Labour markets in the global financial crisis: the good, the bad and the ugly.
Daly, Mary C. ; Fernald, John G. ; Jorda, Oscar 等
I. Introduction
The impact of the global financial crisis on labour markets varied
widely from country to country. For example, in the United States, the
unemployment rate at its highest level was about five percentage points
above its pre-recession level. The rate rose much less in the United
Kingdom and barely changed in Germany--despite larger declines in gross
domestic product.
In this note, we summarise a few key cross-country differences
using the perspective of Okun's Law. Okun's Law, the reduced
form empirical relationship between changes in the unemployment rate and
changes in output growth, provides a natural measure of how labour
markets in different countries responded to the large, arguably common,
global financial shock. It also provides an organising framework for
discussing these differences.
We find that, after the 1970s but prior to the Great Recession, the
relationship between output and the unemployment rate became more
homogenous across countries. These changes presumably reflected
institutional and technological changes. But, at least in the short
term, the global financial crisis undid much of this convergence, in
part because the affected countries adopted different labour market
policies in response to the global demand shock.
We then decompose the Okun relationship using a simple output
identity, that output growth is the sum of growth in workers, hours per
worker, and productivity. This identity suggests some potential reasons
for the changes during and since the financial crisis. For almost all
countries, increases in the unemployment rate were associated with
larger declines--in some cases, substantially larger--in hours per
worker in the crisis period than the pre-crisis period. The experiences
in the US, UK and Germany offer three contrasting lessons about this
process of adjustment.
2. Interpreting Okun's Law
Arthur Okun (1962) observed half a century ago that changes in the
unemployment rate have a consistent and predictable relationship with
changes in real gross domestic product (GDP). Since then, what is now
called 'Okun's Law' has become a standard rule of thumb
used by monetary policymakers and economic forecasters. (1)
Okun's Law is estimated in different ways in the literature.
Okun estimated the relationship in growth rates, but it is often
estimated in levels (relating output and unemployment 'gaps').
And, since it's a reduced-form relationship, either the
unemployment rate or output can be put on the left-hand side. In what
follows, we focus on the following relationship between output growth
and the change in the unemployment rate:
[DELTA][y.sub.t] = [alpha] + [beta][DELTA][U.sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t] (i)
Lower case variables are logs of upper case (level) variables and A
is the four-quarter change. So [DELTA][y.sub.t] is the 4-quarter
log-change in real output, and [DELTA][U.sub.t] is the 4-quarter change
in the rate of unemployment.
Daly et al. (2013a) discuss the merits of estimating the
relationship in the form of (1), from the perspective of growth
accounting. Loosely speaking, a 1 percentage point change in the
unemployment rate leads to a direct 1 per cent reduction in the number
of workers. From the production function, a 1 per cent reduction in
labour input should lead to about a 2/3 per cent reduction in output,
where 2/3 is labour's (approximate) share. A coefficient of [beta]
that is substantially greater than 2/3 in absolute value reflects other
margins that adjust at the same time and, hence, are correlated with
changes in the unemployment rate. In terms of the number of workers,
these margins include labour-force participation, immigration, and
multiple job holders. As we discuss further below, other margins include
variations in hours per worker or imply cyclical movements in
productivity. (2)
We will refer to [beta] as Okun's 'coefficient'. In
the data, this coefficient is always negative, indicating that increases
in the unemployment rate are associated with slower-than-usual growth in
output. The discussion in the previous paragraph makes clear that this
negative relationship is hardly surprising. We expect a higher
unemployment rate to be associated with lower hours worked which, other
things equal, means less output.
Research has found that estimates of the Okun's Law
relationship vary markedly across countries (e.g., IMF, 2010; Gordon,
2011). We discuss cross-country estimates in Sections 3 and 4. The
association between changes in the unemployment rate, hours worked, and
productivity should depend on institutional, industrial, and other
relations that affect how businesses and households adjust to shocks.
IMF (2010) provides a detailed discussion of policies that affect these
relations and, thereby, Okun's Law. Thus, the Okun coefficient
provides a convenient, quantitative summary of how these institutional
and other differences affect cyclical adjustment. Moreover, given the
major shock of the global financial crisis, it provides a lens on the
different sources of adjustment used in different countries.
We make use of the following identity to look at Okun's Law in
more detail:
[DELTA][y.sub.t], [equivalent to] [DELTA][n.sub.t] +
([DELTA][h.sub.t] - [DELTA][n.sub.t]) + ([DELTA][y.sub.t]-
[DELTA][h.sub.t]) (2)
[DELTA][n.sub.t] is the 4-quarter (log) change in total employment,
([DELTA][h.sub.t] - [DELTA][n.sub.t]) is the 4-quarter (log) change in
hours per worker, and ([DELTA][y.sub.t] - [DELTA][h.sub.t]) is the
4-quarter (log) change in labour productivity.
This identity focuses on three levers businesses might use to
adjust output in response to a decline in demand: the number of workers
they employ, the number of hours each employee works, and (possibly as a
residual) their rate of productivity. When demand changes, the use of
these levers is likely to depend on a range of factors. These include
labour laws and contracts that affect an employer's ability to lay
off workers or change hours, as well as the bargaining environment. They
are also likely to depend on the persistence of shocks to demand. For
example, businesses are more likely to adjust the number of employees if
the drop in demand is viewed as permanent. In contrast, for temporary
shocks, they might 'hoard labour' to have it ready for the
eventual recovery. Productivity changes in response to a change in
demand can be a residual, to the extent firms cannot or choose not to
adjust total hours commensurate with changes in demand--perhaps
reflecting labour hoarding. Productivity changes may also be intentional
if, for example, competitive pressures create incentives to raise
productivity and lower production costs.
Some responses to a downturn in demand might be captured only
indirectly. For example, depending on the institutional environment,
firms may be able to cut wages, reduce costs on other production
factors, and/or squeeze their profit margins. These choices are likely
to influence the adjustments made in the output identity (2). And
general equilibrium effects might matter. For example, the monetary or
fiscal policy reaction function may affect the persistence of a downturn
in demand, thereby affecting the choice of margins by a firm. In the
context of all of these factors, equation (2) nevertheless summarises
how businesses adapt to changes in demand.
These changes, in turn, have implications for Okun's Law.
Specifically, we can project each of the terms in (2) on changes in
unemployment:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
By construction, the Okun coefficient [??] is the sum of the three
coefficients from (3):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Thus, the estimates in (3) give us a lens to discuss why
Okun's coefficient might be changing across countries.
3. Pre-crisis, advanced economies gradually looking more alike
Since the 1970s, several broad developments have affected labour
markets and may have changed the cyclical relationship between the
unemployment rate and changes in output. In many countries, labour
markets have become more flexible and the power of unions has waned.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Those might reduce the importance of labour hoarding (e.g., Gali and van Rens, 2014). From the mid-1980s to the mid-2000s, economies
across the world experienced a simultaneous decline in the volatility of
output and a reduction in inflation, a period known as the Great
Moderation. Whether the decline in volatility reflected good policy or
good luck (low variance of shocks), it would presumably affect
incentives to hoard labour. The cyclical link between changes in the
unemployment rate and changes in employment depend, in part, on the
cyclical response of labour-force participation. Female labour force
participation in advanced economies had surged since the 1960s, but
began to stabilise in the mid-1990s and then declined; that might have
influenced the responsiveness of the participation margin over the
business cycle. Meanwhile, in the past ten years, aging populations in
advanced economies have driven broader declines in overall participation
rates. (3) For these and possibly other reasons, Okun's Law is
likely to evolve over time.
Figure 1 shows how the distribution of Okun coefficients has
evolved across fifteen OECD economies over time, based on equation (1).
Country by country, it estimates equation (1) as a simple OLS regression
of the 4-quarter (log) change in real GDP on the 4-quarter change in
unemployment, using rolling windows of 40 quarters. (See the appendix
for details on the data.) The figure shows the end dates of the rolling
windows, which range from 1979Q4-2013Q1.
Each estimated [beta] shows how much output tends to change,
relative to trend, for each 1 percentage point increase in the
unemployment rate. The figure displays the average value of this
relation across the fifteen countries. The figure also depicts the
dispersion of the Okun relation across countries by plotting the
relation for the bottom and top quarter of countries in the sample,
denoted 25th and 75th percentile respectively.
Early in the sample, before the Great Moderation, the Okun relation
in the typical country was large. A 1 percentage point increase in the
unemployment rate was typically associated with nearly a 3 percentage
point decline in output growth. This suggests that countries were
substantially relying on margins other than unemployment to adjust
production to shocks. But around that average value, countries differed
greatly as shown by the interquartile range.
Starting with samples ending in the mid-1980s, the average Okun
coefficient fell sharply. During the 1990s and early 2000s, the
coefficient gradually declined further to nearly one-to-one at its
lowest point. And differences across countries narrowed considerably. A
simple standard deviation across estimated Okun's coefficients
confirms these patterns, with a substantial decline in its value between
1980 and 2005.
Several factors may contribute to explaining the decline in the
Okun relation before 2007, including globalisation, greater labour
mobility, and overall liberalisation of employee-employer relations. In
addition, over the past decade, employment protection has declined, a
feature visible in regulatory changes concerning individual and
collective job dismissals (see, e.g. OECD, 2013). These factors have
generally increased labour- and product-market flexibility. As a result,
when output changed, more of the adjustment took place through
employment, which in turn showed up in the unemployment rate.
Then came the global financial crisis. Data since 2007 indicate
that the Okun relation rose to levels last seen in the 1980s. Countries
adopted different policies during and after the crisis, reflecting
institutional or philosophical differences; in the next section, we
discuss a few of these policies. Of course, the figure to some extent
could also reflect institutional differences across countries that were
relatively unimportant for Okun's Law in the decade or so prior to
the crisis, but then those differences became important in response to
the financial shock. As a reduced-form relationship, Okun's Law
could depend on the source of the shocks hitting the economy. (4) In any
event, as output fell, some of these policies prevented unemployment
from rising as sharply as it typically did before the crisis. In
addition to the rise in the Okun coefficient, the different approaches
countries took increased the dispersion in the Okun relation as shown by
the widening in the interquartile range. The next section discusses some
of those differences.
Some previous literature has also explored whether Okun's Law
has changed over time. For example, IMF (2010) uses rolling regressions
and reports changes in several countries. However, they do not
explicitly compare the coefficients across countries as in figure 1,
and, below, we implement a different decomposition to understand these
changes. In contrast, Ball, Leigh and Loungani (2013) argue that
Okun's Law is remarkably stable within countries over time.
However, they begin their analysis a decade after we do (with data that
start in 1980, and simply compare 1980-95 with 1995-2011. In figure 1,
this corresponds to windows from 1990-2011. Up until the last few years
of the sample, it's not clear that one should find large changes
across subsamples.
4. The Great Recession: The Great Divergence?
The global financial crisis both raised the average 15-country Okun
coefficient and increased its cross-country variability. Did these
changes reflect a reversal of the factors behind the pre-2007 declines?
To understand better what happened following the global financial
crisis, we break down the estimate of the Okun coefficient into three
parts using equation (3). Those regressions decompose the coefficient
into the parts relating changes in output to movements in total
employment, in hours per worker, and in labour productivity. Decomposing
the Okun coefficient into these three factors helps clarify the
differences across countries. Although we show more countries, for
concreteness we focus the discussion on the United States, Great
Britain, and Germany.
To begin, figure 2 shows individual Okun coefficients for the
fifteen countries in our sample. The red bars show the pre-crisis period
from 1996Q1-2006Q4. Consistent with figure 1, those bars hover around -1
with a range from about -1 1/2 Vi to - 1/2. The black dots show the
coefficients estimated over the period of the global financial crisis,
from 2007Q1-2013Q1. In all but two cases (the United States and New
Zealand), the coefficient is more negative in the crisis period. In
several cases, including the UK and Germany, the coefficient is much
more negative in the crisis period.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Figures 3-5 decompose the bars in figure 2 into the responses of
each of the three factors from equation (3), namely [[??].sup.emp],
[[??].sup.hours] and [[??].sup.LP]. Not surprisingly, perhaps, figure 3
shows that the magnitude of the Okun coefficient--indeed, its systematic
negative sign--is mostly a result of the total employment component. In
both the pre-crisis and later periods, a 1 percentage point increase in
the unemployment rate is typically associated with a decline of about 1
percentage point or more in a country's employment rate. Such a
relationship is intuitively obvious, but variations in such factors as
labour force participation and immigration mean that the association
need not be one-to-one in practice. Daly et al. (2013a) discuss the
quantitative importance of some of these margins in the US case.
Figures 4 and 5 show that hours per worker and productivity
contribute to the Okun relation, but prior to the Great Recession were
less quantitatively important. Indeed, even the sign varied across
countries. In the United States, hours per worker are procyclical--they
tend to fall in a downturn, when unemployment rises. In others,
including France, Germany, and Italy, hours per worker prior to the
Great Recession tended to rise in a downturn, suggesting that the
employed workforce was used more intensively. In terms of productivity,
some recent literature has discussed the apparent change in the
cyclicality of US productivity, from procyclical (a negative
[[??].sup.LP]) to countercyclical (a positive coefficient). (5) Figure 5
shows that the US was not alone in having countercyclical productivity
since the mid-1990s. In contrast, in France, Germany, Italy, and several
other countries, productivity tended to fall substantially when the
unemployment rate rose.
During and since the Great Recession, countries have adjusted all
three factors, but have placed different emphasis on them. The US
adjustment was largely in line with its pre-recession experience.
Increases in unemployment were associated with reductions in employment,
falling hours per worker, and slightly higher productivity. The
coefficients change little relative to the pre-recession period.
Across countries, figure 4 shows that a major difference in the
post-2006 period is the use of the hours-per-worker margin. When
unemployment rose, all countries reduced hours per worker, in some cases
substantially. The productivity and employment responses varied less
systematically across countries before and after the crisis.
Looking specifically at the United Kingdom, the declines in
employment, hours, and productivity were all larger than in the
pre-recession period. Compared with the US, the main difference was that
the UK adjusted productivity far more, with a larger increase (in
absolute value) of [[??].sup.LP] In Germany, the pre-and-post-crisis
responses were particularly different. Both hours per worker and
productivity fell much more following the crisis, explaining why Germany
saw big output changes during the crisis and recovery period with
relatively little change in the unemployment rate. This partly reflects
Germany's widespread adoption of procedures that permitted
employers to adjust worker hours easily (Burda and Hunt, 2011).
Germany, the United Kingdom, and the United States are good
examples of three ways businesses in advanced economies responded to the
global financial crisis. In Germany, the pattern reflects explicit
policy decisions. In other countries, the reasons for the differences
are less clear. For example, it may reflect different social models in
the UK and the US about retaining jobs versus retaining wages. (6) And
of course, productivity growth in the UK has been puzzlingly weak since
the crisis began (see, e.g., the discussion in Bean, 2014). In all
cases, the differences among countries in the methods businesses used to
adjust output are directly reflected in the path of each country's
unemployment rate.
5. Conclusion
The global financial crisis reversed the steady cross-country
convergence of the Okun relation observed since the 1970s. This is not
explained by a reversal of secular trends in labour markets. Rather, it
reflects how countries responded to the crisis. Differences in the
institutional framework in possible combination with government policy
responses to the crisis led some countries to emphasise shrinking the
workforce, others to reducing hours per worker, and still others to
letting labour productivity adjust. These differences in emphasis
probably contributed to divergent paths of recovery from the crisis;
future work can help deepen our understanding of the key differences.
Given the financial roots of the crisis, one policy response has
been to re-evaluate financial market regulation. The results in this
note point to a similar reflection--that events of recent years should
lead to a consideration of how labour-market institutions can be
improved.
Data Appendix
The data for figure 1 consists of a balanced panel of fifteen
countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland,
France, Italy, Germany, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden, United
Kingdom, and the United States. All data are quarterly. Figure 1 uses
data running from the first quarter of 1970 to the first quarter of
2013.
Real GDP, the unemployment rate, hours per worker, and total number
of workers are obtained from the OECD. To construct productivity as GDP
per hour, we construct total hours as the product of hours per worker
and the total number of employees.
For all series except unemployment, all growth rates are 100 times
the 4-quarter change in logs. The unemployment rate enters all
regression as a simple 4-quarter change.
REFERENCES
Ball, L.M., Leigh, D. and Loungani, P. (2013), 'Okun's
Law: fit at fifty?', NBER Working Paper No. 18668, January.
Basu, S. and Fernald, J. (2001), 'Why is productivity
procyclical? Why do we care?', NBER chapters in New Developments in
Productivity Analysis, pp. 225-302, National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Bean, C. (2014), 'Sustaining the recovery', speech given
to the North East Chamber of Commerce President's Club Talk,
Rockcliffe Hall Hotel, Darlington, 10 March.
Bernanke, B.S. (2012), 'Recent developments in the labor
market', National Association for Business Economics Annual
Conference, Washington D.C., 26 March, available at http://www.
federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20120326a. htm.
Burda, M. and Hunt, J. (201 I), 'What explains the German
labor market miracle in the Great Recession?', Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity.
Congressional Budget Office (2014), Revisions to CBO's
Projection of Potential Output Since 2007, The Congress of the United
States, Congressional Budget Office, February, available at http://www.
cbo.gov/publication/45012.
Daly, M.C., Fernald, J.G.,Jorda, 6. and Nechio, F. (2013a),
'Okun's Macroscope and the changing cyclicality of underlying
margins of adjustment', FRBSF Working Paper 2013-32.
--(2013b), 'Labor markets in the global financial
crisis', FRBSF Economic Letter, 23 December, available at
http://www.frbsf. org/economic-research/publications/economic-letter/20131 december/labour-market-global-financial-crisis-okun-law/.
Elsby, M.W.L., Shin, D. and Solon, G. (2014), 'Wage adjustment
in the Great Recession', in The Labour Market in the Aftermath of
the Great Recession, University of Chicago Press, Journal of Labour
Economics.
Gall, J. and van Rens, T. (2014), 'The vanishing
procyclicality of labor productivity', manuscript, January.
Gordon, R.J. (2011), 'The evolution of Okun's Law and of
cyclical productivity fluctuations in the United States and in the
EU-15', presented at EES/IAB workshop, Labor Market Institutions
and the Macroeconomic, Nuremberg, 17-18 June.
Knotek, E.S. (2007), 'How useful is Okun's Law?',
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas Economic Review, pp. 73-103.
IMF (2010), 'Unemployment dynamics in recessions and
recoveries', World Economic Outlook, Chapter 3, April.
Okun, A.M. (1962), 'Potential GNP: its measurement and
significance', Proceedings of the Business and Economics Statistics
Section of the American Statistical Association, pp. 98-104.
OECD (2013), 'Protecting jobs, enhancing flexibility: a new
look at employment protection legislation', OECD Employment Outlook
2013, OECD Publishing.
NOTES
(1) See, for example, Bernanke (2012) and Congressional Budget
Office (2014). Knotek (2007) and Ball, Leigh and Loungani (2013) provide
references to the substantial literature.
(2) Basu and Fernald (2001) and Gali and van Rens (2014) discuss
the literature on cyclical productivity.
(3) Movements in labour-force participation may have a cyclical
dimension that influences the relationship between changes in
unemployment and changes in the number of people working. For example,
in the Great Recession, some older people who lose jobs may decide to
retire--and cease to be counted as unemployed.
(4) Daly et al. (2013a) discuss conditional estimates of
Okun's Law for the United States.
(5) See Gali and van Rens (2014) for references. Daly et al.
(2013a) discuss the changing |3 LF coefficient in the US context.
(6) For example, Elsby et al. (2014) find much more procyclicality
of real wages in the UK than in the US during the Great Recession.
Mary C. Daly, John G. Fernald, Oscar Jorda, and Fernanda Nechio *
* Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. E-mail:
john.fernald@sf.frb.org. This paper is a somewhat extended version of
Daly et al. (2013b). We thank Bart Hobijn, Dawn Holland, Simon Kirby,
Ron Smith and Garry Young and participants at the Bank of England for
helpful comments.