The economics of Scottish independence: introduction.
Armstrong, Angus ; Ebell, Monique
On September 18th 2014 the people of Scotland will choose whether
to remain part of the United Kingdom or to become an independent
country. If Scotland becomes an independent country this would bring to
a close one of the longest serving and most successful economic and
political unions in the modern era. The process of Scottish devolution
began in 1997, with the creation of the Scottish Parliament and
Executive, and has been followed by more devolution of powers up to the
Scotland Act 2012. Independence would be a fundamental and historic
change. On the one hand it offers an opportunity for the Scottish
government to choose its own economic, social and political framework.
On the other, Scotland would no longer automatically be an integral part
of risk-sharing arrangements within the UK, including monetary
arrangements, welfare and pension provisions and defence.
The outcome of the referendum could also have important
consequences for the rest of the UK and indeed the world. The political
balance of power in the rest of the UK would change decisively with the
loss of the 59 Scottish MPs in Westminster, a majority of which have
been Labour in recent decades. (1) This could lead to a rightward shift
in the UK political balance, with consequences for all areas of policy.
Even setting that political shift aside, the mere mechanics of Scottish
independence will have an important impact on the UK. The UK will be
left with a significantly higher public debt to GDP ratio, with gross
debt to GDP possibly exceeding 100 per cent. Both the UK and Scotland
might feel the impact of higher transactions costs on trade, as
regulations gradually diverge. The political influence of the rest of
the UK in Europe and other international forums is also likely to
change.
The consequences of the referendum may have ramifications well
beyond these isles. The Scottish government has made clear that an
independent Scotland would no longer house the UK's nuclear
weapons. Finding a new base would have significant costs which may lead
to a reappraisal of the current policy with implications for other
members of the North Atlantic Treaty Organisation. For all the fluidity
of international borders and a near tripling of the number of
independent states in the past sixty years, there are few examples of
cordial separations which have not followed the end of colonialism or
communism. If an important region within the European Union can secede
from a sovereign state with ongoing membership to the international
community, this would set an interesting precedent for other regions
such as Catalunya, the Basque Country or Flanders. The settlement
between the UK and an independent Scotland would be particularly
important in terms of setting a precedent for the separation of highly
indebted countries.
Given the long lasting and far reaching consequences of the
referendum, the Scottish and UK governments recognise the importance of
making impartial information and analysis on key issues available to
voters. Both governments support the particular role of the Economic and
Social Research Council (ESRC) in funding independent research on
Scottish independence and in assisting in planning for whichever outcome
prevails. Three of the six articles in this Review are co-authored by
ESRC Senior Scottish Fellows (Angus Armstrong, David Bell and Michael
Keating) and four articles are co-authored by members of the ESRC's
Scottish Centre on Constitutional Change (Angus Armstrong, David Bell,
Katerina Lisenkova and Michael Keating). We are grateful for this
support and the opportunity to contribute to the debate on Scottish
independence.
The first paper, 'Scotland's economic performance and the
fiscal implications of moving to independence', by John McLaren and
Jo Armstrong of Glasgow University's Centre for Public Policy for
Regions, provides an overview of the economic position of Scotland as it
approaches the referendum, and examines how its fiscal position might
evolve over the coming years and decades. One important focus is on
different measures of aggregate income, Gross Domestic Product versus
Gross National Income, and their implications for assessing living
standards and the tax base available to an independent Scotland. Another
important distinction is real versus cash terms measures of aggregate
income, which are especially important due to volatility in the oil
price. The authors go on to assess the impact of competing forecasts on
future oil production and revenues for an independent Scotland's
medium- and long-term fiscal position.
Next, Angus Armstrong and Monique Ebell of the National Institute
of Economic and Social Research contribute an article entitled,
'Scotland: currency options and public debt', in which they
examine the implications of the level of public debt that Scotland might
expect to inherit at independence for its optimal currency choice.
Armstrong and Ebell argue that, at high levels of government debt, a
monetary union with the UK would restrict Scotland's capacity to
adjust. Only being able to use fiscal policy would limit its degrees of
policy freedom to manoeuvre in adverse economic circumstances. An
independent Scotland would always retain the sovereignty to change its
currency and fiscal arrangements in the future. This makes agreeing and
implementing fiscal constraints which bind in all circumstances
difficult to achieve. It may also mean that investors question the
commitment of the government to remain within the union when a
significant economic shock hits.
The next three papers are all concerned with the long-run aspects
of Scottish independence, in particular with the affordability of
pensions and the impact of demographics. David Bell, David Comerford and
David Eiser lead off with their piece on 'Funding pensions in
Scotland: would independence matter?', which considers the costs to
providing state and public sector pensions in an independent Scotland.
They note that the lower cost of financing pensions in Scotland due to
lower further life expectancy makes providing pensions in Scotland less
expensive per retiree, but that higher dependency ratios (2) work
against this when pension affordability is assessed in terms of the cost
per working adult. They also examine the distributional implications in
the case that government debt carries higher interest rates for an
independent Scotland. Pensioners would benefit from the higher interest
rates, but at the expense of higher taxes for younger cohorts of
taxpayers due to higher costs of debt service.
Katerina Lisenkova of the National Institute of Economic and Social
Research and Marcel Merette of the University of Ottawa examine the
affordability of pensions in their article entitled, 'Can an ageing
Scotland afford independence?'. They address this question using a
dynamic multi-regional overlapping generations model spanning Scotland,
the rest of the UK and the rest of the world, which differentiates two
cases: under independence, Scotland would finance its pensions alone,
while as part of the UK pensions would be funded jointly. Lisenkova and
Merette find that Scotland would be slightly worse off under
independence, but that this difference is small compared to the effects
of ageing on both economies.
Next, Rowena Crawford and Gemma Tetlow, both of the Institute for
Fiscal Studies, present their work on 'Fiscal challenges and
opportunities for an independent Scotland'. They first examine how
public spending and revenues differ between Scotland and the UK average,
before presenting a detailed national transfer accounts analysis of how
Scotland's fiscal position might evolve in the next 50 years if
current policies were maintained. Crawford and Tetlow project that if
Scotland targets a debt to GDP ratio of 60 per cent by 2062-3, it would
have a fiscal gap of between 1.5 and 5.9 per cent of GDP, compared to a
fiscal gap of 0.4 per cent for the UK. They conclude that Scotland would
either need to rein in its current spending levels, or increase taxes,
in order to fund this gap.
Finally, Michael Keating and Malcolm Harvey of the University of
Aberdeen conclude this special issue with their work on 'The
political economy of small states: and the lessons for Scotland'.
This provides some fundamental analysis on the different political
models that an independent Scotland might choose. It distinguishes
between the market competition state, similar to Ireland or the Baltics,
and the social investment state model favoured by the Nordic countries,
as well as discussing corporatist models. This work begins to map out
the alternative social and economic models which would be available to
an independent Scotland. Keating and Harvey conclude by examining which
of these models fits most closely to Scotland.
NOTES
(1) Of the 59 Scottish MPs in the UK Parliament, 41 are members of
the Scottish Labour Party against a single Conservative, while II are
Liberal Democrats, and 6 belong to the Scottish National Party. This
would imply a loss of about 15 per cent of Labour's 257 MPs in the
current parliament, while the Liberal Democrats would lose 19 per cent
of their 57 sitting MPs.
(2) The dependency ratio is the ratio between pensioners and the
working population.