Prospects for the UK economy.
Kirby, Simon ; Carreras, Oriol ; Meaning, Jack 等
Introduction
The publication of the final GDP estimates before the election were
disappointing. The Office for National Statistics' (ONS)
preliminary estimate of GDP suggests that economic growth slowed to 0.3
per cent per quarter in the first quarter of this year, half the rate in
the preceding three months. There are undoubtedly concerns that this
quarter is the harbinger of a pervasive slowdown. However, this is
probably just a temporary deceleration, partly related to a fall in
construction output, a sector that is particularly volatile. We expect
economic growth, consistent with a modest recovery, to resume from the
second quarter of this year.
We should not be surprised by a quarter, or two, of relatively
subdued growth: quarterly GDP growth over the period since the end of
the Great Recession has a standard deviation of 0.36; much the same as
the variation in the distribution of quarterly growth rates in the
decade preceding the crisis. Growth this year is expected to resume via
a pick-up in consumer spending growth, supporting by the positive terms
of trade effect from the sharp fall in oil prices. Nonetheless, the weak
rate of growth in the first three months of this year is enough to lower
this year's growth rate to 2.5 per cent per annum, a downward
revision of 0.4 percentage point compared with our forecast published
three months ago (figure 2). Over the forecast horizon we continue to
expect growth to persist at around this rate. Such a performance would
be consistent with the general notion of a continued economic recovery.
The sharp fall in the oil price has already permeated through to
the headline inflation figures. CPI inflation has now reached 0 per cent
per annum (figure 3). These recent outturns have been marginally weaker
than we had expected, but are within the bounds of confidence intervals
we publish in each Review. Our modal forecast is for a modest fall in
the level of prices in the latter half of this year as the lagged
effects of commodity and exchange rate developments pass through to
consumer prices. As we note in Kirby and Meaning (2014, 2015) the impact
of such developments on the rate of inflation are only temporary. As
figure 3 highlights, at the two-year horizon, we expect the rate of
inflation to have returned close to the Bank of England's target
rate of 2 per cent per annum. But as the fan chart highlights, there are
considerable uncertainties with regards to the future.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The rate of unemployment has continued to decline. We estimate that
it reached 5.6 per cent in the first quarter of this year (figure 4).
Robust employment growth has been a key feature of the UK's
economic recovery. Employment growth is expected to expand by around 1
3/4 per cent this year. From 2016 onwards we expect employment to grow
in step with the labour force, maintaining the rate of unemployment at
around 5 1/4 per cent. Again, there is considerable uncertainty over the
future path of unemployment, but we attach a reasonably low probability
to unemployment rising back above the Bank's short-lived forward
guidance metric of 7 per cent.
While the rapid fall in unemployment, due to a large expansion of
employment, is obviously welcome, the persistent poor productivity
performance is a major concern, and a fundamental risk to the outlook.
Productivity growth has persistently failed to materialise to any
meaningful degree, even as the economic recovery became entrenched.
Recent months are no exception to this.
The absence of a clear understanding of why the productivity
numbers have performed as they have adds to the uncertainty surrounding
any assumptions for their future development. In the long run,
productivity growth is the key driver of rising living standards. If a
shock has somehow permanently lowered the rate of productivity growth,
our expectations of future increases in living standards could well
smack of hubris with hindsight.
This also has serious implications for the current mix of macro
policy. For example, the OBR currently assumes productivity growth of
2.4 per cent per annum over the period 2016-19. With this view of the
macroeconomy underpinning projections, the current government would
ensure the structural budget deficit is eliminated in 2017-18. However,
if productivity performance is considerably weaker, then the fiscal
consolidation plans as currently announced are too modest. In the most
extreme variant of this scenario, both fiscal and monetary policy could
be perceived as operating in a highly procyclical fashion.
The other alternative is that there will be a sustained snap-back
in productivity growth rates as we go through a sustained period of
catch-up. In this scenario fiscal consolidation plans could be viewed as
unnecessary since the return of persistent robust growth will eliminate
the structural deficit naturally.
Our modal forecast assumes a gradual resumption of productivity
growth, but on a more muted path than both the OBR and the Bank of
England suggest. Given this baseline projection, the current
government's announced fiscal plans are expected not just to
eliminate the budget deficit, but to return the public sector to an
absolute surplus.
It is these discretionary fiscal policy assumptions that we have
built into this forces. As the OBR has highlighted, we are in the odd
position where the official fiscal plans are unlikely to be implemented
after the election.
The main parties' implied fiscal rules allow for significantly
looser fiscal policy over the coming Parliament. It is probable that
this is exactly how fiscal policy will evolve. Kirby (2015) illustrates
the macroeconomic implications of the different intended fiscal stances
of the main parties. These scenarios suggested this would lead to
slightly higher growth and employment for the next few years, combined
with slightly higher short-term interest rates and a slower rate of
reduction in the deficit and debt to GDP ratio. The effects of these
differences on the macroeconomy are probably modest. This is not to
belittle important differences in policy implications for different
sections of our society and different parts of the economy.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
If the next government does run looser fiscal policy, then it will
do so at extraordinarily low borrowing costs. We expect 10-year
government bond yields to reach only 2 per cent at the end of this year
and just 2.5 per cent in 2016. If additional spending by government were
to be focused on infrastructure, education and science and innovation,
it could also provide significant long-run returns through positive
effects on future productivity performance. As we converge on the
general election it is unfortunate that the main parties, and in
particular the Conservative and Labour parties, have instead focused on
what they will not do. Committing themselves to not raising tax rates on
some of the main sources of government revenues is not an example of
sensible policymaking.
If there was concern over the outlook due to the election, we
should expect to see a depreciation of sterling as a greater risk
premium is demanded by investors in sterling assets. However, as we
highlight in the Monetary Conditions section, sterling's
trade-weighted exchange rate sterling has noticeably appreciated in
recent months. Freely floating exchange rates can be moved as much by
external as by domestic factors. As such, any uncertainty about election
outcomes manifesting as an increased risk premium could be more than
offset by the depreciation of the euro due to the expansionary monetary
policy of the ECB and current brinksmanship over the disbursements of
the final tranches of the Greek bailout package. It is also entirely
possible that current public discourse overstates the degree to which
domestic political uncertainty has an impact on economic and financial
decisions.
Monetary conditions
The path for monetary policy implied by market interest rates is
changed little from three months ago. The first increase of 25 basis
points is still priced in for July 2016, although this had temporarily
slipped back to September 2016 over the course of the quarter. The
current expectation then is that rates will increase by an additional 25
basis points roughly once every two quarters, reaching around 1.75 per
cent in 2020. As in February, underlying our own forecast is a slightly
earlier rate rise, in the first quarter of next year, and a marginally
quicker pace of tightening, averaging 50 basis points a year. Even under
this path, Bank Rate reaches just 3 per cent per annum by the end of
2021.
February's exchange of letters between the Governor of the
Bank of England and the Chancellor of the Exchequer was notable for its
discussion of the potential for the MPC to cut Bank Rate below 1/2 per
cent. In 2009 this was considered the effective lower bound of policy in
the UK, as anything below this, it was feared, would cause financial
stability risks by damaging the profitability of a fragile financial
sector. However, now the banking sector is in ruder health, it appears
that, should it be required, the MPC sees a Bank Rate of 1/2 per cent or
less as practically achievable.
In March the Bank's Chief Economist, Andrew Haldane, said that
having this additional 50 basis points in the MPC's arsenal would
halve the risk of consumer price deflation at the two-year horizon, from
20 to 10 per cent (Haldane, 2015). The confidence intervals around our
own forecast suggest a similar probability of deflation two years ahead,
but we find this is little changed whether the lower bound is set at
zero or 1/2 per cent.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
What is more, when we use NiGEM to simulate the impact of a 50
basis point cut on the wider economy, we see little effect. Ten-year
rates fall by just 7 basis points and the annual rate of inflation
increases by just 0.08 percentage point. This is likely to be an
underestimate of the actual impact as it fails to account for the
signalling and symbolic dimension of such a move, but the magnitude of
these channels is far from certain. Should downside risks emerge of
sufficient magnitude to warrant looser monetary policy, it is likely to
require more than the fine-tuning implied by a 50 basis points cut in
Bank Rate. Any effective policy prescription would more than likely
require an interest rate cut to be accompanied by other policy measures,
such as communication to shape expectations about the path of rates and
further quantitative and credit easing. For now though, it looks as if
talk of loosening policy is nothing more than a hypothetical. The
minutes of April's MPC meeting carried a clear implication that the
"exceptionally slow" pace of rate increases expected by
markets underestimated the probability of tightening in the near term,
highlighting that data from the Euro Area was stronger than had been
anticipated in the February Inflation Report. The minutes also revealed
that for two members the decision on whether or not to raise rates was
finely balanced, widely viewed as a pre-cursor to them voting for an
increase.
There exist risks to both sides of our central expectation on
monetary policy. On the downside it is key that inflation expectations
remain anchored in the medium term. Though they have fallen slightly at
shorter horizons, they are relatively robust at two years and beyond.
However, should they begin to drift lower, we would expect the Bank of
England to react to reassure markets that the 2 per cent target remains
credible.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
The other key downside risk derives from the economic and political
uncertainty surrounding Greece. A disorderly default or a break-up of
the Euro Area will not only weigh on activity in our main trading
partner, but also cause stress in financial markets. Then the MPC would
have to act not only to ease the monetary stance, but most probably to
provide liquidity support as required by the UK financial system to
isolate it from the worst of the spillover.
On the upside, the major risk is that labour market productivity
fails to pick up as strongly as forecast by both us and the MPC. In the
April Minutes, the Committee highlighted that "it was unlikely that
activity growth could be maintained at its current pace for long,
without generating greater inflation in wages and prices, in the absence
of some material improvement in labour productivity". In that
instance, it may be that inflationary pressure accelerates quickly and
policy has also to move quickly, increasing rates to curtail an
overheating economy.
Monetary policy cycles in advanced economies continue to drive
global exchange rate movements. In the November 2014 Review we showed
how the majority of the appreciation of sterling between the beginning
of 2013 and mid-2014 could be explained by the movements in expected
policy paths in the UK, US and Euro Area, and a simple uncovered
intereest rate parity condition (UIP) condition (Kirby and Meaning,
2014). Since February the trade-weighted price of sterling has
appreciated a further 3 per cent, mostly driven by a 624 per cent
appreciation against the euro. With the expected path of policy in the
UK little changed, this is largely the result of monetary loosening in
the Euro Area, where the ECB's asset purchase programme has started
to lower longer-term interest rates and push back expectations of future
rate rises.
Whilst the effective exchange rate has risen, sterling has fallen
bilaterally relative to the dollar for the last eight months as talk of
tightening by the Federal Reserve has intensified. The first rate rise
in the US is now expected by markets a full nine months before the MPC
moves.
Over the course of the next year or two, we expect the divergence
of monetary cycles to continue in this fashion. As the Bank of England
and Federal Reserve begin to tighten policy, interest rate differentials
with Europe will widen and sterling should appreciate against the euro
by just under 11 per cent while depreciating against the dollar by
around 10 per cent in 2015. In both cases these movements are greater
than we forecast three months ago. Given its larger trade weighting, the
euro appreciation should dominate the effective exchange rate, which is
expected to rise 4.3 per cent in 2015. Beyond this, as policy cycles
come back in to line, we should see the price of sterling level at
around 1.35 euros and 1.50 dollars in the medium term.
Prices and earnings
Consumer prices failed to grow in the twelve months to March, with
zero inflation for the second consecutive month. This was marginally
weaker than our expectation published in February's Review. This
near-term weakness is largely attributable to the fall in global oil
prices, but there are signs of inflation softening more generally as
core 12-month CPI inflation fell to 1 per cent in March. Part of this
will be second round effects of the oil shock as it works its way
through supply chains and their rigidities, but other factors, such as
the continued appreciation of sterling, will also be weighing on price
growth.
Oil prices have risen by around $10 since our February forecast,
slightly more than we had assumed. The Eneregy Information
Administration (EIA) projections which underpin our forecast have also
been revised up this year and are now expected to reach $70 a barrel by
the end of 2015. This should moderate some of the disinflationary impact
we had expected in the very near term. For 2016 and beyond though, the
projected growth rates are little changed, so the impact on domestic
inflation over the more medium term is more or less consistent with our
view three months ago. The depreciation of sterling against the dollar
and our updated view of the bilateral exchange rate over the next few
years act to accentuate the upward revision of oil prices when viewed in
sterling terms.
The exchange rate has a wider role to play for UK domestic prices.
As Kirby and Meaning (2014) noted in our November Review, the
significant appreciation of sterling between the beginning of 2013 and
mid-2014 was expected to weigh down on the annual inflation rate by
about Vi per cent last year and this, before waning into 2016. However,
since then, sterling's trade-weighted price has risen a further 3
per cent and we have revised up the expected appreciation in our
forecast for 2015 by 3 percentage points. Results from our global
econometric model would suggest that this would lower the inflation rate
by an additional 0.2 percentage points through this year and next,
prolonging the headwind caused by the exchange rate pass-through. Of
course, the exchange rate, inflation and monetary policy are
inextricably tied and if inflation were to surprise on the downside it
is likely that expectations of a policy rate increase would be pushed
back, causing a depreciation of sterling relative to our central
forecast, and thus less downward pressure on prices.
Some of the disinflationary impact of the exchange rate movements
can already be seen in import prices. In the year to March, the
ONS' import price index fell 5.8 per cent. Almost all of this is
attributable to the movement in the UK effective exchange rate, which
appreciated 5.5 per cent over the same period, with the remaining fall
coming from inflation differentials. (1) Given that until recently
economic cycles between the UK and her main trading partners were
relatively synchronised, the link between exchange rate movements and
import prices is unsurprising. A simple correlation test on the two
series yields a coefficient of -0.85. In our forecast import prices
continue to contract strongly this year by more than domestic prices,
and will rise by less in 2016, so will weigh down on the CPI index until
2017 when the exchange rate appreciation has levelled out and inflation
rates between the UK and Europe are once again back in sync.
Recent data may be beginning to provide early signs of second-round
price effects from January's oil price collapse. As the oil price
has rebounded, headline measures of producer input and output prices
have seen their annual decline stabilise, falling 13 and 1.7 per cent
respectively in the twelve months to March, compared with 13.5 and 1.7
per cent in February. However, core measures, excluding oil effects,
have experienced a pronounced weakness in the first quarter of this
year. This is to be expected as the lower costs of energy and oil inputs
are passed along the supply chain to products more generally, and also
as the passing of time allows for expiring contracts to be adjusted to
take account of the lower oil price.
The RPI measure of inflation echoed movements in CPI, falling to
0.9 per cent in March from 2 per cent back in November. The wedge
between the two indices has been historically low in recent years, due
largely to lower mortgage interest payments which feature in RPI but not
CPI. In our forecast, this wedge widens over the next four or five years
as tightening monetary policy leads to higher interest payments for
mortgages. In the medium term this stabilises back to its longer-run
average of around 1/2 percentage point.
Real earnings have picked up in recent months, expanding by 2.2 per
cent per annum in February compared to the same month in 2014. This is
predominantly a result of the weak inflation outturns rather than a
significant shift in nominal earnings (figure 8). We expect real
earnings growth to continue, averaging 1.7 per cent in 2015 and 1.3 in
2016. However, underpinning this growth is a change in emphasis from low
inflation to quickening nominal wage growth brought about by improved
productivity performance. Should this productivity performance fail to
materialise, then this represents a substantial downside risk to our
central forecast, but it is likely that nominal wages would begin to
rise regardless. Without increases in productive capacity, the amount of
slack in the labour market will be soon absorbed and labour shortages
will begin to put pressure on wages. This is obviously a less appealing
cause of wage growth.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Over 2013, the earnings growth that occurred was driven in large
part by increases in hours. In recent months this has diminished and
actual hours worked have appeared to stabilise around their pre-crisis
level. We expect them to fall moderately over the coming years as higher
hourly earnings mean that workers can maintain their standard of living
whilst working less. This should increase the space for non-inflationary
employment growth within the economy.
Components of demand
The preliminary estimate of GDP made by the ONS suggests the
economy expanded by 0.3 per cent in the first quarter of this year, half
of the rate of growth experienced in the preceding three-month period
(see figure 9). This is the weakest rate of growth since the end of
2012, but as figure 9 shows, we assume this is simply a blip. As figure
9 shows, the return of a sustained period of above trend growth has been
driven by domestic demand, and we expect this to persist this year and
next, the first quarter of this year notwithstanding.
Realising the current government's ambition for more balanced
economic growth, i.e. a narrowing of the current account deficit through
the shrinking of the trade deficit and a positive contribution from net
trade have proved somewhat elusive. The UK's trade deficit is
broadly unchanged at around 2 per cent of GDP, while net trade has
subtracted a cumulative 1 percentage point from economic growth between
2010 and 2014.
In 2015 and 2016 (figure 9) we expect this pattern of net
trade's negative contribution to offset some of the continuing
robust contribution of consumption to GDP growth. However, we do expect
the UK economy to transition to a phase of more balanced growth further
into the future. Such gains in net trade growth come not from miraculous
gains in competitiveness, but rather through the sustained increase in
demand within the Euro Area. Recovery in the Euro Area is a key
determinant of the UK's economic recovery beyond 2016 and also
poses the most acute known downside external risk to the UK economy.
In the final quarter of 2014, net trade contributed 0.8 percentage
point to GDP growth, the first positive contribution since the second
quarter of 2013. The improvement in net trade resulted from a sharp
increase in exports of 5.6 per cent on a yearly basis. Driven by growth
in the manufacturing sector, specifically consumer goods and
semi-manufactured goods which grew by 9.2 and 7 per cent respectively in
the three months to December when compared to the previous quarter.
Recent data suggest that this is temporary, as quarterly data for goods
exports up to February had slowed when compared to the three months to
January, which include the final two months of 2014 which were
exceptionally strong. We therefore expect net trade to return to deficit
in the first quarter of 2015.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
One possible concern for the external sector is from the recent
appreciation of Sterling of 12 per cent since the start of 2013. Figure
10 shows that throughout the financial crisis the depreciation of the
effective exchange rate was not matched with a one-to-one change in the
price competitiveness of UK exporting firms. Furthermore, the net rate
of return for the non-financial corporate sector remained relatively
stable throughout the financial crisis. Taken together this may suggest
that firms maintained or even increased margins, as a result we expect
that firms will adjust margins and maintain price competitiveness
throughout our forecast period. Conversely, the terms of trade
improvement will lead to an increase in imports as consumers and
businesses switch from domestic products and services to relatively
cheaper foreign ones.
Exports had regained their pre-crisis levels by the final quarter
of 2010, however as figure 10 shows this has been driven by exports
outside the Euro Area, while exports to Europe remain below the
pre-crisis levels. As mentioned in the February 2014 Review, Europe
still constitutes the most important trading partner for the UK,
accounting for over half of all goods and services exports. As such our
forecast for exports and net trade in general remain dependant on a
recovery in Europe. If the Euro Area recovers in line with our forecast,
then net trade will begin to contribute positively to GDP growth from
the middle of 2016, and throughout our forecast period.
Our forecast for the volume of government consumption is based on
the projections of the OBR published in its March 2015 Economic and
Fiscal Outlook. Data outturns suggest the volume of government
consumption continued to expand throughout 2014, increasing by 1.7 per
cent from the level in 2013. A key difference between the OBR's
December and March forecasts is the assumption governing the growth of
Total Managed Expenditure (TME), which is now forecast to grow at the
same rate as nominal GDP rather than at the rate of the government
consumption deflator. This implies a significant upward revision for
government consumption growth from our previous forecast to around 1.4
per cent per annum from zero growth in 2019. As noted by Kirby (2015)
the effect of the increase in government consumption growth is likely to
lead to only a modest increase in GDP as a result. Given the current
forecasts, the profile for government consumption now resembles the
'implied conservative' plans rather than the 'coalition
plans' from that analysis. Furthermore, this means that government
spending is no longer forecast to be the lowest it has been
historically.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
Household sector
Private consumption remains the largest contributor to growth,
adding 1.8 out of 3 percentage points during the last quarter of 2014 on
a year-on-year basis. 2014 registered a significant growth in consumer
spending as well as a modest increase in real income, which has led to a
reduction in the saving ratio and a small increase in the household
debt-to-income ratio. House prices have kept rising, which has had a
positive income effect on homeowners, albeit at a slower pace.
Household consumption increased by 0.6 per cent in the fourth
quarter of 2014 compared to the previous quarter, most of the growth
coming from services and expenditure of UK tourists abroad. Spending in
durable goods has also increased, albeit at a slower rate than in the
previous quarter. Retail sales for March 2015 have been buoyant, with
volume and value increases on a year-on-year basis. We project household
expenditure to remain strong over 2015, growing by 3.6 per cent, based
on expectations of strong wage and employment growth, and to moderate
over 2016.
Real disposable income grew by 0.6 per cent during 2014,
significantly less than our estimate of 1.6 per cent from our previous
Review. We have increased our estimate of income growth for 2015 from
3.6 in our previous Review to 4.7 per cent. The difference is due
primarily to a reduction in the rate of consumer price inflation, which
pushes real income up (see figure 11). In particular, in our previous
Review we predicted an inflation rate of 0.9 per cent in 2015 while we
now project a contraction in prices of 0.2 per cent. We forecast that
real disposable income growth will moderate from 2016 onwards as
inflation picks up and unemployment stabilises at around 5 1/4 per cent.
In line with our previous Review, real disposable income per capita will
grow over the medium term at around 2 per cent.
Slower growth in real disposable income and a strong outturn of
consumer spending has translated into a fall in household saving. The
saving ratio--excluding net adjustment for equity held in pension
funds--fell from 0.9 to -0.2 per cent in 2014 (see figure A6). We
forecast the saving ratio will increase in 2015 to 0.9 per cent, before
falling to 0.3 per cent in 2016, and then growing steadily in the near
term; a view consistent with our projections of income growth
outstripping spending growth in the medium term. Household debt to
income ratio has increased compared to our previous Review, from 143.0
to 144.2 per cent. In line with our projections for the saving ratio, we
expect the debt-to-income ratio to fall from 2015 onwards, simply due to
growth in nominal income surpassing growth in nominal debt.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
Mortgage approvals seem to have stabilised after a sharp fall
during the first half of 2014. The Bank of England's February Money
and Credit report highlights a fall in mortgage approvals of 1.6 per
cent in January 2015 and a subsequent increase of 1.8 per cent in
February. A similar picture is provided by HMRC data on property
transactions, which show that after a significant drop in February 2014
transactions have remained fairly constant until January 2015. There has
been a substantial rebound in February 2015 with a monthly growth rate
of 4.7 per cent which could, as we mentioned in our previous Review, be
the consequence of the modification of residential stamp duty introduced
in the Autumn Statement 2014.
Recent house price data supports our view of a softening of the
housing market. House prices are still rising but the growth rate has
been declining since the second half of 2014. According to our preferred
measure of house prices, the seasonally and mix-adjusted index from the
ONS, prices in the UK have increased by 7.1 per cent in February 2015
compared to twelve months earlier; a much smaller figure compared to the
12.1 per cent increase in September 2014. The Nationwide house price
index, which acts as one of the leading indicators for the ONS measure
as it is derived earlier in the house purchase process, provides a
similar picture: on a 12-month basis, house prices in March increased by
5.1 per cent; in June 2014 they grew by 11.9 per cent. Also from
Nationwide, house price inflation has slowed for the whole of the UK
except in the North of England. It also reports a significant slowdown
in Fondon. Year-on-year, prices in the capital grew by 12.7 per cent
during the first quarter of 2015, compared to a growth rate of 17.8 per
cent in the last quarter of 2014. According to the Royal Institute of
Chartered Surveyors (RICS), house prices will still grow during 2015 due
to lack of supply, but at a slower pace, reaching a rate of 3 per cent
growth over the last three months of 2015. We expect house prices to
increase by 8.2 per cent in 2015 and by 3.1 per cent in 2016.
According to the Halifax, Nationwide, and our own database, the
house price-to-earnings ratio has reached historically high levels and
is projected to keep increasing. The Bank of England has kept Bank Rate
close to zero since March 2009, affording 'cheap' mortgage
rates to households; it may pose a risk to the economy. Households are
highly indebted, which makes them vulnerable to sudden increases in
interest rates. In fact, interest rates have already started increasing.
Markets currently expect the Bank of England to keep Bank Rate low until
at least 2016 but this has not prevented the spread between lending and
deposit rates increasing by around 55 basis points in 2014. This comes
from a reduction of around 60 basis points in deposit rates and a fall
of just 5 basis points in lending rates. While the nominal return on
saving has fallen further, we have also seen a modest pick-up in income
gearing. Interest payments have risen relative to gross disposable
incomes in recent quarters (figure A5). This may be a sign of indebted
households increasing their mortgage payments as budget constraints
ease, but if this pattern persists it does pose a downside risk to our
consumer spending forecasts.
Supply conditions
Although business investment has shown robust growth between 2010
and 2014, it stalled in the third quarter of 2014 and fell by 0.9 per
cent in the final quarter. Given the relative volatility of business
investment, this drop in investment is not particularly significant.
Nevertheless there is some concern that uncertainty regarding
developments in the Euro Area and potential spillovers to UK domestic
markets is weighing on firms' investment decisions. The
Confederation of British Industry's Business Optimism Index--which
ranges from -100 to +100, where 0 represents neutrality fell to 8 in the
fourth quarter of 2014, down from a post-crisis peak of 33 in the second
quarter of 2014 before rising slightly to 15 in the first quarter of
2015. This compares to a trough of -64 in the first quarter of 2009 (see
figure 12). Businesses surveyed by the CBI in the first quarter of this
year reported the main factors limiting investment as: uncertainty about
demand (50 per cent of respondents), inadequate net return on proposed
investments (42 per cent) and shortage of internal finance (15 per
cent). This ties in with research by Banerjee et al. (2015) who conclude
that uncertainty about the future state of the economy is a bigger
factor influencing investment decisions than poor financing conditions.
We predict growth in business investment of 4.9 per cent in 2015, rising
to 5.9 per cent in 2016 before settling at around 1.5 per cent per annum
in the medium term.
The annual rate of growth in the stock of lending to UK businesses
has been contracting since 2009 and remained negative in the fourth
quarter of 2014, although less severe than in recent years by most
measures. Respondents to the Bank of England's Credit Conditions
Survey reported that the availability of credit was unchanged for small
and medium sized enterprises, and increased for large businesses in the
final quarter of 2014. This follows several quarters of improving credit
conditions for businesses, with the net balance of 84 per cent of
respondents to the Deloitte CFO Survey, who reported that credit was
available and 72 per cent who reported that credit was cheap in the
fourth quarter of 2014. This compares to a net balance of around 90 per
cent who considered credit hard to get and over 80 per cent who
considered credit to be costly at the start of 2009.
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
Housing investment fell by 1.1 per cent in the final quarter of
2014,
but this still represents a rise of 5.9 per cent year-on-year. Data
from the Department for Communities and Local Government (DCLG) show
that seasonally adjusted housing starts in England in the last quarter
of 2014 were estimated at 29,800, 10 per cent lower compared to the
previous quarter and 9 per cent lower than the same quarter one year
earlier. In contrast, housing completions were estimated at 30,760, 1
per cent higher than the previous quarter and 8 per cent higher than the
same quarter one year earlier. DCLG (2012) reports that the time taken
to construct a new home from start to completion can be anywhere between
a few months and several years. Rudimentary analysis of the data
indicates that completions are most strongly correlated with starts
lagged by three quarters, thus assuming this average lag is not just a
spurious product of a small sample size, we expect aggregate completion
statistics to start declining year-on-year in around the third quarter
of this year. Housing starts and completions are still 39 and 36 per
cent respectively below their peak in the second quarter of 2007. Our
forecast is for housing investment to grow by 4 1/2 per cent in 2015,
rising to around 11 per cent in 2016 before falling to around 6 per cent
in the medium term.
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
The unemployment rate continued to fall, reaching 5.6 per cent of
the labour force in the first quarter of 2015. This compares to an
average unemployment rate of 11.4 per cent for the Euro Area. We expect
the unemployment rate to average around 514 per cent this year, and to
remain at this level through to the end of our forecast horizon. The
youth unemployment rate has also fallen to 16.1 per cent in the three
months to February, down from a peak of 22.5 in the three months to
September 2011. This level is still significantly higher than an average
of around 13 per cent between 2000 and the start of the crisis. However,
these figures are skewed upwards by increasing numbers of young people
enrolling in fulltime education, reducing the labour force aged 16-24 to
a smaller population of less skilled individuals. It is worth bearing in
mind that the increasing number of full-time students may be, at least
in part, a consequence of higher unemployment rates and the weak economy
of 2008-12. Data from the Labour Force Survey shows that the number of
16-24 year-olds who are not in employment, education or training (NEET)
has fallen to 13.5 per cent in the first quarter of 2014, which
represents a return to the average level in the years leading up to the
crisis (see figure 13). While this return to pre-crisis levels is
welcome, it does also highlight the long-standing structural issue in
the UK labour market, and the waste of potential that these figures
imply.
Productivity continues to disappoint. In the fourth quarter of
2014, whole economy output per worker, per job and per hour worked were
all still below pre-crisis levels, with output per hour worked the worst
affected at 1.7 per cent below its peak in the first quarter of 2008.
Sluggish productivity growth is driven by poor performance in the
production sector, with output per hour worked in the fourth quarter of
2014 at 5.7 per cent below its pre-crisis peak. On the other hand, all
measures of productivity in manufacturing and services have met or
exceeded their pre-crisis peaks, with output per job in manufacturing
showing the strongest recovery, reaching 6.4 per cent above its level in
the first quarter of 2008.
The robust outturn in employment and hours worked appears to be
pulling productivity down, particularly output per hour worked. Wage
growth has also been weak, with falling real consumer and real producer
wages between 2012 and 2014, reflecting poor productivity growth. Indeed
falling wages may be a cause of sluggish labour productivity growth if,
as suggested by Carney (2014), low wages have led to firms hiring more
labour instead of investing in labour augmenting capital. Barnett et al.
(2014) find evidence to support the view that reduced capital investment
and sub-optimal resource allocation are a drag on productivity. We
expect the labour input to stabilise from 2016 onwards, and grow at a
more muted pace than in recent years. Such a projection is consistent
with unemployment at around 514 per cent and a resumption of the gradual
downward trend in average hours worked. Beyond 2016, the economic growth
is dependent on a rebound in productivity growth. Indeed we expect
average productivity to grow by 0.6 per cent in 2015, before
accelerating to 1.2 per cent in 2016. Productivity growth of around 2
per cent over the medium term is not a view of the long-run steady state
growth rate but rather a modest period of catch-up. That this
performance will not materialise is a significant downside risk to the
outlook.
Public finances
The outturns for fiscal aggregates for fiscal year 2014-15 suggest
the gap between the public sector's revenues and expenditures
narrowed more than had previously been expected. The narrowing gap was
more a consequence of weaker than projected current expenditure. Public
sector net borrowing, excluding the public sector banks, reached 87.3
billion [pounds sterling] (4.9 per cent of nominal GDP), down from 98.5
billion [pounds sterling] (5.5 per cent of GDP) in 201314. Public sector
net borrowing has now shrunk in each fiscal year since its recent peak
of 152 billion [pounds sterling] (10.6 per cent of GDP) in 2009-10.
Our projections are similar to those of the OBR. In both instances
borrowing is expected to narrow further. The discretionary policy
decisions announced in Budget 2015 have a limited effect on these
projections. Overall, Budget 2015 was fiscally neutral, even if it was
far from politically so. Presenting a fiscally neutral package extended
the government's approach of the past three years' Budgetary
statements.
We assume that tax rates evolve in a manner consistent with
announced policy changes. The revenues themselves are endogenously
determined within our model NiGEM. Tax revenues grow in line with the
tax base, adjusting for the announced tax policy changes. The speed and
composition of nominal economic growth are the key determinants of
changes in the tax base. We assume that as nominal wage growth starts to
outstrip the rate of inflation, fiscal drag will further support the
buoyancy of future tax revenues. We expect the total tax take to rise
from 35.5 per cent of GDP in 2014-15 to just over 36 per cent by
2019-20. Thus, the tax take returns to around its average level for the
20-year period prior to the onset of the financial crisis (figure 15).
The OBR's forecast incorporates the government's policy
assumptions for the future path of TME. For the period beyond 2015-16
the projections for government consumption and investment are derived as
the difference between TME and annually managed expenditures (AME). The
OBR's projections imply that government consumption will start to
rise towards the end of the next Parliament. The forecast revision
introduced by the OBR for 2019-20 amounts to a 28.5 billion [pounds
sterling] (1.3 per cent of GDP) increase in government consumption.
Approximately half of this change is due to projections for lower
social transfers and interest payments. The remaining half is due to a
change in the government's assumption that total spending will now
grow in line with nominal GDP.
We assume that government consumption evolves as the OBR projects
and that the government broadly meets its net investment ambitions over
the next Parliament. The other components of expenditure are
endogenously determined in our model.
Even with this significant loosening of policy on current plans,
the government is still expected to record a surplus of 9.3 billion
[pounds sterling] (0.4 per cent of GDP) in 2019-20. Nonetheless, this is
a significantly smaller absolute surplus than we had expected based on
the government's Autumn Statement, where policy assumptions built
into our forecast implied an absolute surplus of 34.5 billion [pounds
sterling] (1.5 per cent of GDP).
The magnitude of public sector net borrowing is expected to shrink
in each year of the forecast, mainly through significant spending
restraint. Borrowing is expected to be just over 4 per cent of GDP this
fiscal year (78.6 billion [pounds sterling]) before falling to around 2
1/2 per cent of GDP in 2016-17. We expect the government to run a
primary surplus (the government budget balance excluding interest
payments) in fiscal year 2017-18, one year before the first year of
absolute surpluses is recorded.
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
As noted in Kirby (2015) the implied fiscal stances from each of
the main political parties' own fiscal rules had suggested looser
fiscal policy than the government's Autumn Statement. The coalition
government's changes in assumptions about TME spending in 2019-20
are consistent with the parties' looser fiscal stances and
reinforce the particular uncertainty over how fiscal policy will evolve
after 7 May 2015. This uncertainty stems not just from the unknown
composition of the next government, but also from the lack of detail on
fiscal policy over the next Parliamentary term. It is probable that
government consumption will be higher, given the concerns over the
ability for expected services to be delivered by non-ring fenced
departments and local government. The other unknown is whether taxes
will rise. At the moment the political debate revolves around modest
amounts of revenues, but as Paul Johnson of the IFS has highlighted,
newly elected governments have a habit of raising taxes once in power.
Saving and investment
In table A9 we disaggregate the economy into three broad sectors:
household, corporate and government. For each of these sectors, if
investment is greater than savings then that sector is a net borrower
and vice versa. The aggregate of these three sectors is the current
account for the UK economy, which describes the aggregate
borrowing/lending position of the whole economy. If in deficit, it
implies that the economy is not saving enough to fund domestic
investment and must therefore be externally financed. It is not possible
to infer whether the levels of capital are optimal from the position of
the current account, just the immediate financing needs of the economy.
Household saving reached 4.1 per cent of GDP in 2014, the lowest
level since 2008. Despite this moderation, our view of the evolution of
household saving remains consistent with our previous forecast. We
expect the saving rate to have reached its trough in 2014 and that
through 2015 and onwards, it will increase. This will be driven by a
larger increase in real personal disposable income than consumption, as
growth in real consumer wages picks up in the near term as a result of
the low inflationary environment relieving the pressure on household
budgets. From 2016, we expect that, as price growth picks up, eroding
household purchasing power, consumption growth moderates. However, real
wages are expected to continue to grow driven by the resumption of
productivity growth, the key to increasing living standards in the long
run. By 2019, we expect household saving to reach around 6 per cent of
GDP.
Housing investment is currently around 5 per cent of GDP, around
the same levels as the turn of the millennium, and we expect it will
increase throughout our forecast period, reaching 6 1/2 per cent. This
implies that households' net lending positions will be broadly in
balance by the end of our forecast period.
Our forecasts for corporate investment and saving are both expected
to be marginally lower in the near term than our forecast published in
the February 2015 Review. The uncertainty around the Euro Area
developments is expected to weigh down on business investment throughout
2015. As this dissipates, from 2016 onwards, we expect corporate
investment to rebound slightly. We forecast that corporate investment
will increase to around 11 1/4 per cent of GDP in 2016. By 2019 we
expect corporate investment to be in the region of 11 1/2 as a per cent
of GDP.
Theory would suggest that the net position of the corporate sector
would be that of a borrower from the rest of the economy, but since 2003
the opposite has been a persistent feature of the UK economy. This trend
appears to have reversed in 2013 and 2014; the corporate sector's
net position has been broadly neutral, reduced from a net lender of 3.3
per cent of GDP in 2009. This reduction has occurred on both sides of
the balance with investment gradually picking up from its trough of 8
per cent of GDP in 2009, and corporate saving falling dramatically
between 2012 and 2013; it has continued to fall since. We expect the
sector to remain broadly neutral in 2015, and to become a net borrower
throughout the rest of our sample, requiring around 3 per cent of GDP
from the rest of the economy by 2019 to fund investment.
Government dis-saving has continued to shrink since its trough in
2009 of 5.7 per cent of GDP. If the mandated fiscal plans evolve as laid
out in the March 2015 Budget, we expect that dis-saving will continue to
narrow throughout our forecast period with government returning to the
position of gross saver towards the end of 2016. If the path of the
economy evolves as we forecast, by 2019 we expect government saving to
be around 3 per cent of GDP. Throughout the past three years government
investment as a percentage of GDP has remained relatively stable at
around 2 per cent. This trend is expected to continue throughout our
forecast period given current plans for the capital budget. In the near
term, the government will remain a net borrower from the rest of the
economy; however as government dis-saving is eliminated the government
will become a net lender to the rest of the economy. We expect this to
occur around 2018, and by 2019 the government is forecast to be a net
lender of around 1 per cent of GDP to the rest of the economy.
Important determinants of the UK current account are the net income
payments. Historically, income earned abroad by domestic companies has
been greater than that of income earned by foreign companies in the UK.
The average surplus on net income between 1998 and 2011 was 1 per cent
of GDP. However, from 2012 onwards this position has reversed, with the
net deficit in 2014 reaching 1.9 per cent of GDP. This period
corresponds with a sharp decline in the balance of the primary account
with Europe and to a lesser extent the US. We assume that the deficit on
net factor income is a transitory phenomenon being led by two factors.
Firstly, rates of return on foreign liabilities should increase as the
Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank begin monetary tightening.
Secondly, resumption in growth in the Euro Area should lead to an
improvement in profits and therefore the return from direct investment.
Europe contributes 45 per cent of total credits in the primary income
account, with the US contributing around 25 per cent (ONS, 2014). We
therefore expect that the improvement in net factor income will be
heavily tied to the performance of each of these economies, especially
the Euro Area. Should Federal Reserve or ECB tightening occur later than
in our forecast, or equally the recovery in the Euro Area not
materialise as soon as expected, net income would likely stay in deficit
longer.
[FIGURE 16 OMITTED]
The aggregate of our three sectors implies that in 2015 the UK will
require around 5 per cent of GDP financing from the rest of the world.
We expect this to remain relatively flat through to 2017 as the
reduction in the net lending positions of the government and households
are offset by the increase in the net borrowing position of the
corporate sector. From 2017 onwards, as the net borrowing position of
the corporate sector stabilises, and the government becomes a net lender
to the rest of the economy, we expect the current account deficit to
reduce. By 2019 we predict that the UK economy will require around 2.5
to 3 per cent of GDP of finance from abroad for domestic investment. The
main risk surrounding this forecast is on the downside from net income;
if the balance of net income remains persistently in deficit rather than
moving back to surplus as we have forecast, the current account would be
expected to record significantly larger deficits as a percentage of GDP
than we currently project.
Medium term
Table A10 presents the modal view of how the economy will evolve in
the medium term. Moving from the current disequilibrium of the UK
economy we expect growth rates in excess of long run potential, which we
estimate to be 2 per cent per annum, in order for the negative output
gap to close. The projections exclude any future shocks to the economy
from either domestic or external sources, however we realise that such
events will occur and move the path of the economy away from the
projections presented. To illustrate this uncertainty we publish fan
charts. Figure 17 shows that there is a more than 1 in 10 chance that
the economy will grow by more than 334 per cent per annum and a less
than 10 per cent chance that the economy will grow by less than 1 per
cent per annum in 2019.
Driving our medium-term forecasts is a resumption of productivity
growth, which underpins growth in wages and GDP per capita. We forecast
that productivity growth will pick up in a gradual fashion, with the
sharpest increase occurring in 2016 before increasing more gradually
from 2017 onwards. We expect that by 2020-24 productivity will be
growing at around 2 per cent per annum. As with our GDP growth
estimates, this implies productivity catch-up above its long-run
average, which we estimate to be just below 2 per cent per annum.
The return in productivity coincides with a general decline in the
labour input into production; we expect a fall in hours worked as wages
increase. By 2020-24 we expect labour input to grow at 0.4 per cent per
annum, while average earnings are expected to grow at 3.3 per cent per
annum. The sharp falls in unemployment seen recently are expected to
have finished and we expect it to remain stable from 2015 onwards at
around 5.2 per cent.
[FIGURE 17 OMITTED]
We know that fiscal policy will not evolve as we have forecast,
with the main political parties outlining fiscal policies within their
manifestos which differ from those announced in the March budget.
However, the next parliament is likely to involve further fiscal
consolidation differing in its speed and composition. That being said,
if fiscal policy were conducted given the current plans, we expect
public sector net borrowing to fall, with the government returning to
surplus by 2018. Between 202024 we predict that the government would run
a surplus of around 0.2 per cent of GDP and therefore would not require
external borrowing to finance public investment. The public debt stock
is expected to remain stable at around 80 per cent of GDP until 2017,
after which it begins to fall. By 2020-24 we forecast that it will have
fallen to around 65 per cent of GDP.
In our baseline we expect monetary tightening to occur gradually,
with the first interest rate rise occurring in 2016. By 2020-24 we
forecast that the interest rate will be between 2 1/2 to 4 per cent per
annum. We believe that the risks around this interest rate path are
broadly balanced. On the downside, negative economic shocks which could
slow down the economy, such as Greece defaulting or decoupling of
expectations as a result of the near-term low inflationary environment,
could delay interest rate rises. Conversely, if the amount of slack in
the economy has been over estimated this could lead to a sharper than
expected rebound in inflation bringing forward rate rises.
Exchange rates over the longer term will be determined by the
normalisation of external monetary policy, especially the policy of the
ECB and the Federal Reserve. We predict that the real effective exchange
rate will appreciate 0.8 per cent by 2020-24. This appreciation will
occur as normalisation of UK monetary policy is expected to occur before
that of the ECB, however this is likely to be partially offset as the
Federal Reserve normalisation is expected to occur before that of the
Bank of England.
After 2016, the current account deficit is expected to reduce
through to the end of our forecast period; by 2020-24 we expect the
deficit to be 2.0 per cent of GDR Over this period the trade balance as
a percentage of GDP remains stable, as such the improvements in the
current account are due to net income returning to surplus. If the net
income deficit represents a structural change rather than a transitory
movement, as we assume, the current account deficit would be
significantly larger than we have forecast.
The risks to this forecast, both internal and external, are
significant. Externally, these risks are likely to be weighted to the
downside; such scenarios as a Greek default would likely cause
disruption to European and UK banking systems and would probably lead to
a significant decline in domestic demand conditions in Europe,
depressing UK exports and subsequently GDP. The main internal risk
occurs from the timing and strength of productivity growth; should this
occur later or slower than we forecast, GDP growth would be slower than
we forecast.
Appendix--Forecast details
[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A9 OMITTED]
[FIGURE A10 OMITTED]
Table A1. Exchange rates and interest rates
UK exchange rates
FTSE
Effective Dollar Euro All-share
2011 = 100 index
2009 100.50 1.57 1.12 2040.8
2010 100.12 1.55 1.17 2472.7
2011 100.00 1.60 1.15 2587.6
2012 104.21 1.59 1.23 2617.7
2013 102.92 1.56 1.18 3006.2
2014 111.05 1.65 1.24 3136.6
2015 115.85 1.49 1.38 3292.8
2016 116.10 1.48 1.38 3450.5
20/7 116.21 1.50 1.37 3604.2
2018 116.39 1.52 1.35 3784.8
2019 116.57 1.54 1.34 4005.3
2014 Q1 109.11 1.66 1.21 3148.9
2014 Q2 110.66 1.68 1.23 3171.0
2014 Q3 112.46 1.67 1.26 3161.3
2014 Q4 111.96 1.58 1.27 3065.3
2015 Q1 115.36 1.51 1.35 3207.6
2015 Q2 115.97 1.48 1.39 3300.8
2015 Q3 116.05 1.48 1.39 3322.0
2015 Q4 116.02 1.48 1.39 3340.9
2016 Q1 116.05 1.48 1.39 3392.6
2016 Q2 116.09 1.48 1.38 3434.1
2016 Q3 116.12 1.48 1.38 3462.7
2016 Q4 116.15 1.49 1.38 3512.5
Percentage
changes
2009/2008 -10.4 -15.5 -10.6 -14.7
2010/2009 -0.4 -1.2 3.8 21.2
2011/2010 -0.1 3.7 -1.2 4.6
2012/2011 4.2 -1.1 7.0 1.2
2013/2012 -1.2 -1.3 -4.5 14.8
2014/2013 7.9 5.3 5.4 4.3
2015/2014 4.3 -9.7 10.9 5.0
2016/2015 0.2 -0.3 0.4 4.8
2017/2016 0.1 1.0 -0.9 4.5
2018/2017 0.2 1.5 -1.1 5.0
2019/2018 0.2 1.4 -1.1 5.8
2014Q4/2013Q4 5.3 -2.2 6.5 -1.0
2015Q412014Q4 3.6 -6.6 9.5 9.0
2016Q4/2015Q4 0.1 0.5 -0.6 5.1
Interest rates
3-month Mortgage 10-year World Bank
rates interest gilts (a) Rate (b)
2009 1.2 4.0 3.7 2.0 0.50
2010 0.7 4.0 3.6 1.6 0.50
2011 0.9 4.1 3.1 1.8 0.50
2012 0.8 4.2 1.8 1.6 0.50
2013 0.5 4.4 2.4 1.3 0.50
2014 0.5 4.4 2.5 1.0 0.50
2015 0.6 4.5 1.7 0.8 0.50
2016 1.0 4.6 2.3 1.3 1.00
20/7 1.5 4.8 2.8 1.9 1.50
2018 2.0 5.0 3.2 2.3 2.00
2019 2.4 5.3 3.5 2.7 2.50
2014 Q1 0.5 4.4 2.8 1.3 0.50
2014 Q2 0.5 4.4 2.7 0.9 0.50
2014 Q3 0.6 4.5 2.6 0.8 0.50
2014 Q4 0.6 4.5 2.1 0.8 0.50
2015 Q1 0.6 4.5 1.6 0.7 0.50
2015 Q2 0.6 4.5 1.6 0.7 0.50
2015 Q3 0.6 4.5 1.8 0.8 0.50
2015 Q4 0.6 4.5 2.0 0.9 0.50
2016 Q1 0.8 4.6 2.1 1.1 0.75
2016 Q2 0.9 4.6 2.3 1.2 0.75
2016 Q3 1.1 4.7 2.4 1.3 1.00
2016 Q4 1.2 4.7 2.5 1.5 1.00
Percentage
changes
2009/2008
2010/2009
2011/2010
2012/2011
2013/2012
2014/2013
2015/2014
2016/2015
2017/2016
2018/2017
2019/2018
2014Q4/2013Q4
2015Q412014Q4
2016Q4/2015Q4
Notes: We assume that bilateral exchange rates for the first quarter
of this year are the average of information available to 15 April
2015. We then assume that bilateral rates remain constant for the
following two quarters before moving in-line with the path implied by
the backward-looking uncovered interest rate parity condition based on
interest rate differentials relative to the US. (a) Weighted average
of central bank intervention rates in OECD economies, (b) End of
period.
Table A2. Price indices
2011=100
Unit Imports Exports Wholesale
labour deflator deflator price
costs index (a)
2009 99.1 89.9 89.9 95.8
2010 100.3 93.4 94.5 97.3
2011 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
2012 101.9 99.2 99.6 101.1
2013 103.4 100.4 101.1 101.9
2014 103.8 96.5 98.9 102.8
2015 105.1 91.5 94.8 102.9
2016 105.7 93.9 97.1 102.9
2017 107.0 97.4 99.4 104.2
2018 108.4 100.0 101.5 106.2
2019 109.7 101.9 103.4 108.2
Percentage
changes
2009/2008 4.4 1.9 3.6 1.4
2010/2009 1.2 3.9 5.1 1.5
2011/2010 -0.3 7.1 5.8 2.8
2012/2011 1.9 -0.8 -0.4 1.1
2013/2012 1.4 1.2 1.5 0.8
2014/2013 0.4 -3.9 -2.2 0.9
2015/2014 1.2 -5.2 -4.2 0.1
201612015 0.7 2.6 2.4 0.0
2017/2016 1.2 3.7 2.4 1.2
2018/2017 1.3 2.7 2.2 1.9
2019/2018 1.2 1.9 1.9 1.9
2014Q4/13Q4 1.2 -4.3 -3.8 0.6
2015Q4/14Q4 0.3 -3.6 -1.8 0.1
2016Q4/15Q4 0.9 4.2 2.7 0.5
World oil Consump- GDP
price tion deflator
($)(b) deflator (market
prices)
2009 61.8 92.6 94.9
2010 78.8 96.7 97.9
2011 108.5 100.0 100.0
2012 110.4 102.1 101.7
2013 107.1 104.0 103.5
2014 97.8 105.6 105.2
2015 60.2 105.4 106.2
2016 79.8 106.5 107.2
2017 81.2 108.6 108.7
2018 82.8 110.9 110.8
2019 84.5 113.1 113.1
Percentage
changes
2009/2008 -35.4 1.6 2.0
2010/2009 27.6 4.4 3.2
2011/2010 37.6 3.4 2.1
2012/2011 1.8 2.1 1.7
2013/2012 -3.0 1.9 1.8
2014/2013 -8.7 1.6 1.7
2015/2014 -38.4 -0.2 0.9
201612015 32.5 1.1 0.9
2017/2016 1.7 1.9 1.4
2018/2017 2.0 2.1 1.9
2019/2018 2.0 2.0 2.0
2014Q4/13Q4 -30.3 1.3 1.3
2015Q4/14Q4 -7.2 -0.6 1.0
2016Q4/15Q4 14.8 1.4 0.8
Retail price index
All items Excluding Consumer
mortgage prices
interest index
2009 90.9 90.7 92.7
2010 95.1 95.0 95.7
2011 100.0 100.0 100.0
2012 103.2 103.2 102.8
2013 106.4 106.4 105.5
2014 108.9 109.0 107.0
2015 109.6 110.0 106.9
2016 111.7 111.9 108.0
2017 115.5 114.6 110.0
2018 119.9 117.6 112.3
2019 124.2 120.6 114.5
Percentage
changes
2009/2008 -0.5 2.0 2.2
2010/2009 4.6 4.8 3.3
2011/2010 5.2 5.3 4.5
2012/2011 3.2 3.2 2.8
2013/2012 3.0 3.1 2.6
2014/2013 2.4 2.4 1.4
2015/2014 0.6 0.9 -0.1
201612015 1.9 1.7 1.0
2017/2016 3.4 2.4 1.9
2018/2017 3.8 2.6 2.1
2019/2018 3.6 2.5 2.0
2014Q4/13Q4 1.9 2.0 0.9
2015Q4/14Q4 0.4 0.9 -0.1
2016Q4/15Q4 2.7 2.0 1.4
Notes: (a) Excluding food, beverages, tobacco and petroleum products,
(b) Per barrel, average of Dubai and Brent spot prices.
Table A3. Gross domestic product and components of expenditure
billion [pounds sterling], 2011 prices
Final consumption Gross capital formation
expenditure
Households General Gross Changes in
& NPISHM govt. fixed inventories
investment (b)
2009 1034.6 337.1 240.6 -16.0
2010 1038.3 337.2 254.9 5.7
2011 1039.1 337.3 260.8 4.3
2012 1050.8 345.2 262.7 6.5
2013 1068.5 344.2 271.6 10.2
2014 1094.9 350.0 292.8 13.3
2015 1133.9 352.5 304.4 10.3
2016 1166.8 349.6 324.6 10.0
2017 1187.6 346.6 339.0 10.0
2018 1210.5 345.9 350.8 10.0
2019 1237.2 350.9 361.5 10.0
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -3.1 1.2 -14.4
2010/2009 0.4 0.0 5.9
2011/2010 0.1 0.0 2.3
2012/2011 1.1 2.3 0.7
2013/2012 1.7 -0.3 3.4
2014/2013 2.5 1.7 7.8
2015/2014 3.6 0.7 4.0
2016/2015 2.9 -0.8 6.6
2017/2016 1.8 -0.9 4.5
2018/2017 1.9 -0.2 3.5
2019/2018 2.2 1.4 3.0
Decomposition of growth in GDP
2009 -2.0 0.2 -2.5 -0.3
2010 0.2 0.0 0.9 1.4
2011 0.1 0.0 0.4 -0.1
2012 0.7 0.5 0.1 0.1
2013 1.1 -0.1 0.5 0.2
2014 1.6 0.4 1.3 0.2
2015 2.3 0.1 0.7 -0.2
2016 1.9 -0.2 1.2 0.0
2017 1.2 -0.2 0.8 0.0
2018 1.2 0.0 0.6 0.0
2019 1.4 0.3 0.6 0.0
Domestic Total Total
demand exports final
(c) expenditure
2009 1593.2 445.1 2039.4
2010 1636.1 472.8 2109.6
2011 1641.5 499.5 2141.0
2012 1665.1 502.8 2167.9
2013 1694.5 510.2 2204.7
2014 1751.0 513.5 2264.5
2015 1801.1 536.0 2337.1
2016 1850.9 566.2 2417.1
2017 1883.3 595.6 2478.9
2018 1917.2 623.6 2540.8
2019 1959.7 650.0 2609.7
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -4.9 -8.2 -5.6
2010/2009 2.7 6.2 3.4
2011/2010 0.3 5.6 1.5
2012/2011 1.4 0.7 1.3
2013/2012 1.8 1.5 1.7
2014/2013 3.3 0.6 2.7
2015/2014 2.9 4.4 3.2
2016/2015 2.8 5.6 3.4
2017/2016 1.7 5.2 2.6
2018/2017 1.8 4.7 2.5
2019/2018 2.2 4.2 2.7
Decomposition of growth in GDP
2009 -5.0 -2.4 -7.4
2010 2.8 1.8 4.5
2011 0.3 1.7 2.0
2012 1.5 0.2 1.7
2013 1.8 0.5 2.3
2014 3.4 0.2 3.6
2015 2.9 1.3 4.3
2016 2.9 1.7 4.6
2017 1.8 1.6 3.5
2018 1.9 1.5 3.4
2019 2.3 1.4 3.7
Total Net trade GDP at
imports market
(c) prices
2009 476.6 -31.5 1561.6
2010 518.2 -45.3 1591.5
2011 523.3 -23.8 1617.7
2012 539.6 -36.8 1628.3
2013 547.4 -37.1 1655.4
2014 559.2 -45.8 1702.2
2015 590.2 -54.2 1 744.2
2016 628.0 -61.8 1786.4
2017 645.4 -49.7 1830.8
2018 659.9 -36.3 1878.2
2019 679.3 -29.2 1927.7
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -9.8 -4.3
2010/2009 8.7 1.9
2011/2010 1.0 1.6
2012/2011 3.1 0.7
2013/2012 1.4 1.7
2014/2013 2.2 2.8
2015/2014 5.5 2.5
2016/2015 6.4 2.4
2017/2016 2.8 2.5
2018/2017 2.2 2.6
2019/2018 2.9 2.6
Decomposition of growth in GDP
2009 3.2 0.7 -4.3
2010 -2.7 -0.9 1.9
2011 -0.3 1.4 1.6
2012 -1.0 -0.8 0.7
2013 -0.5 0.0 1.7
2014 -0.7 -0.5 2.8
2015 -1.8 -0.5 2.5
2016 -2.2 -0.4 2.4
2017 -1.0 0.7 2.5
2018 -0.8 0.7 2.6
2019 -1.0 0.4 2.6
Notes: (a) Non-profit institutions serving households, (b) Including
acquisitions less disposals of valuables and quarterly alignment
adjustment, (c) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud, (d)
Components may not add up to total GDP growth due to rounding and the
statistical discrepancy included in GDP.
Table A4. External sector
Exports of Imports of Net trade
goods (a) goods (a) in goods
(a)
billion [pounds sterling],
2011 prices (b)
2009 261.2 355.3 -94.1
2010 289.4 398.9 -109.5
2011 309.2 405.7 -96.5
2012 306.6 416.2 -109.6
2013 305.1 419.1 -114.0
2014 305.0 430.2 -125.2
2015 320.7 457.0 -136.3
2016 340.7 489.9 -149.3
2017 358.0 504.7 -146.7
2018 374.5 516.4 -141.9
2019 390.2 531.8 -141.6
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -10.1 -10.8
2010/2009 10.8 12.2
2011/2010 6.8 1.7
2012/2011 -0.8 2.6
2013/2012 -0.5 0.7
2014/2013 0.0 2.7
201512014 5.1 6.2
201612015 6.2 7.2
201712016 5.1 3.0
2018/2017 4.6 2.3
201912018 4.2 3.0
Exports of Imports of Net trade
services services in
services
billion [pounds sterling],
2011 prices (b)
2009 184.0 120.5 63.5
2010 183.4 119.3 64.1
2011 190.3 117.6 72.7
2012 196.2 123.4 72.8
2013 205.1 128.3 76.8
2014 208.5 129.1 79.4
2015 215.3 133.2 82.1
2016 225.6 138.1 87.5
2017 237.6 140.7 97.0
2018 249.2 143.5 105.7
2019 259.8 147.4 112.4
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -5.9 -7.3
2010/2009 -0.4 -1.0
2011/2010 3.8 -1.4
2012/2011 3.1 4.9
2013/2012 4.6 4.0
2014/2013 1.6 0.6
201512014 3.3 3.2
201612015 4.8 3.7
201712016 5.3 1.8
2018/2017 4.9 2.0
201912018 4.3 2.8
Export World Terms of Current
price trade (d) trade (e) balance
competitive-
ness (c)
2011=100 % of GDP
2009 94.7 86.0 100.0 -2.8
2010 96.4 94.7 101.2 -2.6
2011 100.0 100.0 100.0 -1.7
2012 101.3 102.2 100.4 -3.7
2013 100.7 104.8 100.7 -4.5
2014 104.9 108.6 102.4 -5.5
2015 100.8 113.4 103.6 -4.7
2016 101.1 119.6 103.4 -5.0
2017 99.8 124.7 102.0 -4.6
2018 99.0 129.9 101.5 -3.5
2019 98.4 135.4 101.5 -2.7
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -4.2 -10.6 1.6
2010/2009 1.8 10.0 1.1
2011/2010 3.8 5.6 -1.2
2012/2011 1.3 2.2 0.4
2013/2012 -0.6 2.6 0.3
2014/2013 4.1 3.6 1.7
201512014 -3.9 4.4 1.2
201612015 0.2 5.5 -0.2
201712016 -1.3 4.2 -1.3
2018/2017 -0.7 4.2 -0.5
201912018 -0.7 4.2 0.0
Notes: (a) Includes Missing Trader Intra-Community Fraud, (b) Balance
of payments basis, (c) A rise denotes a loss in UK competitiveness,
(d) Weighted by import shares in UK export markets, (e) Ratio of
average value of exports to imports.
Table A5. Household sector
Average Compen- Total Gross
(a) sation of personal disposable
earnings employees income income
2011=100 billion [pounds sterling],
current prices
2009 95.8 792.0 1299.7 999.8
2010 99.1 817.0 1358.0 1052.8
2011 100.0 827.8 1383.5 1067.9
2012 102.2 849.4 1424.2 1107.0
2013 104.2 875.9 1457.3 1129.8
2014 105.7 904.1 1492.4 1154.1
2015 107.1 937.7 1557.8 1205.8
2016 109.5 966.7 1613.7 1245.4
2017 112.7 1002.4 1684.6 1298.1
2018 116.3 1042.1 1768.6 1362.1
2019 119.9 1082.6 1856.8 1428.3
Percentage changes
2009/2008 1.9 -0.1 2.1 3.9
2010/2009 3.5 3.2 4.5 5.3
2011/2010 0.9 1.3 1.9 1.4
2012/2011 2.2 2.6 2.9 3.7
2013/2012 1.9 3.1 2.3 2.1
2014/2013 1.5 3.2 2.4 2.2
201512014 1.3 3.7 4.4 4.5
201612015 2.3 3.1 3.6 3.3
2017/2016 2.9 3.7 4.4 4.2
201812017 3.1 4.0 5.0 4.9
2019/2018 3.2 3.9 5.0 4.9
Final consumption
Real expenditure
disposable
income Total Durable
(b)
billion [pounds sterling],
2011 prices
2009 1079.2 1034.6 91.2
2010 1088.6 1038.3 89.3
2011 1067.9 1039.1 90.4
2012 1084.6 1050.8 96.9
2013 1086.1 1068.5 102.8
2014 1092.4 1094.9 111.1
2015 1143.8 1133.9 121.4
2016 1168.8 1166.8 127.0
2017 1195.3 1187.6 130.9
2018 1228.3 1210.5 135.1
2019 1262.3 1237.2 138.8
Percentage changes
2009/2008 2.3 -3.1 -2.4
2010/2009 0.9 0.4 -2.1
2011/2010 -1.9 0.1 1.3
2012/2011 1.6 1.1 7.2
2013/2012 0.1 1.7 6.1
2014/2013 0.6 2.5 8.0
201512014 4.7 3.6 9.3
201612015 2.2 2.9 4.6
2017/2016 2.3 1.8 3.1
201812017 2.8 1.9 3.2
2019/2018 2.8 2.2 2.7
Saving House Net
ratio prices (d) worth to
(c) income
ratio(e)
per cent 2011=100
2009 9.3 94.1 6.2
2010 11.0 101.0 6.3
2011 8.6 100.0 6.6
2012 8.0 101.6 6.8
2013 6.4 105.2 6.7
2014 5.9 115.8 7.4
2015 6.9 125.3 7.7
2016 6.4 129.1 7.6
2017 6.9 130.4 7.4
2018 7.9 131.4 7.2
2019 8.5 132.0 7.1
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -7.8
2010/2009 7.2
2011/2010 -1.0
2012/2011 1.6
2013/2012 3.5
2014/2013 10.0
201512014 8.3
201612015 3.1
2017/2016 1.0
201812017 0.8
2019/2018 0.5
Notes: (a) Average earnings equals total labour compensation divided
by the number of employees, (b) Deflated by consumers' expenditure
deflator, (c) Includes adjustment for change in net equity of
households in pension funds, (d) Office for National Statistics, mix-
adjusted, (e) Net worth is defined as housing wealth plus net
financial assets.
Table A6. Fixed investment and capital
billion [pounds sterling], 2011 prices
Gross fixed investment
Business Private General Total
investment housing government
(a)
2009 138.7 52.3 49.5 240.6
2010 143.7 60.5 50.6 254.9
2011 152.3 62.2 46.3 260.8
2012 158.7 60.2 43.7 262.7
2013 167.2 64.0 40.4 271.6
2014 179.7 69.8 43.3 292.8
20/5 187.0 73.0 44.5 304.4
20/6 198.3 80.9 45.4 324.6
2017 204.7 88.1 46.2 339.0
2018 209.2 94.8 46.8 350.8
2019 212.2 100.7 48.6 361.5
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -14.4 -31.6 12.6 -14.4
2010/2009 3.7 15.7 2.3 5.9
2011/2010 6.0 2.8 -8.5 2.3
2012/2011 4.2 -3.1 -5.5 0.7
2013/2012 5.3 6.2 -7.7 3.4
2014/2013 7.5 9.0 7.2 7.8
201512014 4.0 4.6 2.7 4.0
2016/2015 6.0 10.9 2.1 6.6
201712016 3.3 8.9 1.8 4.5
2018/2017 2.2 7.6 1.3 3.5
201912018 1.4 6.2 3.8 3.0
Capital stock
Corporate
User profit
cost of share of Private Public
capital (%) GDP (%) (b)
2009 15.8 24.7 2954.5 757.8
2010 15.7 24.1 2965.0 780.9
2011 15.3 25.0 2980.7 794.9
2012 13.3 24.6 3005.0 815.1
2013 12.4 24.9 3033.1 841.7
2014 13.8 24.9 3076.3 858.5
20/5 13.3 25.0 3126.6 876.0
20/6 13.6 25.6 3191.9 893.8
2017 14.0 26.0 3265.8 911.9
2018 14.4 26.6 3345.6 930.0
2019 14.7 27.4 3428.6 949.3
Percentage changes
2009/2008 0.0 4.3
2010/2009 0.4 3.0
2011/2010 0.5 1.8
2012/2011 0.8 2.5
2013/2012 0.9 3.3
2014/2013 1.4 2.0
201512014 1.6 2.0
2016/2015 2.1 2.0
201712016 2.3 2.0
2018/2017 2.4 2.0
201912018 2.5 2.1
Notes: (a) Includes private sector transfer costs of non-produced
assets, (b) Including public sector non-financial corporations.
Table A7. Productivity and the labour market Thousands
Employment
Employees Total (a)
2009 25092 29156
2010 25017 29229
2011 25117 29376
2012 25214 29697
2013 25516 30043
2014 25939 30726
2015 26565 31291
2016 26776 31529
2017 26978 31793
2018 27196 32074
2019 27387 32325
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -1.9 -1.6
2010/2009 -0.3 0.2
2011/2010 0.4 0.5
2012/2011 0.4 1.1
2013/2012 1.2 1.2
2014/2013 1.7 2.3
2015/2014 2.4 1.8
2016/2015 0.8 0.8
2017/2016 0.8 0.8
2018/2017 0.8 0.9
2019/2018 0.7 0.8
ILO Population
unemploy- Labour of
ment force (b) working
age
2009 2403 31559 38529
2010 2497 31725 38759
2011 2593 31969 39243
2012 2572 32268 39441
2013 2476 32519 39699
2014 2027 32753 39984
2015 1769 33060 40267
2016 1771 33300 40582
2017 1775 33567 40934
2018 1755 33828 41261
2019 1741 34066 41694
Percentage changes
2009/2008 34.5 0.5 0.5
2010/2009 3.9 0.5 0.6
2011/2010 3.8 0.8 1.2
2012/2011 -0.8 0.9 0.5
2013/2012 -3.7 0.8 0.7
2014/2013 -18.1 0.7 0.7
2015/2014 -12.7 0.9 0.7
2016/2015 0.1 0.7 0.8
2017/2016 0.2 0.8 0.9
2018/2017 -1.1 0.8 0.8
2019/2018 -0.8 0.7 1.1
Productivity Unemployment, %
(2011 = 100)
Claimant ILO unem-
Per hour Manufact- rate ployment
uring rate
2009 97.2 90.5 4.6 7.6
2010 98.7 97.9 4.6 7.9
2011 100.0 100.0 4.7 8.1
2012 98.8 98.3 4.8 8.0
2013 98.6 98.2 4.2 7.6
2014 98.7 99.7 3.1 6.2
2015 99.0 101.1 2.3 5.4
2016 100.6 104.4 2.4 5.3
2017 102.4 107.3 2.4 5.3
2018 104.3 110.4 2.3 5.2
2019 106.3 113.9 2.3 5.1
Percentage changes
2009/2008 -1.6 -2.7
2010/2009 1.5 8.2
2011/2010 1.3 2.2
2012/2011 -1.2 -1.7
2013/2012 -0.3 -0.2
2014/2013 0.1 1.5
2015/2014 0.3 1.4
2016/2015 1.6 3.3
2017/2016 1.8 2.8
2018/2017 1.8 2.9
2019/2018 1.9 3.2
Notes: (a) Includes self-employed, government-supported trainees and
unpaid family members, (b) Employment plus ILO unemployment.
Table A8. Public sector financial balance and borrowing requirement
billion [pounds sterling], fiscal years
2012-13 2013-14
Current Taxes on income 363.9 374.3
receipts: Taxes on expenditure 209.7 221.7
Other current receipts 21.1 23.7
Total 594.7 619.7
(as a % of GDP) 35.8 35.8
Current Goods and services 341.4 347.2
expenditure: Net social benefits paid 217.2 220.1
Debt interest 36.5 35.5
Other current expenditure 51.8 52.0
Total 646.9 654.7
(as a % of GDP) 38.9 37.8
Depreciation 32.8 33.9
Surplus on public sector -85.0 -68.9
current budget (a)
(as a % of GDP) -5.1 -4.0
Gross investment 68.4 60.2
Net investment 35.6 26.3
(as a % of GDP) 2.2 1.5
Total managed expenditure 715.3 714.9
(as a % of GDP) 43.0 41.3
Public sector net borrowing 120.5 95.2
(as a % of GDP) 7.3 5.5
Financial transactions 23.2 25.8
Public sector net cash requirement 97.4 69.4
(as a % of GDP) 5.9 4.0
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 77.4 79.8
GDP deflator at market prices 101.9 104.0
(2011 = 100)
Money GDP 1663.1 1732.8
Financial balance under -8.3 -5.7
Maastricht (% of GDP) (b)
Gross debt under Maastricht 85.8 87.3
(% of GDP) (b)
2014-15 2015-16
Current Taxes on income 387.7 402.9
receipts: Taxes on expenditure 229.9 237.2
Other current receipts 24.2 21.0
Total 641.7 661.1
(as a % of GDP) 35.5 35.3
Current Goods and services 353.1 353.6
expenditure: Net social benefits paid 225.9 226.4
Debt interest 35.1 35.1
Other current expenditure 51.3 57.0
Total 665.4 672.0
(as a % of GDP) 36.8 35.9
Depreciation 35.0 37.3
Surplus on public sector -58.7 -48.3
current budget (a)
(as a % of GDP) -3.3 -2.6
Gross investment 65.0 68.5
Net investment 30.0 31.2
(as a % of GDP) 1.7 1.7
Total managed expenditure 730.4 740.5
(as a % of GDP) 40.4 39.6
Public sector net borrowing 88.7 79.5
(as a % of GDP) 4.9 4.3
Financial transactions -0.5 11.8
Public sector net cash requirement 89.2 67.7
(as a % of GDP) 4.9 3.6
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 81.6 81.6
GDP deflator at market prices 105.5 106.5
(2011 = 100)
Money GDP 1807.2 1870.3
Financial balance under -5.7 --4.5
Maastricht (% of GDP) (b)
Gross debt under Maastricht 89.4 89.6
(% of GDP) (b)
2016-17 2017-18
Current Taxes on income 425.4 447.0
receipts: Taxes on expenditure 246.0 255.5
Other current receipts 20.6 20.4
Total 692.0 722.9
(as a % of GDP) 35.8 35.9
Current Goods and services 343.9 336.1
expenditure: Net social benefits paid 230.8 236.8
Debt interest 38.3 38.8
Other current expenditure 58.4 60.2
Total 671.4 671.9
(as a % of GDP) 34.8 33.4
Depreciation 39.5 41.5
Surplus on public sector -19.0 9.5
current budget (a)
(as a % of GDP) -1.0 0.5
Gross investment 69.3 70.4
Net investment 29.8 28.9
(as a % of GDP) 1.5 1.4
Total managed expenditure 740.8 742.3
(as a % of GDP) 38.4 36.9
Public sector net borrowing 48.8 19.4
(as a % of GDP) 2.5 1.0
Financial transactions -19.6 -15.3
Public sector net cash requirement 68.4 34.7
(as a % of GDP) 3.5 1.7
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 80.8 78.1
GDP deflator at market prices 107.5 109.2
(2011 = 100)
Money GDP 1931.6 2012.7
Financial balance under -3.0 -1.4
Maastricht (% of GDP) (b)
Gross debt under Maastricht 89.3 87.2
(% of GDP) (b)
2018-19 2019-20
Current Taxes on income 471.1 498.1
receipts: Taxes on expenditure 266.1 277.6
Other current receipts 20.3 21.2
Total 757.4 796.9
(as a % of GDP) 36.0 36.1
Current Goods and services 337.3 358.5
expenditure: Net social benefits paid 245.3 253.7
Debt interest 38.7 38.3
Other current expenditure 62.4 64.7
Total 683.6 715.2
(as a % of GDP) 32.5 32.4
Depreciation 43.5 45.5
Surplus on public sector 30.3 36.2
current budget (a)
(as a % of GDP) 1.4 1.6
Gross investment 71.8 74.6
Net investment 28.3 29.1
(as a % of GDP) 1.3 1.3
Total managed expenditure 755.4 789.8
(as a % of GDP) 35.9 35.8
Public sector net borrowing -2.0 -7.1
(as a % of GDP) -0.1 -0.3
Financial transactions -10.8 -12.4
Public sector net cash requirement 8.8 5.3
(as a % of GDP) 0.4 0.2
Public sector net debt (% of GDP) 74.9 71.7
GDP deflator at market prices 111.4 113.7
(2011 = 100)
Money GDP 2105.7 2205.4
Financial balance under -0.1 0.3
Maastricht (% of GDP) (b)
Gross debt under Maastricht 83.4 79.3
(% of GDP) (b)
Notes: These data are constructed from seasonally adjusted national
accounts data. This results In differences between the figures here
and unadjusted fiscal year data. Data exclude the impact of financial
sector Interventions, but include flows from the Asset Purchase
Facility of the Bank of England, (a) Public sector current budget
surplus Is total current receipts less total current expenditure and
depreciation, (b) Calendar year.
Table A9. Saving and investment As a percentage of GDP
Households Companies General government
Saving Invest- Saving Invest- Saving Invest-
ment ment ment
2009 6.6 3.9 11.3 8.0 -5.7 3.1
2010 7.9 4.3 11.4 9.1 -5.6 2.9
2011 6.0 4.5 12.8 9.3 -4.2 2.6
2012 5.6 4.5 11.6 9.6 -4.5 2.4
2013 4.4 4.7 10.9 10.3 -2.8 2.1
2014 4.1 5.0 10.7 10.6 -2.4 2.3
20/5 4.8 5.1 10.3 10.9 -1.7 2.2
20/6 4.4 5.6 9.9 11.3 -0.4 2.1
20/7 4.8 6.0 8.9 11.5 1.2 2.0
2018 5.6 6.3 8.3 11.5 2.4 2.0
2019 6.0 6.6 8.5 11.4 2.8 1.9
Whole economy Finance from abroad
(a)
Net
Saving Invest- Total Net factor national
ment income saving
2009 12.1 14.9 2.8 -0.1 -1.6
2010 13.7 16.3 2.6 -1.1 0.4
2011 14.7 16.4 1.7 -1.2 1.5
2012 12.8 16.5 3.7 0.3 -0.5
2013 12.6 17.0 4.5 0.9 -0.7
2014 12.4 17.8 5.5 2.1 -0.9
20/5 13.4 18.1 4.7 1.5 0.1
20/6 13.9 19.0 5.0 1.5 0.6
20/7 14.9 19.5 4.6 1.3 1.7
2018 16.2 19.8 3.5 0.8 3.0
2019 17.2 19.9 2.7 0.3 3.9
Notes: Saving and investment data are gross of depreciation unless
otherwise stated, (a) Negative sign indicates a surplus for the UK.
Table A10. Medium and long-term projections
All figures percentage change unless otherwise stated
2011 2012 2013 2014
GDP (market prices) 1.6 0.7 1.7 2.8
Average earnings 0.9 2.2 1.9 1.5
GDP deflator (market prices) 2.1 1.7 1.8 1.7
Consumer Prices Index 4.5 2.8 2.6 1.4
Per capita GDP 0.8 0.0 1.0 2.1
Whole economy productivity (a) 1.3 -1.2 -0.3 0.1
Labour input (b) 0.4 1.9 1.8 2.7
ILO unemployment rate (%) 8.1 8.0 7.6 6.2
Current account (% of GDP) -1.7 -3.7 -4.5 -5.5
Total managed expenditure
(% of GDP) 43.7 43.9 41.1 40.6
Public sector net borrowing
(% of GDP) 7.5 8.1 5.3 5.2
Public sector net debt 70.6 74.6 78.3 80.6
(% of GDP)
Effective exchange rate
(2011 = 100) 100.0 104.2 102.9 111.0
Bank Rate (%) 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
3 month interest rates (%) 0.9 0.8 0.5 0.5
10 year interest rates (%) 3.1 1.8 2.4 2.5
2015 2016 2017
GDP (market prices) 2.5 2.4 2.5
Average earnings 1.3 2.3 2.9
GDP deflator (market prices) 0.9 0.9 1.4
Consumer Prices Index -0.1 1.0 1.9
Per capita GDP 1.8 1.7 1.8
Whole economy productivity (a) 0.3 1.6 1.8
Labour input (b) 2.0 0.7 0.8
ILO unemployment rate (%) 5.4 5.3 5.3
Current account (% of GDP) -4.7 -5.0 -4.6
Total managed expenditure
(% of GDP) 39.9 38.7 37.2
Public sector net borrowing
(% of GDP) 4.4 3.0 1.3
Public sector net debt 81.4 81.5 79.8
(% of GDP)
Effective exchange rate
(2011 = 100) 115.8 116.1 116.2
Bank Rate (%) 0.5 0.8 1.3
3 month interest rates (%) 0.6 1.0 1.5
10 year interest rates (%) 1.7 2.3 2.8
2018 2019 2020-24
GDP (market prices) 2.6 2.6 2.5
Average earnings 3.1 3.2 3.4
GDP deflator (market prices) 1.9 2.0 2.1
Consumer Prices Index 2.1 2.0 2.1
Per capita GDP 1.9 2.0 1.9
Whole economy productivity (a) 1.8 1.9 2.1
Labour input (b) 0.8 0.7 0.4
ILO unemployment rate (%) 5.2 5.1 5.2
Current account (% of GDP) -3.5 -2.7 -2.0
Total managed expenditure
(% of GDP) 36.0 35.8 36.4
Public sector net borrowing
(% of GDP) 0.1 -0.3 0.2
Public sector net debt 76.9 73.7 64.5
(% of GDP)
Effective exchange rate
(2011 = 100) 116.4 116.6 116.7
Bank Rate (%) 1.8 2.2 3.3
3 month interest rates (%) 2.0 2.4 3.5
10 year interest rates (%) 3.2 3.5 4.0
Notes: (a) Per hour, (b) Total hours worked.
REFERENCES
Banerjee, R., Kearns, J. and Lombardi, M. (2015), '(Why) Is
investment growth weak?', BIS Quarterly Review, March, pp. 67-82.
Barnett, A., Batten, S., Chiu, A., Franklin, J. and
Sebastia-Barriel, M. (2014),'The UK productivity puzzle', Bonk
of England Quarterly Bulletin, 2014 Q2, pp. 114-127.
Carney, M. (2014), Speech given at the Trades Union Congress,
Liverpool.
Department for Communities and Local Government, House Building:
March Quarter 2012, England, https://www.gov.uk/government/
uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/6834/2145660.pdf.
Kirby, S. (2015).'The macroeconomic implications of the
parties' fiscal plans', National Institute Economic Review,
231, pp. F4-11.
Kirby, S. and Meaning, J. (2014),'Exchange rate pass-through:
a view from a global structural model', National Institute Economic
Review, 230, pp. F59-64.
--(2015),'Oil prices and economic activity', National
Institute Economic Review, 231, pp. F43-8.
ONS (2014), Pink Book.
NOTE
(1) For instance, while prices in the UK. were flat over this
period, in our main trading partner, the Euro Area, prices contracted
0.1 per cent.
Simon Kirby * with Oriol Carreras **, Jack Meaning **, Rebecca
Piggott ** and James Warren **
The production of this forecast is supported by the
Institute's Corporate Members: Bank of England, HM Treasury, Mizuho
Research Institute Ltd, Office for National Statistics, Santander (UK)
pic and by the members of the NiGEM users group.
* NIESR and Centre For Macroeconomics. E-mail: s.kirby@niesr.ac.uk.
** NIESR. Thanks to Jonathan Portes for helpful comments and
suggestions. Unless otherwise stated, the source of all data reported in
the figures and tables is the NiGEM database and forecast baseline. The
UK forecast was completed on 28 April 2015.
Table 1. Summary of the forecast
Percentage change
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
GDP 1.6 0.7 1.7 2.8 2.5
Per capita GDP 0.8 0.0 1.0 2.1 1.8
CPI Inflation 4.5 2.8 2.6 1.4 -0.1
RPIX Inflation 5.3 3.2 3.1 2.4 0.9
RPDI -1.9 1.6 0.1 0.6 4.7
Unemployment, % 8.1 8.0 7.6 6.2 5.4
Bank Rate, % 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
Long Rates, % 3.1 1.8 2.4 2.5 1.7
Effective exchange rate -0.1 4.2 -1.2 7.9 4.3
Current account as % of GDP -1.7 -3.7 -4.5 -5.5 -4.7
PSNB as % of GDP (a) 7.5 7.3 5.5 4.9 4.3
PSND as % of GDP (a) 72.3 77.4 79.8 81.6 81.6
2016 2017 2018 2019
GDP 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.6
Per capita GDP 1.7 1.8 1.9 2.0
CPI Inflation 1.0 1.9 2.1 2.0
RPIX Inflation 1.7 2.4 2.6 2.5
RPDI 2.2 2.3 2.8 2.8
Unemployment, % 5.3 5.3 5.2 5.1
Bank Rate, % 0.8 1.3 1.8 2.2
Long Rates, % 2.3 2.8 3.2 3.5
Effective exchange rate 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.2
Current account as % of GDP -5.0 -4.6 -3.5 -2.7
PSNB as % of GDP (a) 2.5 1.0 -0.1 -0.3
PSND as % of GDP (a) 80.8 78.1 74.9 71.7
Notes: RPDI is real personal disposable income. PSNB is public sector
net borrowing. PSND is public sector net debt, (a) Fiscal year,
excludes the impact of financial sector interventions, but includes
the flows from the Asset Purchase Facility of the Bank of England.