higher capital standards will be understood only over time.
One danger of setting the capital requirement very high as
recommended by Admati et al. (2010), is that it creates a large
discrepancy between required and desired equity financing. Such a
discrepancy is likely to create strong incentives to manipulate, evade
and avoid the requirement. The stronger these incentives are the greater
are the costs to supervise and examine banks' compliance with the
regulation. These costs are likely to be particularly high within the
Basel Capital Accord framework for risk-weighting based on internal
models that enable substantial manipulation of risk-estimates.
5.4. What to do about big bank failures?
The fourth type of reform involves changes to the framework for
dealing with the collapse of big or systemically important banks. There
are two motivations behind such policies: first, to better ensure the
stability of the system; second, to alert market participants that banks
are more likely to be allowed to fail and that creditors will be forced
to take losses. That awareness may help remove advantages that big banks
have previously enjoyed by being perceived as too big to fail and,
thereby, strengthen market discipline on banks' risk-taking. (17)
The Dodd-Frank Act requires banks to devise their own 'living
wills', or plans for possible recovery of a bank's core
business by disinvestment in other financial activities and an orderly
shutdown if the bank actually fails. This could prove to be a symbolic
step, because no one knows how or if the plans will work in the event of
an actual crisis. Even so, however, the preparation of a living will may
provide an additional signal that regulators will let banks collapse
rather than bail them out in the future. Living wills are subject to
regulators' approval and they allow regulators to intervene to
separate activities. Thus, the living wills have the potential to lead
to a process of reduced complexity and greater correspondence between
legal and functional organisations.
The new orderly liquidation authority in the Dodd-Frank Act, as
well as the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive within the EU's
banking union, could fundamentally change the way in which failures at
big banks are resolved. (18) Bondholders and other creditors are now
more likely to incur losses if a bank fails, even though the deployment
of government resources is allowed to support a bank and slow its demise
through the Orderly Liquidation Fund. Absent additional congressional
action (which is now hard to imagine, given the unpopularity of the
Troubled Asset Relief Program), in the case of a future failure of a big
bank that involves the resolution of the holding company beyond simply
the insured depository institutions, bondholders will incur losses. The
EU's Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive also allows for the
deployment of a fund in resolution while specifying a minimum of
'bail-in' of unsecured creditors.
It is difficult to predict how the new resolution authority under
the Dodd-Frank Act and the Single Resolution Mechanism in the EU will be
used. (19) In the US the FDIC might use its new authority to arrange a
debt-for-equity swap that recapitalises the failing bank, turning the
former bondholders into the new owners. The possibility of having such a
swap imposed on bondholders should affect the terms under which
potential creditors are willing to provide funding to banks that might
be put through a resolution. One risk is that the new resolution
authority could give providers of funding an incentive to flee at the
first hint of trouble. The threat of such bank runs is an important
disciplining device, but it could also lead to more hair-trigger
responses and inadvertently prove destabilising.
Either way, however, the resolution authority will be incomplete
and perhaps unworkable until there is more international coordination of
bankruptcy regimes. In the case of Lehman's failure, for example,
the UK bankruptcy regime disrupted the operations of many US-based firms
when it froze their overseas assets. Of the thirteen US banks of the 100
biggest banks for which information is available, seven have foreign
assets. Among the latter banks, Citigroup has the largest share of
foreign assets at 46 per cent, while Capital One has the smallest share
at 4.5 per cent. Importantly, international coordination of regulatory
regimes for both normal times and during resolution or bankruptcy
procedures will be crucial for the continued evolution of the global
financial system. (20)
One aspect of international coordination is the issue of
single-entry point vs multiple entry point resolution. Strongly
integrated banks without clear separation of banks across countries and
activities require single-entry point resolution. To achieve agreement
on a single entry point for international banks it is necessary that
regulators in countries where the banks are operating mutually recognise
resolution regimes. Conflicting interests of countries in a crisis
situation implies that such mutual recognition is currently not in
sight.
The organisational complexity discussed here has led to a
discussion of 'single-entry point' vs 'multiple entry
point' resolution procedures. A single entry point for a large
global bank implies recognition of the near-impossibility of resolving
individual functional and legal entities. It is clearly appropriate if a
bank is organised as a universal bank supplying a variety of financial
services within different divisions of one legal unit. The different
divisions can be thought of as branches without financial independence
and functionally integrated to the extent that there are economies of
scope to be exploited.
At the other extreme of bank organisation we can imagine a large
number of subsidiaries defined by separate functions. Firewalls would
separate the operations and the subsidiaries would be responsible for
their own debt financing. The different units would essentially be
stand-alone units with common ownership. Multiple entry point resolution
is appropriate for this type of organisation. There would be relatively
little complexity since each legal unit could default on its own without
severe repercussions for other subsidiaries within the banking group. On
the other hand, in this organisation economies of scope between
functional areas cannot be exploited. The systemic risk consequences of
a failing entity within this kind of bank organisation are relatively
easier to manage.
A key problem facing the Orderly Liquidation procedures in the US
as well as the bail-in rules in the EU's Single Resolution
Mechanism is to achieve credibility that creditors of large banks will
not be bailed out in a crisis. Loopholes in the rules for activation of
the procedures will always exist and allow regulators to bailout
creditors for fear of contagion. It is possible that a large bank must
fail without a bailout in order to achieve credibility of the resolution
procedures. (21)
6. Summary and conclusion
That some banks are too big to fail is not new. Neither is the
challenge for policymakers to implement reforms that eliminate the need
to bailout big banks. The regulatory regimes for big banks in many
countries are undergoing changes from those that prevailed before the
global financial crisis. Banks will now be required to hold more
capital, have more robust access to liquidity, undergo increased
regulatory scrutiny, and face restrictions on certain activities. Many
of these changes are still evolving as some reforms are being
implemented and proposals for additional reforms are still being
evaluated.
A fundamental problem is that we do not understand well why the
world's financial systems are dominated by relatively few large and
organisationally complex banks. It is uncertain whether complexity to a
large extent is driven by economies of scope, by the implicit subsidy
associated with high bailout probability or by tax incentives and the
design of regulation, including capital requirements. The most effective
approach to complexity cannot be assessed without greater knowledge of
these factors.
Removal of the implicit subsidy associated with size and complexity
would provide information and incentives for banks to organise
themselves over time based on economies (and diseconomies) of scale and
scope. Current regulatory approaches to complexity include requirements
for separation or ring-fencing of particular activities, implementation
of resolution procedures that would enable banks to fail with a minimum
of bailouts of creditors and a minimum of contagion, and additional
capital requirements for systemically important banks.
There is little doubt that the various measures to separate
activities within banking groups, including living wills, will induce
large banks to adjust their organisation. The extent to which banking
structures will be simplified sufficiently to enable resolution of
failing banks without bailouts depends very much on regulators' and
supervisors' behaviour. The credibility that the new procedures
will be applied in a crisis of one or more large banks has not been
established, and most likely will not be until there is another crisis.
Big banks do possess considerable power that may be used to
influence the regulatory authorities to pursue policies that increase
the risk of a systemic crisis. The regulatory authorities, moreover, may
also pursue such policies based upon a bias in favour of banks. In the
absence of evidence that the benefits exceed the cost of breaking up big
banks, policymakers may simply have to monitor the incremental reforms
they have already begun to implement and make adjustments as the results
become available. Barth, Caprio and Levine (2012) point out that given
the poor past performance of the regulatory authorities, it may also be
prudent to establish procedures to hold them more accountable for
achieving stability in the future.
NOTES
(1) See Wihlborg (2012).
(2) See Barth et al. (2012) for an analysis of regulatory capture
in the US.
(3) See Barth, Prabha and Wihlborg (2015).
(4) See European Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee, Statement
No 39, 14 November, 2014.
(5) Philip Davis (1995) provides an overview of the evolution of
financial systems and their fragility since 1970 with an emphasis on the
period 1988-93.
(6) Beck et al. (2014) find that GDP growth is strongly linked to
financial intermediation while financialisation is not.
(7) One might wish to distinguish between the ratio of domestic
assets to domestic GDP and the ratio of foreign assets to the GDPs in
which the assets are located.
(8) For additional information on different business models of
European banks, see Ayadi et al. (2012).
(9) Carmassi and Herring (2013) discuss how the Lehman
Brother's bankruptcy was complicated and contagious among different
Lehman subsidiaries as a result of the way assets and liabilities were
booked in subsidiaries without correspondence to the functional
organisation.
(10) This section draws upon Barth, Prabha and Swagel (2012).
(11) The Dodd-Frank Act provides exceptions to these limits in the
case of mergers and acquisitions of troubled institutions.
(12) This is a bill introduced by Senator Sherrod Brown (see
http:// www.brown.senate.gov/newsroom/press/release/
brown-introduces-bill-to-end-too-big-to-fail-policies-prevent-mega-banks-from-putting-our-economy-at-risk).
(13) See Saunders and Walter (2010) for a more general discussion
on this issue.
(14) See Barth et al. (2009).
(15) For further discussion of this and related issues, see Barth,
Caprio and Levine (2012).
(16) See Calomiris and Herring (2013).
(17) See Mullineux (2012) for a discussion of the role of
governance with respect to too big to fail banks.
(18) For a discussion of resolution procedures in other countries,
see Wihlborg (2012).
(19) Brown and Din? (2011) find that a government is less likely to
take over or less likely to close a failing bank if other banks in that
country are weak. They further argue that this too-many-to-fail effect
was present in the US Savings and Loan Crisis of the 1980s and the
Japanese Banking Crisis of the 1990s.
(20) See, for example, Prabha and Wihlborg (2012) for a discussion
of this issue as it relates to global bank organisational structure.
(21) See, for example, Barth et al. (2015) and European Shadow
Financial Regulatory Committee (2014).
REFERENCES
Admati, A. and Hellwig, M. (2013), The Bankers' New Clothes,
Princeton University Press.
Admati, A.R., DeMarzo, P.M., Hellwig, M.F. and Pfleiderer, P.
(2010), 'Fallacies, irrelevant facts, and myths in the discussion
of capital regulation: why bank equity is not expensive', Stanford
GSB Research Paper No. 2063, September.
Ayadi, R., Arbak, E. and De Groen, W.P. (2012), Regulation of
European Banks and Business Models: Towards a New Paradigm? Center for
European Policy Studies.
Barth, J.R., Caprio, G. and Levine, R. (2006), Rethinking Bank
Regulation: Till Angels Govern, Cambridge University Press.
--(2012), Guardians of Finance: Making Regulators Work for Us, MIT
Press.
Barth, J.R., Li, T., Lu, W., Phumiwasana, T. and Yago, G. (2009),
The Rise and Fall of the US Mortgage and Credit Markets: A Comprehensive
Analysis of the Meltdown, John Wiley & Sons.
Barth, J.R., Li, T., Prabha, A.P., Chiang, Y. and Li, L. (2012),
'Industrial loan companies: where banking and commerce meet',
Financial Markets, Institutions & Instruments, 21 (1), pp. 1-69.
Barth, J.R. and McCarthy, D. (2012), 'Trading losses: a little
perspective on a large problem', Milken Institute, November.
Barth, J.R., Prabha, A.P. and Swagel, P. (2012), 'Just how big
is the too big to fail problem?', Journal of Banking Regulation,
13, pp. 265-99.
Barth, J.R., Prabha, A.P. and Wihlborg, C. (2015), 'The
Dodd-Frank Act: key features, implementation progress, and financial
system impact', in Barth, J.R. and Kaufman, G.G. (eds), The First
Great Financial Crisis of the 21st Century: A Retrospective, December.
Barth, J.R. and Sau, M. (2015), 'Designating bank SIFIs: an
arbitrary threshold for risk', Milken Institute Report, November.
Beck, T., Degryse, H. and Kneer, C. (2014), 'Is more finance
better? Disentangling intermediation and size effects of financial
systems 'Journal of Financial Stability, 10, February, pp. 50-64.
Boot, A.W.A. and Ratnovski (2012), 'Banking and trading',
IMF Working Paper, 12/238.
Brown, C.O. and Ding, I.S. (2011), 'Too many to fail? Evidence
of regulatory forbearance when the banking sector is weak', Review
of Financial Studies 24.4, pp. 1378-405.
Calomiris, C.W. and Herring, R.J. (2013), 'How to design a
contingent convertible debt requirement that helps solve our
too-big-to-fail problem', Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 25,
Spring, pp. 39-62.
Caprio, G., Klingebiel, D., Laeven, L. and Noguera, G. (2005),
'Banking crisis database', in Honohan, P. and Laeven, L.
(eds), Systemic Financial Crises: Containment and Resolution, New York,
NY: Cambridge University Press.
Carmassi, J. and Herring, R.J. (2013), 'Living wills and
cross-border resolution of systemically important banks 'Journal of
Financial Economic Policy, 5, 4.
--(2015, forthcoming), Corporate Structures, Transparency and
Resolvability of Global Systemically Important Banks, Systemic Risk
Council, Jan.
Carrington, T. (1984), 'US won't let 11 biggest banks in
nation fail', Wall Street Journal, 20 September.
Chouinard, E. and Ens, E. (2013), 'Assessing the systemic
importance of financial institutions', Bank of Canada, Financial
System Review, December.
Clearing House Association (2011), 'Understanding the
economics of large banks', November,
http://www.theclearinghouse.org/ index.html?f=073071.
Davis, E.P. (1995), Debt, Financial Fragility and Systemic Risk,
Oxford University Press.
European Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee (2014),
'Complexity and credibility in the Single Resolution
Mechanism', Statement No 39, London, 14 November, www.esfrc.eu.
Goodhart, C. (2014), 'The parlous state of macroeconomics and
the optimal financial structure', International Review of Financial
Analysis, 36, pp. 78-83.
Haldane, A.G. (2012), 'The dog and the frisbee', Bank of
England, August.
Hoenig, T.M. (2012), 'Back to basics: a better alternative to
Basel capital rules', speech to the American Banker Regulatory
Symposium, Washington, D.C., 14 September, http://www.fdic.
gov/news/news/speeches/chairman/spsep_1412_2.html.
Honohan, P. and Klingebiel, D. (2003), 'The fiscal cost
implications of an accommodating approach to banking crises',
Journal of Banking & Finance, 27, (8), August, pp. 1539-60.
Hughes, J.P. and Mester, L.J. (2011), 'Who said large banks
don't experience scale economies? Evidence from a
risk-return-driven cost function', Working Papers No. 11 -27,
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.
International Monetary Fund (2014), Global Financial Stability
Report, April.
Johnson, S. and Kwak, J. (2010), 13 Bankers: The Wall Street
Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown, New York: Pantheon.
Kashyap, A.K., Stein, J.C. and Hanson, S. (2010), 'An analysis
of the impact of 'substantially heightened' capital
requirements on large financial institutions'. Harvard University
mimeo, May.
Kaufman, G. (2002), 'Too big to fail in banking: what
remains?', The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 42, pp.
423-36.
Kroszner, R.S. and Rajan, R.G. (1994), 'Is the Glass-Steagall
Act justified? A study of the US experience with universal banking
before 1933', American Economic Review, 84, (4), pp. 810-32.
Laeven, L., Ratnovski, L. and Tong, H. (2014), 'Bank size and
systemic risk', IMF Staff Discussion Note, SDN/14/04.
Miles, D., Yang, J. and Marcheggiano, G. (2013), 'Optimal bank
capital', The Economic Journal, 3, pp. 1-37.
Mullineux, A. (2012), 'The governance of 'too big to
fail' banks' in Barth, J.R., Lin, C. and Wihlborg, C. (eds),
International Research Handbook on Banking and Governance, Edward Elgar
Publishing.
Prabha, A. and Wihlborg, C. (2012), 'Cross-border banking in
subsidiaries and branches; organization, supervision and
resolution', in Caprio, G. (ed.), Encyclopedia of Financial
Globalization, Elsevier.
Saunders, A. and Walter, I. (2010), 'Financial architecture,
systemic risk, and universal banking', Financial Markets and
Portfolio Management, 24, I, edited by Markus Schmid, Springer, March.
Schmid, M.M. and Walter, I. (2009), 'Do financial
conglomerates create or destroy economic value?', Journal of
Financial Intermediation, 18, (2), pp. 193-216.
Shull, B. (2010), 'Too big to fail in financial crisis:
motives, countermeasures, and prospects', the Levy Economics
Institute of Brad College Working Paper, No. 601.
Tarullo, D.K. (2009), 'Confronting too big to fail',
speech at the Exchequer Club, Washington, D.C., 21 October.
Wheelock, D.C. and Wilson, P.W. (2012), 'Do large banks have
lower costs? New estimates of returns to scale for US banks',
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44(1), pp. 171-99.
Wihlborg, C. (2012), Developing Distress Resolution Procedures for
Financial Institutions', SUERF (Societe Universaire Europeenne de
Recherches Financiers) Study, 2012/4, August.
James R. Barth * and Clas Wihlborg **
* Lowder Eminent Scholar in Finance at Auburn University, and
Senior Fellow at Milken Institute. E-mail: barthjr@auburn.edu. **
Fletcher Jones Chair of International Business at Chapman University.
E-mail: wihlborg@chapman.edu. This is a short version of a much longer
paper with tables and figures, which is available on request. The
authors are grateful for helpful comments from two anonymous referees
and the excellent assistance of Yanfei Sun.