Commentary: the economic consequences of leaving the EU.
Armstrong, Angus ; Portes, Jonathan
"The crisis takes a much longer time coming than you think,
and then it happens much faster than you would have thought."
Rudi Dornbusch
The phony war is over. We enter a crucial final six weeks before
the UK's referendum on EU membership. A decision by the British
people to vote to leave will alter the course of both British and
European history. While this is fundamentally a political choice,
economic consequences are rightly central to the debate. In this issue
of the Review we bring together some of our colleagues from the
ESRC's 'UK in a Changing Europe' programme, from a
variety of disciplines, to examine the implications of this decision. We
also summarise the National Institute's estimates of the
macroeconomic consequences of leaving the EU and compare them to other
model based estimates. This exercise is of particular interest since
both the well-publicised HM Treasury and OECD analyses use our global
macroeconomic model, the National Institute Global Econometric Model
(NiGEM). (1)
Referenda are relatively rare in the UK, although they have become
more common of late. The last time the UK voted on Europe was a
generation ago--or 41 years ago to be exact. But because they are so
infrequent, the outcomes are typically long-lasting. Some on the Leave
side have contemplated the idea of a further renegotiation and a second
vote, but this seems very unlikely. The Prime Minister has made it clear
that the government would have an obligation to give effect to the
electorate's wishes and, following a vote in Parliament, would give
notice to the European Council under Article 50 of the Treaty of the
European Union. (2) This starts a two-year process of negotiating the
terms of withdrawal, unless extended by unanimous agreement of all other
27 Member States. There is no provision to withdraw an intention to
leave under Article 50. (3) Meanwhile, many in the rest of the EU
already see Prime Minister Cameron's agreement with Heads of State
in February as going as far as feasible or desirable (or indeed farther)
in giving the UK a special status.
Influence and immigration
One of the most often aired concerns in the referendum debate is
that the UK has little influence over EU institutions and regulations.
Our first research article by Menon and Salter examines the degree to
which the UK is able to set and influence the EU's agenda. They
find that, despite headlines about the UK being 'outvoted',
that at least up until the most recent period, the UK has been
relatively successful in influencing policy, in both a negative
(preventative) and positive (proposing) sense. In many ways the UK has
steered the EU in its own preferred direction of market liberalisation
combined with national control of social policies. However, the run-up
to the referendum may have eroded our credibility and hence our ability
to advance this agenda. Paradoxically, then, the UK government's
mishandling, over the past few years, of the domestic EU debate and the
renegotiation has, if anything, strengthened the case for Leave. If we
vote to Remain, re-establishing the UK's centrality to EU debates
will be an urgent task.
Perhaps the greatest concern about our EU membership is the
inability to control migration. In the second article, Portes points out
that negative attitudes to immigration, and in particular free movement
within the EU, are by far the strongest predictor of opposition to EU
membership. The Prime Minister's initial objective of imposing
significant restrictions on free movement was resoundingly rejected in
the UK's renegotiation. This means that a vote to Remain will
unequivocally be a vote for the status quo. Some who favour leaving the
EU argue that ending free movement of labour might allow a more liberal
approach to non-EU migration, particularly of skilled workers, with
consequent economic benefits; but it also seems plausible that policy
might become significantly more restrictive overall, since even a large
reduction in EU migration would leave overall net migration well above
the government's target.
The Single Market
In the past few weeks the alternative on offer has come into
sharper focus. Previously, scenarios ranging from continued membership
of the European Economic Area (EEA) to completely independent trade
policy on the lines of New Zealand or even Hong Kong were floated. Now,
however, the official Leave campaign has narrowed that range
considerably. Their vision is of a UK outside the Single Market, but
within what they describe as the "free trade zone stretching from
Iceland to Turkey that all European nations have access to, regardless
of whether they are in or out of the euro or EU". (4) This includes
not just members of the EEA and European Free Trade Association (EFTA)
but also countries like Bosnia and Turkey.
Let us then suppose that the preferred alternative to the EU is an
arrangement that secures, broadly, continued tariff-free access for UK
exporters and importers to EU markets, subject to rules of origin, and
other regulatory and non-tariff barriers that do not apply to full
members, particularly in trade in services. In this light, what do the
remaining three research articles collected in this issue tell us about
the impact of leaving the EU?
Services account for the overwhelming majority of the UK economy,
and a large and growing proportion of our trade. Focusing on the sectors
of tourism and higher education, Barnard and Ludlow examine how the
process of liberalisation, driven by EU law and policy, has largely
worked to the benefit of the UK. Looking forward, many Member States
continue to be very cautious about further liberalisation. But leaving
the EU, in the absence of an alternative such as EEA membership, would
make matters considerably worse. Currently, the Treaties, the Commission
and the European Court of Justice mean that there are strong central
authorities which broadly share the UK agenda. We would lose our
influence within these bodies, and our ability to call on them for
recourse. By comparison Free Trade Agreements (FTA) do not cover all
services, and there is no region in the world which has such a high
level of integration of services across sovereign borders.
For good or (sometimes) ill, the financial sector plays a key role
in the UK economy, and is a major contributor to our trade performance
and public finances. Despite remaining outside the Eurozone, London
continues to be Europe's dominant centre of financial services. It
is difficult to see how leaving not just the EU but also the wider EEA
would not have important implications for this status. Armstrong argues
that some substantial UK institutions would necessarily be excluded from
key parts of the European financial infrastructure, including central
counterparty clearing houses. This in turn could have major consequences
for the decisions of private sector firms on where to locate both their
headquarters operations and large parts of their operational business.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The direct impact of EU membership on the public finances --the
'membership fee'--is often cited as a key argument for leaving
the EU. Begg points out that it is easy to present the same basic data
as either an unreasonable burden or a comparatively trivial cost to the
tax-payer which yields considerably greater benefits. He concludes that,
although it is a net contributor to an extent comparable with several
other Member States of a similar level of prosperity, the UK does not
face an unfair share of the burden of the gross costs of the EU.
Nevertheless, it is clear that the direct fiscal impact of leaving would
be a saving to the UK budget that would be significant, albeit not huge,
in both budgetary and political terms.
There are profound differences between the Single Market and a free
trade area. The former is a single set of rules designed to create a
level playing field. It removes barriers to competition as well as to
the free movement of goods, services, capital and labour. Shifting to a
free trade agreement is not, as some would argue, a relatively minor
matter. It would be uncharted territory, likely to result in significant
changes to the structure of the UK economy, particularly in respect of
the tradeable services sectors.
Macroeconomic impact
We turn now to a discussion of the macroeconomic impact of leaving
the EU. The Treasury's recent analysis estimated that if EU
membership were replaced with a free trade agreement, similar to that
currently being negotiated between the EU and Canada, this would reduce
UK GDP in 2030 by 6.2 per cent (compared to a base case of remaining in
the EU). Other credible analyses, including that by the Centre for
Economic Performance at the LSE, also find that leaving the EU would
result in a significant decline in UK GDP relative to remaining in the
EU. Table 1 summarises the key results.
The OECD's analysis is arguably the most comprehensive; for
example, it includes estimates of the impact on migration flows, which
is notably absent from the Treasury analysis (Portes, 2016); it also
includes some potential benefits from deregulation, although these are
small. However, in all cases the key mechanism leading to the decline in
GDP is a decline in trade openness, which is assumed to feed through
into a decline in investment and labour productivity.
The Institute's analysis (Baker et al.; Ebell and Warren, both
in this Review) is also set out in the table. Like the OECD, we look
both at the long-term impacts and the short-term adjustment process in
an integrated framework. In the short term, increased uncertainty leads
to a sharp fall in the exchange rate and an increase in risk premia and
hence firms' borrowing costs. This can be thought of as a higher
cost of financial intermediation as discussed by Armstrong in this
Review. The increase in risk premia act to tighten monetary and
financial conditions. But the exchange rate, which falls and possibly
overshoots, acts to soften the various blows.
Over the longer term, we model three scenarios, and their impact on
trade in both goods and services and foreign direct investment: a
'Norway' scenario (EEA membership), a 'Swiss'
scenario (EFTA with various EU bilateral agreements) and an 'Island
Nation' scenario where we face WTO tariff conditions. We
incorporate several additional, detailed mechanisms into the adjustment
process, including changes in tariff rates and the impact on the capital
stock.
In the short term, we expect that a vote to leave would result in a
significant economic downturn, with unemployment rising by up to 1.7 per
cent. However, as uncertainty was resolved, employment and growth would
recover. Over the long term, our results are somewhat less pessimistic
than those of the Treasury or OECD, with the long-term hit to GDP
ranging from about 1.5 to 3.7 per cent.
We do not incorporate changes in migration into this analysis:
however, forthcoming research by our colleague Katerina Lisenkova uses
an overlapping generations model with detailed treatment of migrants,
their labour market characteristics and access to welfare payments. The
model takes into account general equilibrium impacts on wages, prices
and investment. Initial results suggest that substantial reductions in
EU migration will reduce GDP per capita and worsen the overall fiscal
position; in other words, changes to migration policy would likely
further exacerbate the negative economic impacts.
Finally, we note that a group called 'Economists for
Brexit' has produced a model based forecast showing a positive
impact on GDP of withdrawing from the EU, assuming that the UK moved to
implement a policy of unilateral free trade (Economists for Brexit,
2016). However, their analysis raises a number of concerns. First, they
model the impact of reduced regulation as equivalent to a reduction of 2
per cent in national insurance contributions; this number appears to be
arbitrary. Second, they model a tariff reduction after leaving the EU as
a cut in expenditure tax; but the impacts on domestic producers of such
a cut would in fact not just be different to that of reducing tariffs,
but of the opposite sign. The resulting impact estimates therefore do
not appear credible.
To summarise, there is a degree, albeit not unanimous, of consensus
that leaving the EU would depress UK economic activity in both the short
term (via uncertainty) and the long term (via trade). However, it is
important to emphasise that all these analyses assume that leaving will
in fact lead to a significant decline in trade with the EU. This is in
turn based, explicitly or implicitly, on the historical experience of
countries (like the UK) that joined the EU (or the EEA).
Leave campaigners accept this basic underlying assumption that
trade is good for productivity and hence growth. However, they argue
that the UK would in fact be able to negotiate arrangements with the
remaining EU that would ensure that any reduction in trade was mitigated
and that at the same time the UK would succeed in negotiating new free
trade arrangements with non-EU countries. The result would be a faster
expansion of trade with the fastest-growing parts of the world economy
than would otherwise occur.
These assertions are impossible to disprove ex ante. However,
future trading arrangements with the EU would require complex and
difficult negotiations, while leaders from the US, China and India have
stated that they would prefer to deal with the UK within the EU. A fair
summary is that the overwhelming weight of economic opinion is that
leaving the EU would not have a significant negative trade impact if-
and only if- the UK was able to undertake a remarkably successful series
of complex and difficult trade policy negotiations after leaving the EU.
Real options
One of the most important result in modern finance theory over the
past five decades is that irreversibility matters. Real options pricing
theory tells us that when a decision is irreversible, we need to
consider the full range of outcomes, not just the expected value. If you
cannot change course--or reverse time--the distribution of outcomes, and
'tail risks' in particular, become extremely important. In
this instance, the UK has the option to leave the EU. Optimal decision
making therefore requires an assessment of the risks involved. As the
above discussion suggests, these appear considerable, in particular
around future UK trade arrangements.
Moreover, withdrawal from the EU could also have serious UK
constitutional consequences, particularly if a decision to withdraw did
not represent the wishes of all the constituent nations. Under the Sewel
Convention, governments should only make changes to devolved
legislatures with the consent of their respective parliaments. Further
referenda, and the potential dissolution of the UK, are possible. Since
the Northern Irish and Scottish governments do not have the funds to
repay their share of UK public debt, this could result in an increase in
public debt per capita in England and Wales of up to 14 per cent.
These political and economic risks, combined with the likely
relocation of at least some parts of the financial sector, could in turn
pose a risk to the UK's ability to fund its 'twin
deficits'; the current account deficit is currently in excess of 5
per cent of GDP. (5) The result might be an adjustment process that was
quicker and more disorderly than any of the models suggest; this would
in turn have a considerably more negative impact on the real economy.
Those in the Leave campaign emphasise that there are also risks to
staying in the EU: the status quo is not an option. There is indeed
widespread recognition that the economic governance of the EU, and in
particular the Eurozone, has proved hopelessly inadequate, and that
fundamental change is required. At best, the EU is only at the beginning
of that process. The European Banking Union, promoted by the UK as a
panacea for the "remorseless logic of monetary unions", is
arguably as ambitious as the single currency project. (6) Greater
financial, and some fiscal, integration is inevitable for Eurozone
countries, with potential consequences for the UK. While the Prime
Minister's agreement with EU Heads of State in February secured a
number of clear safeguards, the possibility that Eurozone nations caucus
and introduce rules unsuitable for non-Eurozone members cannot be
eliminated. If we remain, we do at least have the opportunity to shape
and influence those changes.
Conclusion
Economists agree that trade, migration and access to large markets
are good for economies. EU membership has led to a relatively liberal
approach to both and provides full access to the largest single market
in the world. If this could be maintained outside the EU and better
trade deals negotiated, then the economic impact might indeed be neutral
or even a slight positive. But this would require benign political and
economic developments in the UK, in the EU, and globally. Moreover, the
potential downside risks of a decision to leave, while not susceptible
to precise quantification, appear large, and need to be taken into
account in assessing the overall costs and benefits. Risks are also
attached to remaining in the EU, but appear easier to manage.
NOTES
(1) While NiGEM is produced and maintained by us, the assumptions
fed into it, and hence the results, are of course the Treasury's
own responsibility.
(2) HM Government (2016) notes that the Prime Minister has made it
clear that "if the British people vote to leave, there is only one
way to bring that about, namely to trigger Article 50 of the Treaties
and begin the process of exit, and the British people would rightly
expect that to start straight away".
(3) The Treaty suggests that the only option would be to re-apply
for membership, just as for any state aspiring to join the EU. According
to University College London's Constitution Unit, "anyone who
suggests that unsure voters can vote to 'leave' at the initial
referendum safe in the knowledge that they can later change their minds
is either playing with fire or manipulating voters disingenuously"
(Renwick, 2016).
(4) Gove (2016).
(5) While long-term interest rates remain very low by historical
standards, demand for UK government debt securities may be precarious;
the bid-cover ratio in the latest gilt auction was only 1.07 times.
(6) HM Treasury (2014).
REFERENCES
Baker, J. et al. (2016), 'The short-term economic impact of
leaving the EU', National Institute Economic Review, 236, May.
Dornbusch, R. http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/shows/
mexico/interviews/dornbusch.html.
Ebell, M. and Warren, J. (2016), The long-term economic impact of
leaving the EU', National Institute Economic Review, 236, May.
Economists for Brexit (2016), The Economy After Brexit',
http;// static I .squarespace.com/static/570a 10a460b5e93378a26ac5/
t/5722f8f6a3360ce7508c2acd / 146190977995 6/
Economists+for+Brexit+-+The+Economy+after+Brexit.pdf.
OECD (2016), The Economic Consequences of Brexit: A Taxing
Decision, Policy Paper No. 16.
Gove, M. (2016), The facts of life say leave: why Britain and
Europe will be better off after we vote leave', http://www.
voteleavetakecontrol.org.
HM Government (2016), The process for withdrawing from the European
Union, CM 9216.
HM Treasury (2014), Extracts from the Chancellor's speech on
Europe, https://www.gov.uk/government/speeches/extractsfrom-the-chancellors-speech-on-europe.
--(2016), Analysis of the long term economic impact of EU
membership and its alternatives, CM 9250.
Portes, J. (2016), The Treasury's Brexit analysis and
immigration', http://www.niesr.ac.uk/blog/treasurys-brexit-analysis-andimmigration.
Renwick, A. (2016), 'What happens if we vote for
Brexit?', The Constitutional Unit
https://constitution-unit.com/2016/01/19/
what-happens-if-we-vote-for-brexit.
Angus Armstrong and Jonathan Portes, National Institute of Economic
and Social Research and Centre for Macroeconomics. E-mail:
a.armstrong@niesr.ac.uk; j.portes@niesr.ac.uk. Funding in support of
this research was provided by the ESRC's UK in a Changing Europe
programme, of which the authors are Senior Fellows.
Table 1. Comparison of recent studies on the impact of leaving the EU
on the United Kingdom
OECD LSE/CEP
WTO/FTA FTA WTO
Near term 2020 Static
GDP (%) -3.30 -1.30 -2.60
Real wages (%) n.a. n.a. n.a.
Longer term 2030 Dynamic n.a.
GDP (%) -5.1 -7.9 n.a.
Range (%) -2.7 to -7.7 -6.3 to -9.5 n.a.
Real wages (%) n.a. n.a. n.a.
Range (%) n.a. n.a. n.a.
Implied multiplier on
trade to get
long-run
GDP effects 0.27--0.39 0.5 to 0.75 n.a.
Method NiGEM Estimated n.a.
trade
elasticities (1)
Short-term uncertainty X
Reduced trade with EU X X X
Productivity losses from
reduction in trade X x(l) X
Reduction in FDI X X
Productivity losses from
reduced FDI X X
Lower contributions to X X
EU
Change in migration X
Productivity gains from
deregulation X
Lower or zero
contributions to the X
EU budget
HM Treasury
EEA FTA WTO
Near term 2020
GDP (%) n.a. n.a. n.a.
Real wages (%) n.a. n.a. n.a.
Longer term 2030
GDP (%) -3.8 -6.2 -7.5
Range (%) -3.4 to -4.3 -4.6 to -7.8 -5.4 to -9.5
Real wages (%) n.a. n.a. n.a.
Range (%) n.a. n.a. n.a.
Implied multiplier on
trade to get
long-run
GDP effects 0.42 0.33-0.41 0.32--0.40
Method NiGEM
Channels
Short-term uncertainty
Reduced trade with EU X X X
Productivity losses from
reduction in trade X X X
Reduction in FDI X X X
Productivity losses from
reduced FDI X X X
Lower contributions to X X X
EU
Change in migration
Productivity gains from
deregulation
Lower or zero
contributions to the X X X
EU budget
NIESR
EEA FTA WTO
Near term 2020
GDP (%) -1.9 -2.1 -2.9
Real wages (%) -2.3 -2.6 -4.2
Longer term 2030
GDP (%) -1.8 -2.1 -3.2
Range (%) -1.5 to-2.1 -1.9 to-2.3 -2.7 to -3.7
Real wages (%) -2.7 -3.4 -5.5
Range (%) -2.2 to -3.2 -3.1 to-3.8 -4.6 to -6.3
Implied multiplier on
trade to get
long-run
GDP effects 0.13 0.14 0.13
Method NiGEM
Short-term uncertainty X X X
Reduced trade with EU X X X
Productivity losses from
reduction in trade
Reduction in FDI X X X
Productivity losses from
reduced FDI
Lower contributions to X X X
EU
Change in migration
Productivity gains from
deregulation
Lower or zero
contributions to the X X
EU budget
Sources: OECD calculations: LSE/CEP study: Dhingra, S., Ottaviano,
G., Sampson, T. and Van Reenen, J. (2016), The Consequences of
Brexit for UK Trade and Living Standards, Centre for Economic
Performance (CEP), London School of Economics and Political Science
(LSE); and Treasury: HM Treasury (2016), HM Treasury Analysis: the
Long-Term Economic Impact ofEU Membership and the Alternatives,
April 2016.
Note: The LZSE/CEP analysis uses econometric estimates of the
relationship between trade and GDP to estimate the impact of a given
reduction in trade on GDP. These estimates would, in principle,
capture any and all impact of trade on GDP, including productivity
gains from increases to openness.