The referendum blues: shocking the system.
Chadha, Jagjit S.
"So, there are 6 cardinal colours: Yellow, Red, Orange, Green,
Blue, and Purple. And there are 3,000 shades. And if you take these
3,000 and divide them by 6, you come up with 500. Meaning that there are
at least 500 shades of The Blues."
H20 Gate Blues, Gil Scott-Heron
When faced with a complex systems of inter-related equations,
economists are used to undertaking perturbation analysis in order to
understand key relationships, in which we shock the economic system and
trace out the effects on certain variables. We may be interested in
whether the system is stable, in plotting its return to equilibrium, or
in the dynamics of how variables respond or jump from one resting point
to some other. The decision first to hold a Referendum and then the
decision to Leave the European Union have certainly shocked our economic
and political settlement. The question is whether the Referendum shock
has simply revealed something about the system or may go further and act
to undermine its fundamentals. In the Economic Prospects section of this
Review we present the National Institute's estimates of the
consequences of the Referendum, and as indicated in our May Review, (1)
we continue to expect a slowdown in overall economic activity following
the Leave vote and a period of heightened uncertainty that will act to
bear down further on activity in the UK and, to a lesser extent, abroad.
The shock
The first collective response to the Referendum result was a
palpable emergence of the blues in many metropolitan quarters--in
contrast perhaps to the delight in many other regions. The political and
economic establishment had uniformly advised that leaving the EU was
likely to damage the economy in the long run and have short-run
consequences that may be hard to manage. And yet on a turnout of 72.2
per cent from a total electorate of 46.5 million, there were 16.1
million (48.1 per cent) votes for Remain and 17.4 million (51.9 per
cent) for Leave. (2) Despite the marginal overall victory, nine of the
twelve regions in the UK voted Leave. Clearly even if the average was
going to be badly affected, most voters felt that the average did not
apply to them or that the economic risk of leaving the EU was worth
taking. (3)
The Institute is trying to understand the economic factors behind
the voting patterns and will return to this issue in the November Review
but one reasonably clear negative association shown in figure 1 is
between the fraction of the population in 380 local areas with higher
education qualifications (of those aged 16-64) and the fraction of the
population voting Leave. We need to interpret this negative correlation
with great care--as it is a simple bivariate relationship--so in the
same way that a Vote for Leave may represent many economic, political
and social motivations, our measurement of the level of higher education
qualifications may be telling us as much about income, opportunity and
access. But to the extent that levels of education attainment may tell
something about an individual's opportunities, the vote to leave
may be then telling us that many do not share that same sense of
opportunity. (4)
The morning after the Referendum, the Prime Minister, David
Cameron, announced his intention to resign once a successor had been
located, probably in the autumn. As it turned out Theresa May assumed
office on 13 July, rather more quickly than anticipated. But
nevertheless measures of economic confidence seemed to move sharply down
and measures of uncertainty sharply up. (5) In part, this may be because
of lack of clarity in the preferences of the new Cabinet and the lack of
an especially effective Opposition at present.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Exit, uncertainty and the economy
Indeed many of the off-model issues connected with the question of
a UK exit from the European Union involve what economists term Knightian
uncertainty. For example, it is hard to predict what future trading
relationships will be, or what the immigration rules will be but also we
do not know what economic and political reactions of other countries
might be or exactly how the City will be treated, (6) or whether there
may be moves by groups within other countries also to leave the EU.
Indeed the process of exit may itself impart a shock and lead to a
contagion or even a 'sudden stop'. (7) That is to say there is
a lump of issues about which it is quite hard to gain numerical
probability measures but that we know are thrown open by a possible exit
from the EU. Some of the quantitative aspects of uncertainty can be
explored with economic uncertainty indices. These indices seem to have
some explanatory power for business cycle fluctuations and so it seems
probable that heightened and sustained uncertainty will cause delay in
investment and some consumption plans. The picture that emerges is
rather clear: there are measurable economic risks to an exit from the
EU, the balance of those risks seem skewed to the downside and any
prolonged uncertainty will tend to shift the whole distribution even
further to the downside.
Accordingly, the immediate response of many survey measures of the
economy has been to go into a tailspin --measures of consumer
confidence, business investment plans and leading indicators of house
prices have fallen sharply. Indeed, as a further sign of the blues,
figure 2 suggests people are turning to holding notes and coins, with
the growth rate in those holdings considerably greater than that of
income. (8) As all serious economists warned: a vote to the leave the EU
would increase significantly the probability of a recession. For
example, when publishing economic forecasts, NIESR can represent risk
arising from uncertainty by wrapping point forecasts of output within a
set of confidence intervals. These confidence intervals are derived by
subjecting the global econometric model, NiGEM, to a series of
historical shocks drawn at random from the set of historical residuals
on the model's equations. Repeating the simulations with different
random shocks enables us to calculate the probability of different
outcomes. This approach assumes not that the future will be like the
past but that shocks in the future will be similar to those from the
past. (9)
We can then show how the most likely path of output under Remain or
Leave would have evolved but also, taking into account the shocks, the
changing structure of trade and policy responses, and thus what the
density of that forecast looks like. And we can see that on exit we may
be entering a world with more variable income flows. Figure 3 suggests
that the probability of a full year's decline in 2017 has increased
from under 5 per cent in May under a Remain vote to at least 15 per cent
following the Leave vote. (10)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
This short-run impact on demand forms part of the adjustment to a
longer-run impact on the supply side. And I reproduce a figure from the
Treasury Committee's (2016) report and note that there is a broad
consensus that the long-run economic costs of leaving the EU are likely
to be significant. (11) Unless we think there has been some
informational herding or group think, we should place a lot of weight on
the central point of these estimates --particularly the median as it is
unlikely to have been reached with an intention to signal rather than
inform. (12) Overall we shall have to monitor carefully the economic
news and judge it carefully against the expectation of an economic
slowdown.
Policy levers
Given these expected paths for output, the standard levers of
stabilisation policy are likely to be pulled. The government has already
indicated that the fiscal charter that required a budget balance by the
end of this parliament will be amended or dropped and the Bank of
England has provided forward guidance about looser monetary policy. We
can expect a clearer set of statements about policy responses once more
data has become available and we look forward to the Autumn Statement.
But given the projections in the May Review (13) and in this Review we
can expect more public debt to be issued and Bank Rate to be nudged
down, as well as possibly some more purchases of government and,
possibly, corporate bonds as well as an expansion of Funding for
Lending. (14) It is, though, quite possible to argue that the levers
have limited room for manoeuvre; despite a growing economy since 2010,
we have continued to run fiscal deficits and seven years of Bank Rate at
0.5 per cent signals anything other than normality.
So what should we do? Financial market prices provide important
clues. The exchange rate is down 9 per cent and bank share prices are
down by 8 per cent while the price of UK government debt is up, which
means that the present value of claims on future taxpayers has gone up.
The exchange rate move has reduced the risk faced by exporters, whilst
warning that our banks, qua domestic economy, look rather vulnerable,
and has also given a prompt to the UK government that there is a
significant world appetite for (relatively) safe assets. Figure 5
illustrates our estimates that around half the fall in government bond
yields can be accounted for by expectations of a looser stance for Bank
Rate and around half by a reduction in term premia. This surprising
finding, if sustained, implies that despite the economic risk of an exit
from the EU and the changes in credit status, financial markets continue
to have an appetite for holding UK debt. (15)
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
A further clue is provided by the intellectual journey taken by
policymakers since 2007-8, in that less attention has been placed on the
average but more on dealing with the tails of the distribution. This
point has been pursued by the Financial Policy Committee of the Bank of
England, which has tried to set capital and liquidity requirements in
such a manner that large shocks are less likely to affect the economy.
It is, for example, important that any shock related to exit from the
European Union is not amplified by a negative shock to the supply of
loanable funds and that depleted confidence does not simultaneously
reduce demand for funds. One reason is that in the event of such an
amplification, lower income families might tend to be more negatively
affected, particularly if low productivity and tighter credit conditions
impinge on their household budget constraints. (16)
Is public debt the answer?
When there is the kind of uncertainty we are currently
experiencing, the issuance of public debt can reduce overall risk in the
economy. Financial instruments and trade can help the sharing of risk
under uncertainty and, to the extent that intra-temporal (across the
current set of households) contracts may not be complete and
intertemporal (with future households) risk sharing may be limited, we
may need to re-think government policy on debt. Obviously, economic
policy per se might also be thought of as a way of risk sharing.
Increasing public debt in the form of fiscal policy may allow
impoverished households today to borrow from the taxes of future
generations. Lower interest rates, from monetary policy, may allow the
same set of impoverished households, possibly through government debt
contracts, to borrow more cheaply from their own future richer selves.
In this context, even movements in the exchange rate can be thought of
as risk sharing because when sterling depreciates, we invite foreigners
to buy our goods and so provide some positive payoffs to UK firms. But
we also know that the issuance of index-linked bonds can help the
private sector manage inflation risk and the issuance of long-term debt
may play a role in developing longer-term planning horizons. (17) It may
therefore now also be time for the Treasury to reconsider how it manages
risk through its issuance of type and quantity of public debt. Bonds of
longer maturities than 50 years and also bonds that pay interest rates
proportional to GDP growth may help us deal with sharp changes in our
structure of trade. (18) The question is whether the government should
now issue bonds and use the money to develop long-term investment
projects that yield a rate of return for those parts of the country that
felt the Left Behind Blues.
NOTES
(1) See Armstrong and Portes (2016) for their commentary.
(2) By comparison the turnout for the 2015 general election had
been 66.4 per cent.
(3) I explained this possible attitude to risk in a June 2016
Gresham Lecture on the Economic Risks of Brexit (Chadha 2016a).
(4) I am grateful to Jessica Baker for bringing this correlation to
my attention.
(5) Box B in the UK chapter of this Review shows NIESR's
measure of uncertainty for the UK.
(6) See Armstrong (2016) on this point.
(7) Box A in the World chapter of this Review examines the impact
on various European States from the Referendum result and there is
considerable heterogeneity.
(8) Gorton (1988) makes the case that there is a switch to currency
from deposits at times of financial uncertainty.
(9) I am grateful to Ian Hurst and Simon Kirby for running this
calculation.
(10) The probability of a year's decline in GDP is
approximately the mass of the distribution under the zero line at any
time horizon.
(11) Chadha and Sarno (2002) looked at the costs of uncertainty on
investment and found that both long and short-run uncertainty matter.
(12) See Chadha (2016b) for a discussion of the incentives that
forecasters face to distort the information in their forecasts. And also
Baker et al. (2016) and Ebell and Warren (2016) for their forecasts.
(13) NIESR (2016).
(14) See Aquilina and Suntheim (2016) for an analysis of the
limited level of liquidity in the corporate bond market.
(15) Moody's changed the credit rating outlook for the UK to
negative on 24 June, S&P and Fitch downgraded the UK's credit
rating on 27 June.
(16) See lacoviello and Pavan (2103) on this point.
(17) In this Review, Weale and van de Ven (2106) consider the
pricing of mortality risk.
(18) We shall be returning to this question in the November 2016
Review.
REFERENCES
Aquilina, M. and Suntheim, F. (2016), 'Liquidity in the UK
corporate bond market: evidence from trade data', FCA Occasional
Paper No. 14.
Armstrong, A. (2016), 'EU membership, financial services and
stability', National Institute Economic Review, 236, pp. 31-8.
Armstrong, A. and Portes, J. (2016), 'Commentary: the economic
consequences of leaving the EU', National Institute Economic
Review, 236, pp. 2-6.
Baker, J., Carreras, O., Ebell, M., Hurst, I., Kirby, S., Meaning,
J., Piggott, R. and Warren, J. (2016), 'The short-term economic
impact of leaving the EU', National Institute Economic Review, 236,
pp. 108-20.
Chadha, J.S. (2016a), 'Assessing the economic risks from
Brexit', Gresham College Lecture, 2 June 2016: http://www.gresham.
ac.uk/lectures-and-events/assessing-the-economic-risks-from-brexit.
--(2016b), 'When experts agree: how to take economic advice
over the referendum', VOX-CEPR, 16 June.
Chadha, J.S. and Sarno, L. (2002), 'Short- and long-run price
level uncertainty under different monetary policy regimes: an
international comparison', Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, 64(3), pp. 187-216.
Ebell, M. and Warren, J. (2016), 'The long-term economic
impact of leaving the EU', National Institute Economic Review, 236,
pp. 121-38.
Gorton, G. (1988), 'Banking panics and business cycles',
Oxford Economic Papers, 40 (December), pp. 751-81.
Iacoviello, M. and Pavan, M. (2013), 'Housing and debt over
the life cycle and over the business cycle', Journal of Monetary
Economics, 60, pp. 221-38
NIESR (2016), National Institute Economic Review, 236, May.
Treasury Committee (2106), The Economic and Financial Costs and
Benefits of the UK's EU Membership, First Report of Session
2016-17.
Weale, M. and van de Ven, J. (2016), 'Variable annuities and
aggregate mortality risk', National Institute Economic Review, 237,
pp. 55-61.
Jagjit S. Chadha, National Institute of Economic and Social
Research. E-mail: j.chadha@niesr.ac.uk. I am grateful for conversations
with and comments from Angus Armstrong, Jessica Baker, Oriol Carreras,
Monique Ebell, Graham Hacche, Ian Hurst, Simon Kirby, Iana Liadze, Simon
Lloyd, Jack Meaning, Rebecca Piggott, Jonathan Portes and James Warren.