The economic record of the coalition government: introduction.
Portes, Jonathan
As we approach the 2015 UK General Election, this Review assesses
the economic record of the 2010-15 Coalition government. While we cannot
hope to be comprehensive, the papers included here cover not just an
overview of developments in macroeconomic policy, growth and
productivity, but also two of the key areas for medium-term policy
reform: education and the welfare system.
First, some context. The 1970s and 1980s were an era of both
political polarisation and sharp controversy over economic policy, both
macroeconomic and microeconomic. But they were followed, in the UK as
elsewhere in most developed economies, by a long period of stability in
the general approach to economic management. From 1992 to 2007 there was
a remarkable degree of consensus across the political spectrum on
economic issues.
As in most advanced economies, monetary policy was taken out of
direct political control and assigned to an independent central bank,
which was responsible for achieving an inflation target. Fiscal policy,
while still macroeconomically significant and occasionally politically
controversial at the margin, was not seen as a useful tool for
short-term demand management, and was therefore seen as primarily
relevant to long-term sustainability.
Microeconomic, or supply-side, policies were directed at improving
the workings of markets, either by policy liberalisation (for example,
through reducing labour market regulation, the development of the Single
Market, or liberalising immigration policy) or by correcting market
failures (for example, congestion charging in London). The existing
boundaries between the public and private sector remained (so health and
compulsory education remained free at the point of use and provided by
the state) but various quasi-market mechanisms were introduced to, it
was hoped, spur greater efficiency within monopoly providers. In
education, greater autonomy was given to schools, and some of the burden
of financing higher education was shifted to students.
Within this framework, what dispute there was among the major
parties and most economic commentators was not about'positive'
economic issues (the basic framework or the efficacy of these policies)
but rather (and properly) about normative questions--the appropriate
level of taxation and spending on public services and the degree of
redistribution implied by the tax and benefit systems.
This consensus was sustained by what appeared to be relatively good
results. Particularly in areas where these ideas were applied clearly
and consistently, with significant input from economic research and
evidence --competition policy, labour markets, welfare reform, and
immigration are prominent examples--significant progress was made and
the economic benefits are generally recognised. UK growth and
productivity performance in the 1979-2007 period was at least reasonable
in absolute terms, and better than our major competitors (Corry, Valero
and Van Reenen, 2011). Meanwhile, the considerably greater degree of
redistribution embodied in the tax and benefit policies implemented by
the 1997-2010 Labour government meant that inequality, which rose very
sharply between 1979 and the mid-1990s, at least stabilised, while child
poverty was substantially reduced (Portes, 2011).
The Great Recession and its aftermath provided a huge shock to this
consensus. While the economy had bottomed in March 2009, and recovery
appeared to have taken hold, this was after the largest fall in output
in living memory. Interest rates were stuck at zero; already,
quantitative easing had blurred the separation between monetary and
fiscal policy, and between the politicians at the Treasury and the
'technocrats' at the Bank of England. And, most immediately,
the incoming Coalition government faced a fiscal deficit unprecedented
in peacetime. Meanwhile, the glaring and manifest failure of the
'light-touch' approach to financial sector regulation at the
very least caused many economists (including this author) and
politicians to question the 'market failure' approach to
microeconomic policymaking (Turner, 2010).
So, arguably, the new government faced both a challenge and an
opportunity--broad continuity in policy was no longer the obvious
default option. Certainly, in sharp contrast to the debate pre-2008
(when the Conservatives pledged to match Labour's spending plans,
and the then Shadow Chancellor, George Osborne, criticised excessive
financial regulation), the initial rhetoric was of a radical break. The
Prime Minister's first major economic speech, in May 2010, claimed
the country faced an existential choice:
"Today, Britain is at a turning point. The decisions we make
now will live with us for decades to come. For many years we have been
heading in the wrong direction. Our economy has become more and more
unbalanced, with our fortunes hitched to a few industries in one corner
of the country, while we let other sectors like manufacturing slide.
It has become over-reliant on welfare, with mass worklessness
accepted as a fact of life and around five million people now on
out-of-work benefits. It has become increasingly hostile to enterprise,
with business investment in the past decade growing at around one per
cent each year--only a quarter of what it was the decade before. It has
become far too dependent on the public sector, with over half of all
jobs created in the last ten years associated in some way with public
spending.
And, of course, as a country we have become indebted on an
unprecedented scale. Our huge deficit and rapidly growing public debt
are the clearest manifestations of our economic mistakes--the glaring
warning sign overhead telling us we have taken the wrong route. We have
been sleepwalking our way to an economy that is unsustainable, unstable,
unfair and, frankly, uninspiring.
Now that this country is waking up to it, the people of
Britain--the people of the world--want to know: can we turn this around?
Can we rebalance economic power across our regions, across different
industries, so that more people have a stake in our success? Can we end
the inevitability of millions on long-term welfare and bring hope to
those unemployed? Can we inject new life into the private sector, so
that enterprise can drive not just our recovery but the re-building
beyond it? Can we go from an economy built on debt and borrowing to one
built on saving and investment? Can we re-open Britain for
business?" (1)
So, nearly five years on, what does the balance sheet look like?
The most prominent and controversial economic policy debate has focused
on the Coalition's approach to fiscal policy, and the first article
in this issue, by Simon Wren-Lewis, examines the macroeconomic record.
He draws a clear distinction between structural and institutional
change--the establishment of the Office of Budget Responsibility (OBR)
and its remit to judge whether government policy is consistent with its
stated fiscal mandate--and the conduct of macroeconomic, especially
fiscal, policy. The former has clearly been a success, and he suggests
possible further extensions of the OBR's role; the latter largely a
failure, in economic if not political terms, albeit mitigated by a
partial change of course in 2012.
He argues that accelerated fiscal consolidation in 2010 was, at
best, an unnecessary risk. It was a risk because, even though recovery
appeared to be underway, interest rates remained at the zero lower
bound, while both domestically and internationally there were obvious
downside risks--several of which duly materialised. It was unnecessary
because, as subsequent theoretical work and empirical evidence have
established beyond doubt, the UK (unlike the eurozone) never faced any
solvency issues relating to the funding of the deficit (De Grauwe,
2011). While the record is flattered by the fact that eurozone
policymakers have made very similar, but larger, more persistent, and
hence more damaging mistakes, the damage was nevertheless significant.
He concludes:
"The delay in the UK recovery over the first part of the
coalition government's term is at least in part a result of the
government's fiscal decisions. I have argued that these decisions
were a mistake not just in hindsight but when they were taken. It will
be many years before we can settle on a figure for the total cost of
that mistake, but measured against the scale of how much governments can
influence the welfare of its citizens in peace time, it is likely to be
a large cost."
Nick Crafts' complementary paper also attempts to understand
and explain the UK's poor growth performance, but primarily from a
supply-side perspective. He concludes that, for better or worse, and in
contrast to the rhetoric above (set out, in much greater length in the
Coalition's Plan for Growth), policy has not deviated significantly
from the pre-crisis path. Sensible policies have largely been continued
and in some places extended (for example, competition and innovation
policies, and education). In some areas there have been much-needed
improvements (land-use)--although still not matching either the rhetoric
or the scale of the problem. On the downside, infrastructure policy
(both in terms of institutional structures, and of actual outcomes)
remains disappointing, while immigration policy has become more
restrictive. He describes the attempt to re-invent 'industrial
strategy' as a "quite modest repositioning of industrial
policy which is most unlikely to re-balance the economy in the direction
of a larger share of GDP originating in manufacturing". Overall, he
concludes, "changes in policy under the Coalition government are
unlikely to have made a big difference to growth potential. On the one
hand, this means opportunities for radical reform have been ignored; on
the other hand, there has been no repeat of the 1930s'
debacle."
If, as Crafts argues, there has been no major structural break in
either supply-side policy or growth potential, what explains the
unprecedented weakness in productivity since the onset of the crisis?
Vicky Pryce examines the potential explanations for the UK's
'productivity puzzle' and concludes that while it remains just
that--a puzzle--most of the explanations point to the demand side,
broadly defined.
In particular, she points to an increase in risk aversion, both by
businesses reluctant to invest and workers reluctant to seek higher pay
or take the risk of moving jobs. This in turn is the result both of the
international environment (in particular the problems of the eurozone)
and of domestic policy. While Pryce is slightly more negative than
Crafts about the government's record, they broadly agree on the
appropriate direction for policy on the supply side, in particular on
the importance of a stable framework which would allow an increase in
growth-enhancing capital investment, and hence in productivity and real
wages; she also identifies the importance of innovation and government
support for research and development.
The other two papers focus on two key areas of public service
reform: education and welfare. Rebecca Allen notes that while education
reform was very much seen as conceived and driven by one single
individual--Michael Gove--there were nevertheless two important, and
still unresolved, contradictions at its (and, implicitly, his) heart.
The first was that between a desire to pursue a "well-evidenced and
moderate approach to reforming the education system" (in large part
representing, as Gove has acknowledged, an intensification rather than a
reversal of the previous government's approach) and an attitude to
those who actually deliver education (teachers and the broader education
system) she describes as "publicly humiliating". The second
was between a market-oriented approach to educational improvement
(competition, choice, exit and entry) and the centralising tendencies
exemplified in a desire to impose a 'traditional' curriculum.
She concludes that while the broad direction of structural reform is
likely to continue, some elements of planning--in particular, in respect
of school places and the teacher workforce--will have to be reintroduced
or reinvented.
Finally, Declan Gaffney examines another set of reforms that were
also largely driven by one Secretary of State. Although Iain Duncan
Smith's programme is often perceived as a seamless whole, Gaffney
distinguishes between several strands or objectives: continuity (in
respect of lone parent and disability benefits, where the key changes
were either planned by the previous government or obvious developments
of the existing policy direction); retrenchment, largely driven by
Treasury requirements for expenditure reductions; and reform, in
particular Universal Credit.
The 'continuity' strand has yielded two very contrasting
outcomes. The extension of worksearch obligations to single parents with
youngest children aged five has resulted in increased employment and
lower numbers on benefits, and is hence likely to have saved money; it
has also been largely uncontroversial. By contrast the reassessment of
incapacity benefit claimants has been an unmitigated disaster, both for
claimants and taxpayers (Portes, 2014a). Meanwhile, while aggregate
spending has not fallen, due both to exogenous factors and policy
errors, there have been significant reductions in some areas--further
cuts will be harder. Finally, Universal Credit faced and failed to meet
a formidable technical challenge, but there are prior questions. Most of
its objectives could have been met with much less ambitious
modifications to the existing system. In retrospect, the debacle was not
only predictable but unnecessary.
More broadly, it is also worth noting that there is no evidence
suggesting that the surprising strength of employment growth has to any
significant extent been driven by recent changes in welfare policy, as
opposed to the more long-run changes in the structure and operation of
the UK labour market over the past three decades. The reduction in JSA
claims has been driven by a fall in inflows rather than by more people
moving from benefits to work, so is difficult to relate to the
functioning of the welfare system. Indeed, in some respects government
policy appears to have resulted in a reduction in labour supply: the
mismanagement of incapacity benefits has actually led to a reversal in
the long-standing trend for the number on these benefits to fall. This
failure, as well as the well-publicised problems with the implementation
of Universal Credit, will pose significant challenges to the next
government, both in fiscal and human terms (Portes, 2014b).
Inevitably, as I noted above, this is only a partial account of the
government's economic record. In particular, we have not attempted
to address in this issue the regulation of the financial sector
(arguably the biggest economic failure of the previous administration);
nor have we covered the most politically salient and expensive public
service, health. Nor have we addressed what will be perhaps the single
most important economic issue of the next Parliament--the UK's
relationship with the European Union. So I will not attempt any
definitive summing up. It is clear, however, that the Prime Minister was
wrong: 2010 was not a turning point, but merely another twist in a long
and winding road.
REFERENCES
Corry, D., Valero, A. and Van Reenen, J. (2011), 'UK economic
performance since 1997: growth, productivity and jobs', CEP Special
Papers 24, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE.
De Grauwe, P. (2011), 'The European Central Bank as a lender
of last resort', VoxEU 18/08/11.
Portes, J. (2011), 'Poverty and inequality:
introduction', National Institute Economic Review, October.
--(2014a), 'Welfare reform and the jobs miracle', NIESR
blogpost, July.
--(2014b), 'Universal credit is a tale of failure', The
Guardian, October.
Turner, A. (2010), 'After the crises: assessing the costs and
benefits of financial liberalisation', speech to the Reserve Bank
of India, February.
NOTE
(1) "Transforming the UK economy: Coalition strategy for
economic growth", Prime Minister's speech, 28 May 2010:
http:// webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/20130109092234/http://
number10.gov.uk/news/transforming-the-british-economy-coalition-strategy-for-economic-growth/
Jonathan Portes, National Institute of Economic and Social
Research. E-mail: j.portes@niesr.ac.uk.