Oil prices and economic activity.
Kirby, Simon ; Meaning, Jack
Introduction
Crude oil spot prices have fallen sharply since the summer of 2014.
In the November 2014 Review, we had factored in a fall in the spot price
of around US $10 per barrel to around $98 per barrel in 2015, following
a temporary fall to close to $90 per barrel in the final quarter of
2014. (1) Outturns have been significantly lower than this: oil prices
currently average below $50 per barrel. Figure 1 plots the assumed path
for oil prices published in the November 2014 Review, together with the
assumptions underpinning the forecasts presented in the World and UK
sections of this Review.
There is uncertainty about the determinants of the sharp fall in
oil prices, as well as how oil prices will evolve in the months and
years to come. There has been a significant softening of demand, from
emerging markets such as China and Brazil as well as advanced economies,
in particular the Euro Area and Japan (see the World chapter in this
Review for forecasts for these economies). At the same time, US oil
supply, which is at its highest level since the 1970s, and the surprise
increase in output from Libya last year have been identified as supply
side factors.
The causes and implications of the recent oil price shock are
discussed in Arezki and Blanchard (2014). In this note, we have two
distinct aims. First, we decompose oil price developments into their
demand and supply components via a Bayesian vector autoregression (VAR)
with sign restrictions. Our analysis suggests that the recent oil price
decline was set off by expanding supply but has been increasingly
dominated by demand side factors, a result supported by the changes in
supply and consumption estimates from the Energy Information
Administration (EIA) in recent months. This insight informs our second
aim, which is to illustrate the effects of recent oil price developments
on global economic activity, and in particular economic activity in a
number of OECD member states. In this analysis we stress the importance
of temporary versus permanent oil price shocks.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
A decomposition of oil price developments
We approach the question of whether supply or demand are driving
oil price movements through a decomposition using sign restrictions on a
standard Bayesian VAR, following Uhlig (2005). The VAR consists of two
series, the 3-month moving averages of the log differences of world oil
prices and world oil supply, with six lags. The restrictions applied are
as general as possible--that prices and quantities move in the same
direction following a demand shock and inversely following a supply
shock. Once demand and supply shocks are identified, we follow Chadha,
Corrado and Sun (2010) in creating a counterfactual historical series
with the effects of either supply or demand shocks stripped out. This
allows us to give an historical decomposition of the impact of each
shock type on the raw series, reported in figure 2. (2)
Looking at what this decomposition implies about recent history is
quite interesting. First, it confirms the result of Barsky and Killian
(2004) who identify the fall in oil prices around the Asian crisis of
1997-8 as mostly emanating from an inward shift in the demand curve.
Second, the drop in oil prices in the financial crisis of 2007-8 was
also dominated by demand shocks as global activity slowed dramatically.
Conversely, the price increases in 2010 and 2011 were driven in part by
strong demand as the world economy began to recover from the Great
Recession, reinforced by falling supply pushing up on prices. This ties
in with the complications of oil supply in the Middle East.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Regarding the most recent fall, it appears to have been initiated
by an expansion of supply, which weighs down on the price from around
the second quarter of 2014. Commentators have highlighted the surge in
supply from US shale and the recovery of Libyan supply as potential
explanations. Although this supply effect persists into the more recent
period, the negative price effect is now dominated by substantial
negative demand shocks, none more so than in the final quarter of last
year.
Our VAR analysis is supported by a comparison of the EIA's
estimates and forecasts between October 2014 and January 2015. Over this
period outturns for oil prices were substantially lower than the EIA
forecast in October and looking at how they have revised their estimates
and forecasts of supply and consumption in light of this reveals what
they implicitly consider to be the driving factors. Viewed from January
2015, the first half of 2014 is now estimated to have experienced
greater supply than was estimated back in October. Given the lag
structure of our VAR analysis, this coincides well with the identified
supply shocks weighing down on prices from the second quarter of the
year. The EIA's estimates of consumption are relatively unaffected
in the first six months of 2014, but from June have been revised
significantly lower in a number of months, again echoing the findings of
our VAR work that demand became an increasingly important part of the
changing narrative on prices.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Looking at 2015, the EIA have revised their estimates for both
supply and consumption by roughly equal amounts; the former up and the
latter down. Both these shifts act to lower expected prices as they
simultaneously act to increase the extent of excess oil supply. However,
the extent to which it is supply or demand which most influences prices
will depend on the elasticities of the price to each shock. Intuitively,
the large contribution of demand shocks in our VAR analysis coupled with
the roughly balanced revisions to supply and demand by the EIA implies
that the oil price is more sensitive to shifts in demand, an assertion
supported by the analysis of Killian (2010), but which needs further
investigation before it can be claimed to hold true definitively in the
current context.
In summary, our empirical analysis presented here suggests that
there has been a significant role for both supply and demand shocks in
moving the oil price in recent months, with tentative signs that the
contribution from demand shocks has been growing.
Illustrating the output effects of the recent oil price shock
As noted above, the recent shock to oil prices appears to be a
combination of demand and supply shocks. In this section we depart from
the concepts of demand- or supply-led oil price shocks and focus on the
important distinction between temporary and permanent shocks. Separating
the two is key, as temporary and permanent shocks have different
implications for the impact on the real economies of oil importing
nations, as well as their respective monetary policy decision-makers. We
use our global econometric model, NiGEM, to illustrate the effects on
advanced economies (and also on net oil importing nations) from both of
these types of oil price shock. If we take our November 2014 baseline as
the counterfactual, then our current baseline implies a $40-$45 fall,
$20 of which is temporary and fades out after a year, and $20-$25 of
which is more permanent (figure 1).
In these simulations we assume that financial markets, including
the monetary policy reaction function, are forward looking. Expectations
are formed consistent with the outturns from the respective scenario.
This allows changes to financial instruments that are consistent with
the shock. Exchange rates are determined by a forward-looking uncovered
interest rate parity condition where risk premia are assumed constant
unless directly 'shocked'. As such, exchange rates can
'jump' in response to changes in expectations about the future
path of interest rates. We use our default monetary policy rule whereby
interest rates adjust to deviations of the inflation rate and a nominal
magnitude from their targets to ensure price stability. (3) In
determining the monetary response, policymakers are assumed to look
forward by eight quarters. Crucially, we assume that monetary policy
authorities retain credibility through inflation expectations remaining
anchored. The wage-price system is also assumed to be forward looking,
where the anchored inflation expectations play an important role.
Across many advanced economies, policy rates were reduced to close
to the zero nominal lower bound as monetary policymakers fought the
deflationary environment of the Great Recession. These extraordinarily
low interest rates have been broadly maintained through to the current
period. Policy rates close to the zero lower bound constrain the ability
of the monetary policy authorities to respond when faced with a
disinflationary shock, such as the ones described here. (4) For the UK,
we have assumed that the floor for policy rates is 50 basis points. (5)
While monetary authorities do not have the ability to lower interest
rates further in the near term in these scenarios, they do have the
ability to keep interest rates at their extraordinarily low levels for
longer. Financial market expectations of future interest rate paths have
indeed adjusted to assume this type of monetary policy response over the
coming months and years.
Table 1 presents the results from both permanent and temporary $20
falls in the price of oil. Table 2 presents the results from permanent
and temporary $40 oil price scenarios. The two sets of scenarios provide
us with some useful rules-of-thumb as we try to gauge the impact of
recent oil price developments on the economic outlook.
Temporary shock
The impact of a temporary oil price shock affects oil importing
economies predominantly via a positive terms of trade effect. With a
two-year horizon for monetary policymakers it takes a couple of quarters
for them to realise the shock is temporary and start to reverse any
initial interest rate cuts. The developments are factored into financial
market decision making and, as a consequence, real long-term rates
barely change, leaving investment decisions by firms little different
from the baseline. The short-term boost to GDP growth stems from the
terms of trade effect on consumer spending. The sharp reduction in
import prices passes through to consumer prices, to an extent which is
country-specific and dependent on oil shares of imports as well as the
composition of the consumption basket.
US consumption is more oil intensive than in the other countries
listed here. In the face of a $20 temporary oil price decline, US GDP
growth increases by 0.2 percentage point in the first year of the shock,
followed by 0.1 percentage point in the second year. At its peak, the
level of US GDP would be 0.3 per cent higher than the baseline (see
table 1). A $40 shock would push the level of GDP 0.5 per cent above the
baseline by year 2 of the shock. In both instances, the sharp rebound in
oil prices is enough to reduce demand for a few years, as the rate of
inflation shifts to positive and the central bank raises rates in
advance of this, following its prescribed reaction function. In the $20
scenario these negative effects are modest, as are the interest rate
movements. In the UK and Euro Area the temporary effects are very
modest, barely increasing and then lowering GDP growth. In the $40
temporary scenario UK GDP growth expands by 0.2 percentage point, and
then falls back as monetary policymakers adjust to offset the period of
above-target inflation as the oil price snaps back by $40 towards the
start of 2017. In both scenarios, the level of GDP in all these
economies remains unchanged in the long run.
In most oil importing economies the exchange rates would be
expected to jump down, given the expectation of a reduction in interest
rates for a period, offsetting some disinflationary pressures (see Kirby
and Meaning, 2014 for an illustration of exchange rate pass-through
effects from NiGEM scenarios). But, as noted previously, at the current
juncture oil consuming economies have little scope to cut interest rates
further. Consequently, 'jumps' in exchange rates are
constrained, inhibiting one of the natural mechanisms which would offset
some of the impact of oil price changes on the price level. Indeed,
given that oil exporting economies have more monetary space to operate
in, it is not clear cut that oil importing countries would necessarily
experience a depreciation in their effective exchange rates. This is the
situation for the Euro Area, where the effective exchange rate
increases, exacerbating the disinflationary impact of oil price
developments.
Permanent shock
The initial effects in the permanent scenarios are similar. The
positive effect on GDP is enhanced by the shift in relative prices of a
key factor input (oil). The broad downward trend in the oil intensity of
output for advanced economies suggests that the boost to the potential
output as a consequence of permanent oil price falls will be of lesser
magnitude than in preceding decades. Nevertheless, we would expect it to
have a permanent positive effect on GDP. In the scenarios presented it
takes a few years for inflation rates to return to baseline. Over this
period, real wages are allowed to rise above baseline, given that the
cost of the average consumption basket will have fallen relative to
nominal incomes. Given the zero lower bound, nominal interest rates are
not able to drop as much as the reaction function would suggest. (6)
However, they do remain at their current low levels for a sustained
period of time. This is exactly how financial markets' expectations
have adjusted in recent months. The lowering of the profile for interest
rates results in a jump down in the exchange rate, of a greater
magnitude than in the temporary scenarios. This induces a rise in
exports, relative to baseline. However, this effect is somewhat dampened
in economies that export more to oil exporting economies. It should be
noted that the positive effect on GDP growth lasts, on average, only
three years, before the new equilibrium level of output is reached.
The effects on the US and Japanese economies are far greater than
in the Euro Area or UK, due mainly, but not exclusively, to differences
in the relative oil intensity of output. For example, our estimates
suggest that US output is more than twice as oil intensive as UK output.
A permanent $20 decline in oil prices would be expected to increase US
GDP by almost 1 1/2 per cent in the medium to longer term. In the first
year GDP growth would be expected to be as much as 0.6 percentage point
higher in the first year. In the $40 scenario GDP growth would be
expected to be around 1.2 percentage points higher. In reality, we have
revised up our forecast for US GDP growth in 2015 by 0.3 percentage
point, the offset being mainly the sharp appreciation of the dollar
against a trade-weighted basket of currencies. These results suggest a
medium to long-run effect on UK GDP of around Vi per cent in a $20 shock
and just over 1 per cent in a $40 shock. The impacts on the Euro Area
are significantly larger, at around 0.8 and 1.6 per cent respectively.
As we note below, there are important factors likely to inhibit
significantly the effectiveness of the stimulus from oil prices in the
Euro Area.
A decline in oil prices is typically viewed as a positive stimulus
to global economic growth because it redistributes incomes from oil
producers to oil consumers, the latter typically economies with a
greater propensity to spend than the former. But we are not in
'normal times' at present.
The results presented here probably represent upper bounds to the
effects of the current oil price shock. Much of the Euro Area suffers
from a deficiency of demand. While oil price developments should
stimulate demand across the Euro Area, heightened uncertainty within the
household and corporate sectors may limit the degree to which normal
transmission mechanisms function. Increases in private demand are the
mechanism by which economies adjust to a disinflationary oil price
shock. If this mechanism is significantly impaired, we should not expect
to see the positive effects on GDP reported in tables 1 and 2.
The disinflationary pressures from this oil price shock also have
the potential to exacerbate deflationary conditions in oil consuming
economies, in particular within the Euro Area. Of acute concern is
whether the pass-through from the decline in oil prices will cause the
anchor on inflation expectations to drift, exacerbating the current
travails of the Euro Area.
REFERENCES
Arezki, R. and Blanchard, O. (2014), 'Seven questions about
the recent oil price slump', IMF direct--The IMF Blog, 22 December,
available at: http://blog-imfdirect.imf.org/2014/12/22/seven-questions-about-the-recent-oil-price-slump/ [verified 1st February 2015].
Barrell, R. and Kirby, S. (2008), 'Oil prices and
growth', National Institute Economic Review, 204, pp. 39-42.
Barrell, R. and Pomerantz, O. (2004), 'Oil prices and the
world economy', Focus on European Economic Integration,
Oesterreichische Nationalbank, 1/2004.
--(2008), 'Oil prices and world inflation', National
Institute Economic Review, 203, pp. 31-4.
Barsky, R. and Kilian, L. (2004), 'Oil and the macroeconomy
since the 1970s', NBER Working Paper No. 10855.
Chadha, J., Corrado, L. and Sun, Q. (2010), 'Money, prices and
liquidity effects: separating demand from supply', Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control, 34, 9, pp. 1732-47.
Hamilton, J.D. (2011), 'Historical oil shocks', NBER
Working Paper No. 16790.
Kirby, S. and Meaning, J. (2014), 'Exchange rate pass-through:
a view from a global structural model', National Institute Economic
Review, 230, pp. F59-64.
Uhlig, H. (2005), 'What are the effects of monetary policy on
output? Results from an agnostic identification procedure', Journal
of Monetary Economics, 52, 2, March, pp. 381-419.
NOTES
(1) The average of Brent and Dubai spot prices.
(2) One caveat of this technique is that it requires the assumption
that supply and demand shocks are uncorrelated.
(3) NiGEM has considerable flexibility in the choice of the
monetary policy rule to be used for each economy in any shock. See
Barrell and Pomerantz (2004, 2008) for a discussion of the effect of
different reaction functions during an oil price shock.
(4) The Swiss and Danish central banks are currently testing the
validity of this assumption.
(5) See the MPC minutes from the June 2012 meeting for a discussion
of issues related to reducing Bank Rate below 0.5 per cent, available at
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/
minutes/Documents/mpc/pdf/2012/mpc1206.pdf.
(6) We assume the lower bound acts as an effective constraint on
policy and further asset purchases either are not carried out or are
ineffectual at significantly loosening policy.
Simon Kirby * and Jack Meaning **
* NIESR and Centre for Macroeconomics. E-mail: s.kirby@niesr.ac.uk.
** NIESR. E-mail: j.meaning@niesr.ac.uk. Thanks to Graham Hacche, lana
Liadze, James Warren, Oriol Carreras and Rebecca Piggott for helpful
comments and discussions.
Table 1. Effects of a $20 decline in oil prices on the level of GDP
(per cent difference from baseline)
Euro Area France Germany Japan
Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp.
2015 0.3 0.1 0.4 0.2 0.4 0.2 0.6 0.3
2016 0.7 0.2 0.7 0.3 0.7 0.3 0.9 0.5
2017 0.8 0.0 0.8 0.0 0.7 0.0 1.0 0.2
2018 0.8 -0.1 0.7 -0.2 0.6 -0.2 1.0 0.0
2019 0.8 -0.1 0.7 -0.2 0.6 -0.2 1.0 0.0
UK USA OECD
Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp.
2015 0.2 0.1 0.6 0.2 0.4 0.1
2016 0.4 0.1 1.3 0.3 0.9 0.2
2017 0.5 -0.2 1.4 0.1 1.0 0.1
2018 0.5 -0.2 1.4 -0.1 1.1 -0.1
2019 0.5 -0.1 1.4 -0.2 1.1 -0.1
Source: NiGEM simulations.
Note: Temporary shock lasts for eight quarters; table shows the
cumulative impacts on the level of the volume of GDP.
Table 2. Effects of a $40 decline in oil prices on the level of GDP
(per cent difference from baseline)
Euro Area France Germany Japan
Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp.
2015 0.7 0.3 0.8 0.4 0.8 0.4 1.1 0.5
2016 1.4 0.4 1.5 0.5 1.4 0.6 1.9 1.1
2017 1.7 0.0 1.6 -0.1 1.5 0.0 2.0 0.4
2018 1.7 -0.3 1.5 -0.5 1.4 -0.4 2.0 -0.2
2019 1.6 -0.2 1.4 -0.4 1.3 -0.4 2.1 -0.1
UK USA OECD
Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp. Perm. Temp.
2015 0.4 0.2 1.2 0.2 0.9 0.2
2016 0.8 0.1 2.6 0.5 1.9 0.4
2017 1.1 -0.4 3.0 0.1 2.2 0.0
2018 1.1 -0.5 3.0 -0.4 2.3 -0.3
2019 1.1 -0.3 2.9 -0.5 2.3 -0.3
Source: NiGEM simulations.
Note: Temporary shock lasts for eight quarters; table shows the
cumulative impacts on the level of the volume of GDP.