Long-term growth in Europe: what difference does the crisis make?
Crafts, Nicholas
OECD projections for European countries imply that the crisis will
have no long-term effect on trend growth. An historical perspective says
this is too optimistic. Not only is the legacy of public debt and its
requirement for fiscal consolidation unfavourable but the experience of
the 1930s suggests that much needed supply-side reforms are now less
probable--indeed policy may well become less growth friendly. Whereas
the 1940s saw the Bretton Woods agreement and the Marshall Plan pave the
way for the 'Golden Age', it is unlikely that anything similar
will rescue Europe this time around.
Keywords: Financial crisis; fiscal consolidation; growth
projections; Marshall Plan; productivity growth; supply-side reform
JEL Classifications: N14; 052
Introduction
About the turn of the century it became conventional wisdom that
economic growth in western European countries was a bit disappointing
and that a rapid decline in Europe's share of world GDP was
underway. Nevertheless, there seemed no reason to doubt the plausibility
of a scenario of 'business as usual' underpinned by gradual
structural reform delivering growth at around 2 per cent per year for
the foreseeable future.
Obviously, the financial crisis which erupted in 2008 was a rude
shock to expectations and many people thought it signalled significant
policy reforms. On the maxim of 'never waste a good crisis',
optimists could see this as an opportunity to overcome obstacles to
reform which were holding back trend growth. In contrast, pessimists
could think that a combination of misdiagnoses and political pressures
might push policymakers in the direction of interventions which would
undermine long-run growth. Economic history offers examples of both--the
former might appeal to the birth of the European Golden Age in the dark
days of the late 1940s while the latter could point to the implications
of the policy responses to the Great Depression of the 1930s.
Econometric analyses of the implications of financial crises for
growth offer some pointers but leave open how far European growth
prospects may have been or may yet be adversely affected by the
financial crisis. It is already generally agreed that a substantial
permanent fall in the level of output is likely, although there is some
uncertainty about its magnitude. It is less clear whether trend growth
will be reduced through declines in the rate of productivity growth.
Clearly, one way in which this might happen is that major crises can
lead to significant changes in supply-side policy. Here it is useful to
turn to economic history to complement what can be learnt from
econometrics.
In the light of this challenge, this paper considers European
growth performance and its likely trajectory in the absence of the
crisis. Then, the direct effects of the crisis on growth are assessed.
The evidence points to a significant negative effect in the absence of
policy reforms that improve productivity growth. Are these policy
reforms likely to be made? Historical experience, notably in the context
of the 1930s, suggests that the crisis will produce strong pressures in
the opposite direction. Overall, although this is not yet recognised by
agencies like the OECD, it seems likely that the crisis implies a
significantly reduced average European growth rate over the period to
2030.
Growth before the crisis
It is well-known that Western European growth performance was
lack-lustre from the mid-1990s up to the start of the current financial
crisis. This was a far cry from the so-called Golden Age of the early
postwar years and for most countries was a period of falling behind
rather than catching up with the United States even though it appeared
that, on the whole, supply-side policy had improved. Yet, while American
productivity growth accelerated, European productivity growth slowed
down.
The period from the early 1950s to the mid-1990s was an era when
Western Europe was catching up with the United States (table 1). During
the Golden Age (195073), real GDP per person (Y/P) and labour
productivity (measured either per worker (E) or per hour worked(HW))
both grew much faster in most European countries than in the United
States. In the following period of growth slowdown (1973-95), labour
productivity continued to grow faster than in the United States but
catch-up in real GDP per person ceased. The discrepancy is, of course,
explained by slower growth in labour inputs in European countries as
unemployment rose and work-years shortened; this is also captured in
table 1.
From 1995 to the eve of the current crisis, real GDP per person in
Western Europe declined slowly relative to the United States; rather
than catching up, Europe had started to fall behind. Table 1 shows that
for the EU15 the ratio was 67.5 per cent in 2007 compared with 70.0 per
cent in 1995. The data in this table also show that the main reason was
slower labour productivity growth in Europe. Trends in annual hours
worked were now more similar while the earlier tendency for employment
rates to fall relative to the United States was reversed, so that total
hours worked per person rose in Europe.
The growth rate of real GDP per hour worked increased in the United
States between 1973-95 and 1995-2007 from 1.28 per cent per year to 2.05
per cent per year. In contrast, in the EU15 it fell from 2.69 per cent
per year to 1.17 per cent per year. The rate of labour productivity
growth fell in most European countries. Indeed, labour productivity
growth in Italy and Spain was below 1 per cent per year after 1995. By
contrast, Sweden saw a productivity revival, while for part of the
period Ireland continued to be a Celtic Tiger and both countries
exceeded the American productivity growth rate. So while there was
falling behind in productivity performance on average, there was also
considerable diversity in European performance.
The acceleration in American productivity growth was underpinned by
ICT. Historical comparisons reveal that the impact of ICT has been
relatively large and also that it has come through very quickly. This
new general purpose technology (GPT) is unprecedented in its rate of
technological progress, reflected in the speed and magnitude of the
price falls in ICT equipment (Crafts, 2004). The main impact of ICT on
economic growth comes through its diffusion as a new form of capital
equipment rather than through total factor productivity (TFP) growth in
the production of ICT equipment. This is because users get the benefit
of technological progress through lower prices and as prices fall more
of this type of capital is installed. (1)
The implication is that ICT has offered Europe a great opportunity
to increase its productivity growth. However, the estimates of the
contribution of ICT capital deepening to the growth of labour
productivity in table 2 show that European countries have been less
successful than the United States in seizing this opportunity. That
said, ICT production has boosted productivity growth, notably in
Finland, Ireland and Sweden, and the use of ICT capital has made a
strong contribution, especially in the services sector, in countries
like the UK. Table 2 suggests that strong productivity performance in
the recent past relied on one or both of ICT production and market
services.
The empirical evidence is that the diffusion of ICT has been aided
by complementary investments in intangible capital and high-quality
human capital but weakened by relatively strong regulation in terms of
employment protection and restrictions to competition, especially in the
distribution sector (Conway et al., 2006). Since these forms of
regulation have weakened over time, the story is not that European
regulation has become more stringent but rather that existing regulation
became more costly in the context of a new technological era. Of course,
European countries have varied considerably in these respects; for
example, the UK and Sweden have been better placed than Italy and Spain.
The example of ICT prompts some more general comments on European
supply-side policies in the decades before the crisis. In some respects,
these improved in terms of providing conditions favourable to growth.
For example, European countries generally became more open to trade,
with positive effects on productivity partly as a result of the European
single market. Over time, years of schooling have steadily increased and
product market regulation that inhibits competition has been reduced.
Corporate tax rates have fallen since the early 1980s. The UK, in
particular, benefited from the big increase in competition in product
markets from deregulation and abandoning protectionism that took place
from the 1970s through the 1990s (Crafts, 2012a). Nevertheless,
supply-side policies were in need of reform prior to the crisis if the
issue of disappointing growth performance was to be adequately
addressed. This was the case quite generally but especially in Southern
Europe.
Thus, there have been serious question marks about the quality of
schooling in many European countries which recent research suggests
exacts a growth penalty. A measure of cognitive skills, based on test
scores, correlates strongly with growth performance (Hanushek and
Woessmann, 2012) and it is striking that even the top European
countries, such as Finland, have fallen behind Japan and South Korea
with some countries, such as Germany and, especially, Italy,
deteriorating. These authors' estimates are that, if cognitive
skills in Greece were at the standard of South Korea, its long-run
growth would be raised by about 1 percentage point per year. Woessmann
et al. (2007) show that the variance in outcomes in terms of cognitive
skills is explained by the way the schooling system is organised (for
example, with regard to the role of external examinations and how much
competition between providers is allowed) rather than educational
spending.
Competition and competition policy has tended to be weaker than in
the United States. This has raised markups and lowered competitive
pressure on managers to invest and to innovate with adverse effects on
TFP growth (Buccirossi et al., 2013; Griffith et al., 2010). Clearly,
productivity growth in market services was very disappointing in many
European countries (table 2). One reason is continued weakness of
competition reflected in high price-cost mark-ups which have survived
the introduction of the Single Market (Hoj et al., 2007). Addressing
these issues by reducing the barriers to entry maintained by member
states would have raised productivity performance significantly but
governments still have considerable discretion to maintain these
barriers notwithstanding the Services Directive (Badinger and Maydell,
2009). It should also be noted that failure to deal with excessive
regulation in professional services in particular has had adverse
effects on productivity growth in user industries (Barone and Cingano,
2011).
Finally, research into the impact of fiscal policy on growth has
suggested that the structure of taxation has significant effects.
Generally speaking, direct taxes are more damaging than indirect taxes.
The substantial increase in social transfers in European countries in
the later decades of the 20th century was financed to a considerable
extent by 'distortionary' taxation; the estimates of Kneller
et al. (1999) indicate that the average 10 percentage point increase in
the share of direct tax revenues in GDP between 1965 and 1995 entailed a
fall in the growth rate of about 1 percentage point. Financing this
expansion of government outlays by a different tax mix would have been
considerably better for growth.
On the eve of the crisis, there was widespread agreement on reforms
which would improve Western European growth performance, although, of
course, the extent of what was needed varied across countries. This
consensus was based on empirical analysis of the experience of recent
decades and reflected the discussion of this section. The very
influential analysis by Sapir (2006) stressed the importance at the EU
level of completing the Single Market in services and at the national
level of reforming labour market and social policies where these reduced
flexibility and employment.
OECD economists, who believe that implementation of these reforms
has been made more urgent by the crisis, provide some useful
quantification of the possible benefits from structural policy reforms
which is summarised in table 3. Drawing on a series of OECD studies of
the effects of policies on income levels and growth rates, Barnes et al.
(2011) sum up by proposing improvements to the quantity and quality of
education, strengthening competition, cutting unemployment benefits,
reducing and reforming taxes, and lowering employment protection. These
would either raise the growth rate or in some cases provide a
transitional boost to growth as the economy moves to higher employment
and output levels. The authors claim that addressing all policy
weaknesses by moving up to the OECD average level has a potential GDP
gain of 10 per cent for the average country after ten years and 25 per
cent eventually. (2)
Growth implications of the financial crisis
This section considers the direct implications of the crisis rather
than those which might come via a wider array of policy responses that
affect the progress of supply-side reforms; these will be addressed in
the following section.
An obvious starting point is to consider what economists who make
long-term projections have to say. The team at Goldman Sachs have
reviewed their BRICs projections which offer comparisons of future
developed market and emerging market growth (Wilson et al., 2011). Their
view is essentially that the crisis will have no long-term impact and
they project real GDP growth in Europe at 2.2 per cent per year for each
of the decades 2010-19 and 2020-29--identical to performance in the
1990s.
A more detailed analysis is provided by OECD (2012, ch. 4). Some of
the main projections are summarised in table 4. The OECD team explicitly
state that their basic assumption is that the crisis will have a small
effect on the level of potential real GDP in the OECD area of about 2.5
per cent but no effect on the trend rate of growth. Currently, output
levels in OECD countries are below potential but these 'output
gaps' are assumed to disappear over the next few years. The
analysis assumes that the crisis does not affect the pace of structural
reforms of the kind listed above which will make a modest contribution
on average to future growth. In particular, it is noticeable that the
labour productivity growth projections in table 4 for the Euro Area and
for the aggregate of OECD countries are quite optimistic and call for a
stronger performance between 2012 and 2030 than for 1995-2007. Even
troubled Eurozone economies will generally share in this experience.
Slower employment growth in future will, however, hold real GDP growth
below the pre-crisis rate.
It is well known that financial crises can have permanent adverse
direct effects on the level and possibly also the trend growth rate of
potential output. Indeed, this is a major reason why such crises have
serious fiscal implications, including big increases in structural
deficits as a percentage of GDP (Reinhart and Rogoff, 2009). Thinking in
terms of a production function or growth accounting, there may be direct
adverse effects on capital inputs (K) as investment is interrupted, on
human capital (HK) if skills are lost or restructuring makes them
redundant, on labour inputs (HW) through increases in equilibrium
unemployment, and on TFP if R&D is cut back or innovative firms
cannot get finance. Given that in the long-run TFP growth is the
fundamental underpinning of the rate of trend growth, the key question
is whether this is affected by financial crises.
Modern econometric studies are not quite conclusive. Furceri and
Mourougane (2009) estimate that for OECD countries a severe banking
crisis reduces the level of potential output by about 4 per cent while
the review of the evidence in IMF (2009, ch. 4), which also covers
lower-income economies, suggests 10 per cent, with the level of capital,
labour inputs and TFP each accounting for about a third of this. In both
papers long-run trend growth is found not to be affected but in both
cases the confidence intervals are large and the transition period while
the levels effect materialises may be quite long. If the level of
potential output suffers an adverse shock, then for a country like the
UK the structural fiscal deficit is likely to rise by a similar amount
as a share of GDP (IFS, 2010) and fiscal consolidation may be required
to head off unstable debt dynamics.
A celebrated historical example of a severe banking crisis is the
United States during the Great Depression of the 1930s when about one in
three banks failed and financial intermediation was severely disrupted
with severe consequences for investment and GDP (Bernanke, 1983). What
does that experience reveal? The obvious feature of the 1930s, reflected
in table 5, is that the financial crisis undermined growth in the
capital stock. Had growth of the capital to labour ratio continued at
the pre-1929 rate, by 1941 it would have been about 25 per cent larger
and, accordingly, potential GDP per hour worked perhaps 8 per cent
bigger. Growth of labour inputs was sluggish, impaired perhaps by the
impact of the New Deal. However, TFP growth was very strong, powered by
sustained R&D, and Field (2013) has labelled the 1930s the most
technologically progressive decade of the twentieth century in the
United States building on the strong fundamentals in place from before
the Great Depression. Overall, the clear impression is that the result
of the banking crisis was to lower the level of productive potential
rather than its growth rate, an outcome in line with the OECD's
assumptions. (3)
For today's European countries the analogue may be that
continued TFP growth in ICT, which will further reduce the price of ICT
equipment, has the scope to underpin future growth. Oulton (2012)
estimates that even without reforms which would speed up its diffusion
this will deliver 0.52 percentage points to future growth on average
across the OECD; with reform, this could go up to 0.73 percentage
points. Table 6 reports projections of the future scope for ICT to
deliver productivity growth for European countries both with and without
reform. The key point to note is that if the use of ICT capital were as
important as in Sweden, the most successful adopter of ICT, then the ICT
capital contribution would rise appreciably, notably by over 0.2
percentage points per year in the large continental economies. (4)
Banking crises can also be expected to affect future growth through
their implications for regulation of the financial sector and through
their fiscal legacy. With regard to regulation, there is general
agreement that a major requirement is to reduce the leverage of the
banking system to lower the chances of future crises. This will
generally entail the banks having more equity capital to absorb losses
which will raise the cost of capital to the banks and to their
borrowers. However, the evidence suggests that, although this will
reduce the capital stock and the level of GDP in the future, the effect
will probably be small. Miles et al. (2013) provide an illustrative calculation which suggests that halving leverage from 30 to 15 might
cost a little under 0.2 per cent of GDP. It should also be recognised
that growth did not seem to be impaired during most of the 20th century
when leverage was much lower.
An obvious implication of the financial crisis is that it will
leave a legacy of much increased ratios of public debt to GDP (D/Y).
Partly this will come through the costs of recapitalising banks but
mainly it will come through the borrowing by governments as a result of
the financial crisis induced recession and the fall in tax receipts that
this has entailed. The median increase in D/Y in advanced countries
following a banking crisis in the recent past is estimated to have been
21 per cent of GDP (Laeven and Valencia, 2012). (5) OECD countries are
more vulnerable on this score than in the 1930s because they entered the
crisis with higher D/Y ratios (Ali Abbas et al., 2011) and during the
crisis have provided some fiscal stimulus and have not tried to
over-ride the automatic stabilisers.
The long-term implications of substantial increases in D/Y are
likely to be unfavourable for growth, as is highlighted by growth models
of the overlapping-generations variety. The adverse impacts can occur
through a number of transmission mechanisms including reductions in
market-sector capital formation, higher long-term interest rates and
higher tax rates. Empirical research on advanced economies has found
negative relationships; for example, Kumar and Woo (2010) estimate that
a 10 percentage point increase in D/Y is associated with a fall of about
0.2 percentage points in growth. It has also been suggested that the
adverse effect on growth is non-linear and rises sharply once the debt
ratio reaches a critical level which has recently been claimed to be
around 90 per cent of GDP (Checherita and Rother, 2010). OECD (2012)
notes that, in the Euro Area, United States and OECD as a whole, D/Y is
approaching 100 per cent and points out that if the results of these
papers are taken literally then this could reduce future trend growth by
between 0.5 and 0.75 percentage points. (6)
High levels of D/Y create further worries about future fiscal
sustainability which add to the pressures for increases in taxes and/or
cuts in public expenditure, i.e., fiscal consolidation. Recent work by
OECD economists in the wake of the crisis has given some guidance on the
size of the adjustments that may be needed. For example, if it is
desired to achieve D/Y = 60 per cent by 2030 (the Maastricht Treaty rule), then the required average improvement in the primary balance from
2011-30 would have been 7.0 per cent of GDP in the UK, about 7.6 per
cent in Ireland and the United States, and 8.6 and 9.7 per cent
respectively in Portugal and Greece (OECD, 2012). (7)
Continuing fiscal consolidation is unlikely to be expansionary; on
the contrary, the implications are likely to be deflationary and to
entail (possibly considerable) GDP losses. The estimates in Guajardo et
al. (2011) are that, on average, a fiscal consolidation of 1 per cent of
GDP reduces real GDP by 0.62 per cent over the following two years. This
can be mitigated if an offsetting monetary-policy stimulus is possible
and/or the exchange rate depreciates. (8) If the fiscal adjustment is
achieved through expenditure cuts rather than tax increases and
accompanied by structural reforms, the evidence is that output losses
may be lower, in particular because private investment tends to respond
favourably (Alesina et al., 2012). Nevertheless, it is reasonable to
suppose that post-crisis fiscal adjustment is likely to be a drag on medium-term growth, especially for countries inside the euro. (9)
It is generally believed that expenditure-based consolidations have
a greater chance of success (Molnar, 2012) and it might be thought that
if this argument informs post-crisis policy it would minimise harmful
supply-side effects on growth by mitigating against distortionary tax
increases. (10) However, cuts in expenditure on education (which adds to
human capital) and on infrastructure (which adds to physical capital)
are bad for long-term growth. Unfortunately, previous episodes of fiscal
stringency have been notable for their negative impact on public
investment (Mehrotra and Valila, 2006). Moreover, it is noticeable that,
at high levels of debt, addressing a rising D/Y typically entails cuts
in both public investment and education spending (Bacchiocchi et al.,
2011). The strong likelihood that post-crisis fiscal consolidation will
undermine these expenditures does not bode well for the growth prospects
of highly-indebted EU countries. (11)
Policy responses to the crisis: lessons from the 1930s
If medium-term trend growth rates are significantly reduced as a
result of the crisis, a major reason could well be the broad economic
policy response. Given the magnitude of the problems that Europe now
confronts, it is useful to consider the lessons from the 1930s, a period
notable for policy changes which helped short term economic and
political objectives but damaged long-term growth performance.
First, it is well-known that the Great Depression saw big increases
in protectionism, partly reflected in the tariff rates reported in table
7. Intra-European trade costs rose by an average of about 20 per cent
between 1929 and 1938 (cf. table 10). Protectionism accounted for about
40 per cent of the fall in trade volumes during the Great Depression
(Irwin, 2012). The most interesting analysis of this protectionism is by
Eichengreen and Irwin (2010) who show that, on average, countries which
devalued had lower tariffs. They argue that protection in the 1930s is
best seen as a second-best policy which was used when the conventional
macroeconomic tools, fiscal and monetary policy, were unavailable. The
countries to which this description most obviously applies today are
Euro Area economies with sovereign debt and competitiveness problems; a
likely implication is that they will be even less inclined to move
towards implementing the Single Market in services.
However, obstacles to the use of monetary and fiscal policy are
more pervasive than this. On the monetary side, with interest rates at
the zero lower bound (ZLB) conventional monetary policy is
circumscribed. (12) On the fiscal side, worries about fiscal
sustainability have already undermined willingness to use fiscal
stimulus. This can be expected to continue to be the case in future,
perhaps reinforced by new fiscal rules for countries in the Euro Area.
Moreover, the legacy of the crisis will be a lengthy period when public
debt to GDP ratios are at a level which potentially renders fiscal
stimulus ineffective or possibly even counterproductive. (13) Auerbach
and Gorodnichenko (2011) find that at debt to GDP ratios greater than
100 per cent fiscal multipliers are close to zero even in deep
recessions, while Ilzetzki et al. (2010) suggest that, on average, the
fiscal multiplier is zero on impact and in the long run is negative at
debt to GDP ratios above 60 per cent.
This makes protectionist policies more likely and we have already
seen a lurch in this direction, albeit not to the extent of the rampant
protectionism of the 1930s. Table 8 reports policy interventions
recorded by Global Trade Alert. These are mostly not flagrant violations
of WTO rules and traditional tariff measures are only a small part of
what has happened. Thus, 84 per cent of interventions in the EU have
employed policy instruments that are subject to low or no regulation by
the WTO using measures such as bailouts and subsidies with the EU
state-aids regime effectively suspended (Aggarwal and Evenett, 2012).
So, although research has suggested that tariff barriers contributed
little (perhaps only 2 per cent) to the downturn (Kee et al., 2013), it
would be misleading to conclude that the protectionist threat is
negligible. Indeed, a WTO-compatible protectionist wave is a real
possibility (Evenett and Vines, 2012).
Second, the 1930s saw a general retreat from competition in the
advanced countries together with increases in regulation and
nationalisation. Voters were less willing to trust in markets and wanted
greater state intervention. This was reflected in policy developments at
the time and in the postwar settlements of the 1940s. Both the British
and American governments sought to encourage cartelization--the
difference being that in the United States the Supreme Court struck down
the provisions of the National Industrial Recovery Act in 1935. In the
United Kingdom, competition in product markets was greatly weakened and
this lasted long into the postwar period. In the late 1950s, tariffs
were still at mid-1930s levels and about 60 per cent of manufacturing
output was cartelised. The retreat from competition had adverse effects
on productivity performance over several decades and provided the
context in which industrial relations problems and sleepy management
proliferated (Crafts, 2012a). In the United States, product market
regulation was substantially increased with adverse implications for
economic efficiency and it was not until the 1970s and 1980s that this
was reformed (Vietor, 1994).
In Europe, the response was also to embrace selective industrial
policy, picking winners and supporting national champions but especially
helping losers, a reaction which was intensified when macroeconomic
troubles and globalisation challenges returned in the 1970s
(Foreman-Peck, 2006). Across Europe, state ownership was extended so
that countries typically entered the Golden Age with nationalised
industries supplying 10 per cent of GDP (Millward, 2011). In practice,
industrial policy was heavily skewed to slowing down exit with adverse
consequences for productivity performance and this may be an inherent
characteristic of such policies (Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud, 2007). By
the 1980s, selective industrial policy deservedly had a bad name
(Geroski and Jacquemin, 1985) and allowing creative destruction to take
its course can be seen to have been a superior policy for high-income
countries (Fogel et al., 2008). Unfortunately, in the aftermath of the
present crisis, the early signs are not good; there has already been a
serious reversion to the use of selective industrial policy and this has
come in the guise of helping losers (Aggarwal and Evenett, 2012).
Third, given the pressures on public finances which the crisis has
triggered, as in the 1930s and 1940s, there may be a serious move to
financial repression with a view to reducing the interest costs of debt
service and holding down the real interest rate relative to the growth
rate, thereby lowering the required primary surplus for fiscal
sustainability. The political attractions of an alternative to fiscal
contraction are apparent. Such a policy involves limiting in various
ways the free flow of capital between countries, i.e., reducing the
integration of capital markets.
Ali-Abbas et al. (2011) found that big debt reductions in the
period 1945-70 were, unusually, characterised by a much larger component
from the growth-interest differential rather than from primary
surpluses, while Wyplosz (2001) showed that capital controls and credit
restraints were instrumental in significantly lowering European real
interest rates at this time. (14) There was, however, a cost to European
growth from reducing the efficiency of capital markets which Voth (2003)
estimated as at least 0.7 percentage points per year. The increment to
growth from greater financial integration in European countries which
was realised pre-crisis (Gehringer, 2013) is at risk if moves towards
financial repression intensify and entail barriers to capital flows
together with reductions in cross-border lending. (15)
Fourth, the 1930s' experience suggests that a strategy of
devaluation and sovereign default could be an attractive escape route
from the euro for the periphery countries of Southern Europe because it
allows more policy sovereignty and a route to return to growth. The key
point is that devaluation and default were good for growth. Indeed,
there is a very clear correlation between the countries that exited
early from the Gold Standard and those that recovered rapidly from the
slump (Bernanke, 1995), see table 9. Abandoning the Gold Standard
allowed countries to reduce both nominal and real interest rates, to
relax fiscal policy, and to escape the need to reduce money wages and
prices through a prolonged recession in order to regain international
competitiveness. It is also clear that sovereign default, which improved
the fiscal arithmetic by eradicating debt overhangs and bolstered the
balance of payments through the elimination of debt-service flows,
promoted short term growth (Eichengreen and Portes, 1990).
The decision to leave the Gold Standard was analysed by Wolf (2008)
who used an econometric model to examine the odds of remaining in this
fixed exchange rate system. The model accurately predicts departures and
shows that a country was more likely to exit from the Gold Standard if
its main trading partner had done so, if it had returned to gold at a
high parity, if it was a democracy, or if the central bank was
independent. Conversely, it was less likely to leave if it had large
gold reserves, less price deflation, and strong banks. In other words,
the loss of international competitiveness and greater pain from
deflationary pressures hastened a country's exit.
Thus, the 1930s' experience suggests that once one country
exits, others may quickly follow. The pressures on the survival of the
euro are likely to intensify. How costly this might be is a matter of
speculation but estimates have been made; for example, Cliffe (2011)
suggests that after five years real GDP in the Euro Area would still be
5 per cent lower than at the break-up. It should be recognised, however,
that the benefit/cost ratio of leaving the Gold Standard then was very
different from that of leaving the euro today; a decision to reintroduce a national currency now might engender 'the mother of all financial
crises' (Eichengreen and Temin, 2010) through instantaneous capital
flight and a collapse of the banking system.
It is also reasonable to suggest that the demise of the currency
union would have a permanent adverse effect on GDP levels, although
perhaps not as large as has sometimes been claimed. The currency-union
effect on trade volumes was once thought to be very large but better
econometrics and the opportunity to examine the actual impact of EMU now
suggests that trade volumes increased by perhaps 2 per cent (Baldwin et
al., 2008) with the implication that the trade effect on GDP was less
than 1 per cent. There are, however, several channels through which EMU
may have raised productivity and a recent study found that EMU had
raised the level of real GDP per hour worked by 2 per cent (Barrell et
al., 2008); this would potentially be at risk.
Fifth, the shock of the 1930s encouraged workers to demand greater
social protection and promoted tighter regulation of the labour market.
In the United States this was famously addressed by the New Deal. There,
the 1930s saw the federal government pass the Social Security Act in
1935, which established a wide range of benefits including unemployment
insurance and retirement benefits. Another long-lasting intervention was
the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938 which brought in minimum wages and
overtime restrictions (Fishback, 2007). Across European countries we see
the development of much more ambitious social policies which leave their
footprint through a big increase of social transfers between 1930 and
1950 (Crafts, 2012b). This t exemplifies the well-known result
established by Rodrik (1998) that in the subsequent return to
globalisation t voters demanded greater government spending to cushion
exposure to external shocks. To the extent that this was financed by
distortionary taxation, there was a negative implication for growth.
The overall message of this section is that there is a serious
threat both to levels of potential output and to t medium-term trend
growth from policy responses to the pressures created by the crisis.
Moreover, the general direction of the 1930s' policy response to
economic crisis runs very much in the opposite direction to the
supply-side reforms which are required to speed up European growth. At
best, this does not bode well for the agenda of completing the single
market and making labour markets more flexible and employment-friendly
put forward by Sapir (2006). At worst, there may be adverse policy moves
which undermine medium-term growth performance.
If this gloomy prospectus is correct, then European growth
performance will probably undershoot the 'business-as-usual'
projections in OECD (2012). Nevertheless, OECD (2013) is optimistic
about the future of structural reforms, as it stresses that the crisis
has seen a significant increase in the responsiveness of governments to
OECD proposals for actions to improve supply-side policies. In the short
term, to a large extent, this is a corollary of strong pressures to
restore competitiveness and improve fiscal sustainability. This is,
however, probably not a good guide to the long term, especially if there
is a 'lost decade'.
In the early 1930s, the initial response of the British government
to its fiscal problems included cuts in unemployment benefits and public
sector wages but this was merely a blip on the road to 1945 when voters
expressed their strong disapproval of the market economy. Across Europe
in the 1930s, prolonged stagnation significantly increased the electoral
prospects of right-wing extremist parties (de Bromhead et al., 2012)
which were not market-friendly. In this context, not only might it be
reasonable to worry about recent election results but it should also be
recognised that opinion polls show disappointingly low support for the
market economy in countries where economic recovery seems a remote
prospect. (16) This suggests that optimism about supply-side policy
based on early responses to the crisis should not be overdone.
Reconstructing Europe: lessons from the 1940s
At the end of World War II, many thought that the prospects for
European growth were quite gloomy, yet The 'Golden Age' was
just around the corner. This was phase of rapid catch-up growth during
which Western Europe greatly reduced the massive productivity gap (cf.
table 1) with the United States that had emerged in the previous 40
years (Crafts and Toniolo, 2008). Clearly, this episode cannot be
repeated but it is useful to consider changes in the international
policy regime, in particular the Bretton Woods agreement and the
Marshall Plan, which were conducive to the start of the Golden Age and
European economic integration, with regard to the implications for
today.
The Bretton Woods agreement meant that the typical OECD country
moved to a macroeconomic trilemma choice of fixed exchange rates,
independent monetary policy and capital controls (Obstfeld and Taylor,
2004). This was designed, with the GATT, to promote a return to freer
international trade after the trade wars of the 1930s. Table 10 reflects
some success in this regard. The prevalence of capital controls can also
be seen as a choice within the 'political trilemma' posited by
Rodrik (2000), reproduced in figure 1, which states that it is generally
only possible to have at most two of the following: deep economic
integration, democratic politics and the nation state.
The 1930s' implosion of the Gold Standard can be understood in
terms of this political trilemma, as follows. In the 1920s, with the
return to the Gold Standard, countries had signed up to the 'golden
straitjacket', which had been acceptable in the context of very
limited democracy in the 19th century but in the 1930s democratic
politics at the level of the nation state overruled this policy choice.
The point is that to retain the benefits of deep economic integration
would have required action to organise it through democratic politics at
a supranational level. (17) So, when reconstruction of the international
economy was subsequently undertaken under the auspices of the 1944
Bretton Woods agreement, economic integration was severely restricted by
controls on international capital flows (the 'Bretton-Woods
compromise' in figure 1).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
It might be suggested that the initial design of the euro sought to
impose an equivalent to the 'golden straightjacket'. History
suggests that it will be difficult to continue this strategy under the
pressures brought on by the crisis and in today's world it is
neither feasible nor desirable to seek to reinstate the capital controls
of the 1950s. If so, then logic points to a different solution to the
political trilemma problem based either on a modern equivalent to the
1950s' 'Bretton-Woods Compromise' or the 'global
federalism' of a 'United States of Europe'.
The idea of the 'Bretton-Woods Compromise' was to
sacrifice some aspects of economic integration to provide sufficient
policy space to make saving the remaining aspects politically
acceptable. Obviously, this came at a cost--European growth in the
Golden Age would have been even stronger without capital controls. It is
arguable that we are already seeing an equivalent in terms of the return
of selective industrial policy, creeping protectionism and moves towards
financial repression. If so, this will also incur a cost in lower growth
over the medium term.
The alternative, 'United States of Europe', solution
would require major institutional reform within the EU and would entail
banking union, fiscal union, and a constitution that ended Europe's
'democratic deficit'. Wolf (2012) spells out what this might
enable. He notes that it would allow more effective European fiscal and
monetary policy at the ZLB, and political legitimisation of a much
higher level of transfer payments from an expanded European budget while
also finding a way to share burdens of adjustment between surplus and
deficit countries. However, delivering this will be difficult and, at
best, it may take years to achieve the success that would preserve the
income gains that have accrued from European integration and preclude
creeping protectionism in capital and product markets.
The Marshall Plan was a major programme of aid which transferred
$12.5 billion from the United States to Western Europe during the years
1948 to 1951 and provided inflows to recipient countries which typically
averaged about 2 per cent of GDP per year. (18) It helped reduce the
costs of the Bretton-Woods Compromise by speeding up European
integration via trade liberalisation and the conditionality that it
entailed also promoted pro-market reforms that were conducive to growth.
As De Long and Eichengreen (1993) stressed, rather than being a handout,
the Marshall Plan was a "structural adjustment program" along
the lines of the Washington Consensus--"the most successful
ever"--which succeeded by raising productivity growth and steered
Europe away from becoming Argentina. It worked by tipping the balance in
favour of pro-market structural reforms that raised productivity growth
rather than through a direct stimulus. (19)
In particular, each country signed a bilateral treaty with the
United States which committed them to follow policies of financial
stability and trade liberalisation while the Organization for European
Economic Cooperation (OEEC) provided 'conditional aid' to back
an intra West European multilateral payments agreement; in 1950,
recipients had to become members of the European Payments Union (EPU).
This lasted until 1958, by which time intra-European trade was 2.3 times
that of 1950 and a gravity-model analysis confirms that the EPU had a
large positive effect on trade levels. (20) This can be seen as a
stepping stone to further trade liberalisation through increases in the
political clout of exporting firms relative to import-competing firms
(Baldwin, 2006). The long-term effect of economic integration raised
European income levels substantially, by nearly 20 per cent by the
mid-1970s according to estimates by Badinger (2005). (21)
This suggests that there might be something to be gained from a
'Marshall Plan' as a way of mitigating the costs of the modern
equivalent of a Bretton-Woods Compromise and as an insurance policy to
reduce the likelihood of the disintegration of the euro in the interval
before the federalist solution is feasible but also as a means to
improve growth prospects in southern Europe. The objective of a
'Real' Marshall Plan for Southern Europe would be to underpin
European economic integration and the survival of the euro by
incentivising supply-side reforms to increase productivity growth. (22)
The central component, as in the 1940s, would be to formulate a
successful structural adjustment programme with strict conditionality
focused on improving productive potential rather than simply spending
more of the EU budget. The programme would include product market
reforms, including serious moves to implement fully the Single Market,
fiscal reforms to broaden the tax base and switch towards consumption
and property taxes, labour-market reforms to increase flexibility and to
reduce the equilibrium level of unemployment. Such changes would not
only improve productivity (cf. table 3) but also go some way towards
restoring lost competitiveness. These are economic-policy changes rather
than investments in projects and, generally, incur political rather than
monetary costs. In the longer term, improvements in educational quality
should also be a focal point.
Unfortunately, it seems most unlikely that a new Marshall Plan of
this kind is feasible. To be credible, the funds would have to be
committed but only released when reforms had been implemented
satisfactorily (Allard and Everaert, 2010)--similar to the deal that
worked in the context of EU enlargement in 2004. Whether the EU could
implement this has to be doubtful. Moreover, the general record of
structural adjustment programmes administered by the IMF and World Bank
is that the results have been disappointing both in terms of compliance
and outcomes. More specifically, the success or failure of such
programmes depended heavily on domestic political economy considerations
and willingness to embrace reform, i.e., finding 'good
candidates' to support (Dollar and Svensson, 2000). It would surely
be difficult at present to persuade Northern Europeans that Southern
European countries are 'good candidates' or that
non-compliance would be effectively punished and the policy
prescriptions would not be welcomed by Southern European voters.
Regrettably, therefore, it seems that trying this antidote to problems
in the Euro Area is most unlikely although, in principle, it could play
a very useful role in underpinning growth as did the Marshall Plan of
the 1940s.
Conclusions
The legacy of the crisis is a number of significant downside risks
to long-term European growth which do not yet seem to be widely
understood and have not yet been incorporated into projections made by
agencies like the OECD.
A major implication of the crisis is that average public debt to
GDP ratios in European countries will approach or even exceed 100 per
cent. Past experience says that the existence of such high debt ratios
will quite possibly reduce growth performance by 0.5 percentage points
or more per year. Attempts to address this issue through fiscal
consolidation which may last for many years will further depress growth.
Fiscal consolidation can be undertaken in a variety of ways with very
different implications for growth potential; past experience suggests
that there is a real danger that government expenditure on education and
infrastructure will be jeopardised.
Supply-side reforms undertaken now could potentially raise European
growth rates perhaps by as much as 0.5 to 1 percentage point per year
over the period to 2030. The general thrust of these reforms would
include fiscal changes to reduce distortionary taxation, strengthening
competition and reducing regulations that damage productivity, and
improving the quality of education. Generally speaking, this could be
done without undermining public finances but not without upsetting many
voters. The debt overhang makes reforms that raise the growth rate in
European countries more urgent because of their favourable implications
for fiscal sustainability but, unfortunately, less likely. Indeed, the
pressures of the crisis may well push policy in adverse directions,
especially if there seems to be no scope to stimulate economic activity
using conventional fiscal or monetary policies. The 1930s' crisis
led to more regulation, less competition, increased protectionism and
financial repression.
The experience of the 1930s also suggests that there is a real risk
of European economic integration being partially reversed or even of the
euro collapsing in chaos with a large cumulative GDP loss over five or
more years. Devaluation and sovereign default may have increasing
political appeal. The logic of the political trilemma points to a
fully-federal Europe as the way to avert these outcomes but this is
unlikely to be achieved easily or quickly. Unlike the 1940s, there seems
no real prospect of a Marshall Plan to help rescue the situation.
Conventional wisdom is still that medium-term growth prospects are
unaffected by the crisis which began in 2007. This seems too optimistic.
Considering both the direct effects and the pressures to change policies
in directions which will undermine rather than stimulate growth, it is
very possible that real GDP growth in the Euro Area between 2012 and
2030 will be well below the OECD's projections.
REFERENCES
Aggarwal, V.K. and Evenett, S.J. (2012), 'Industrial policy
choice during the crisis era', Oxford Review of Economic Policy,
28, pp. 261-83.
Alesina, A., Favero, C. and Giavazzi, F. (2012), 'The output
effects of fiscal consolidation', NBER Working Paper No. 18336.
Ali Abbas, S.M., Belhocine, N., El-Ganainy, A. and Horton, M.
(2011), 'Historical patterns and dynamics of public debt- evidence
from a new database', IMF Economic Review, 59, pp. 717-42.
Allard, C. and Everaert, L. (2010), 'Lifting euro area growth:
priorities for structural reforms and governance', IMF Staff
Position Note 10/19.
Auerbach, A. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2011), 'Fiscal policy in
recession and expansion', NBER Working Paper No. 17447.
Bacchiocchi, E., Borghi, E. and Missale, A. (2011), 'Public
investment under fiscal constraints', Fiscal Studies, 32, pp.
11-42.
Badinger, H. (2005), 'Growth effects of economic integration:
evidence from the EU member states', Review of World Economics, 14
I, pp. 50-78.
Badinger, H. and Maydell, N. (2009), 'Legal and economic
issues in completing the EU internal market for services: an
interdisciplinary perspective', Journal of Common Market Studies,
47, pp. 693-717.
Baldwin, R. (2006), 'Multilateralising regionalism: spaghetti
bowls as building blocks on the path to global free trade', The
World Economy, 29, pp. 1451-518.
Baldwin, R., Di Nino, V., Fontagne, L., De Santis, R. and Taglioni,
D. (2008), 'Study on the impact of the Euro on trade and foreign
direct investment', European Economy Economic Papers No. 321.
Baldwin. R.E. and Evenett, S.J. (2012), 'Beggar-thy-neighbour
policies during the crisis era: causes, constraints and lessons for
maintaining open borders', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 28,
pp. 211-34.
Baldwin, R.E. and Robert-Nicoud, F. (2007), 'Entry and
asymmetric lobbying: why governments pick losers', Journal of the
European Economic Association, 5, pp. 1064-93.
Barnes, S., Bouis, R., Briard, P., Dougherty, S. and Eris, M.
(2011), 'The GDP impact of reform: a simple simulation
framework', OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 834.
Barone, G. and Cingano, F. (2011), 'Service regulation and
growth: evidence from OECD countries', Economic Journal, 121, pp.
931-57.
Barrell, R., Gotschalk S., Holland, D., Khoman, E., Liadze, I. and
Pomerantz, O. (2008), 'The impact of EMU on growth and
employment', European Economy Economic Papers No. 318.
Ben-David, D., Lumsdaine, R. and Papell, D. H. (2003), 'Unit
roots, postwar slowdowns and long-run growth: evidence from two
structural breaks', Empirical Economics, 28, pp. 303-19.
Bernanke, B. (1983), 'Non-monetary effects of the financial
crisis in the propagation of the great depression', American
Economic Review, 73, pp. 257-276.
--(1995), 'The macroeconomics of the great depression: a
comparative approach', Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 27,
pp. 1-28.
Bernanke, B. and James, H. (1991) 'The gold standard,
deflation, and financial crisis in the great depression: an
international comparison', in Hubbard, R.G. (ed.), Financial
Markets and Financial Crises, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, pp.
33-68.
Blanchard, O. and Leigh, D. (2013), 'Growth forecast errors
and fiscal multipliers', IMF Working Paper No. 13/1.
Buccirossi, P., Ciari, L., Duso, T., Spagnolo, G. and Vitale, C.
(2013), 'Competition policy and productivity growth: an empirical
assessment', Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.
Checherita, C. and Rother, P. (2010), 'The impact of high and
growing government debt on growth: an empirical investigation for the
Euro area', ECB Working Paper No. 1237.
Cliffe, M. (2011), EMU Break-Up: Pay Now, Pay Later, London, ING.
Conway, P., de Rosa, D., Nicoletti, G. and Steiner, F. (2006),
'Regulation, competition and productivity convergence', OECD
Economics Department Working Paper No. 509.
Crafts, N. (2004), 'Steam as a general purpose technology: a
growth accounting perspective', Economic Journal, 114, pp. 338-51.
--(2011), 'The Marshall Plan: a reality check',
University of Warwick CAGE Working Paper No. 49.
--(2012a), 'British relative economic decline revisited: the
role of competition', Explorations in Economic History, 49, pp.
17-29.
--(2012b), 'Western European growth prospects: an historical
perspective', University of Warwick CAGE Working Paper No. 72.
--(2012c), 'Saving the Eurozone: is a 'real'
Marshall Plan the answer?', CAGE-Chatham House Policy Paper No. 1.
Crafts, N. and Toniolo, G. (2008), 'European economic growth,
1950-2005: an overview', CEPR Discussion Paper No. 6863.
De Bromhead, A., Eichengreen, B. and O'Rourke, K. H. (2012),
'Right-wing political extremism in the great depression', NBER
Working Paper No. 17871.
De Long, J.B. and Eichengreen, B. (1993), 'The Marshall Plan:
history's most successful adjustment program', in Dornbusch,
R., Nolling, W. and Layard, R. (eds), Postwar Economic Reconstruction and Lessons for the East Today, Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press, pp.
189-230.
Dollar, D. and Svensson, J. (2000), 'What explains the success
or failure of structural adjustment programmes?', Economic Journal,
110, pp. 894-917.
Eichengreen, B. (1993), Reconstructing Europe's Trade and
Payments, Manchester, Manchester University Press.
Eichengreen, B. and Irwin, D. (2010), 'The slide to
protectionism in the great depression: who succumbed and why?',
Journal of Economic History, 70, pp. 871-97.
Eichengreen, B. and Portes, R. (1990), 'The interwar debt
crisis and its aftermath', World Bank Research Observer, 5, pp.
69-94.
Eichengreen, B. and Temin, P. (2010), 'Fetters of gold and
paper', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 26, pp. 370-84.
Eichengreen, B. and Uzan, M. (1992), 'The Marshall Plan:
economic effects and implications for Eastern Europe and the former
USSR', Economic Policy, 14, pp. 13-75.
Evenett, S.J. and Vines, D. (2012), 'Crisis-era protectionism
and the multilateral governance of trade: an assessment', Oxford
Review of Economic Policy, 28, pp. 195-210.
Fernandez-Villaverde, J, Guerron-Quintana, P. and Rubio-Ramirez,
J.F. (2011), 'Supply-side policies and the zero lower bound',
NBER Working Paper No. 17543.
Field, A.J. (2013), 'Economic growth and recovery in the
United States, 1919-41', in Crafts, N. and Fearon, P. (eds), The
Great Depression of the 1930s: Lessons for Today, Oxford, Oxford
University Press, pp. 358-94.
Fishback, P.V. (2007), 'The New Deal', in Fishback, P.V.
(ed.), Government and the Economy: a New History, Chicago, University of
Chicago Press, pp. 384-430.
Fogel, K., Morck, R. and Yeung, B. (2008), 'Big business
stability and economic growth: is what's good for General Motors
good for America?', Journal of Financial Economics, 89, pp. 83-108.
Foreman-Peck, J. (2006), 'Industrial policy in Europe in the
20th century', EIB Papers, II (I), pp. 37-62.
Furceri, D. and Mourougane, A. (2009), 'The effect of
financial crises on potential output: new empirical evidence from OECD
Countries', OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 699.
Gehringer, A. (2013), 'Growth, productivity and capital
accumulation: the effects of financial liberalization in the case of
European integration', International Review of Economics and
Finance, 25, pp. 291-309.
Geroski, P. and Jacquemin, A. (1985), 'Industrial change,
barriers to mobility and European industrial policy', Economic
Policy, I, pp. 170-218.
Grifflth, R., Harrison, R. and Simpson, H. (2010), 'Product
market reform and innovation in the EU', Scandinavian Journal of
Economics, 112, pp. 389-415.
Guajardo, J., Leigh, D. and Pescatori, A. (2011),
'Expansionary austerity: new international evidence', IMF
Working Paper No. 11/158.
Hagemann, R.P. (2012), 'Fiscal consolidation part 6: what are
the best policy instruments for fiscal consolidation?', OECD
Economics Department Working Paper No. 937.
Hanushek, E.A. and Woessmann, L. (2012), 'Do better schools
lead to more growth? Cognitive skills, economic outcomes, and
education', Journal of Economic Growth, 17, pp. 267-321.
Hoj, J., Jimenez, M., Maher, M., Nicoletti, G. and Wise, M. (2007),
'Product market competition in OECD countries: taking stock and
moving forward', OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 575.
Holland, D. (2012), 'Less austerity, more growth?', NIESR Discussion Paper No. 400.
Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E.G. and Vegh, C.A. (2010), 'How big
(small?) are fiscal multipliers?', NBER Working Paper No. 16479.
Institute for Fiscal Studies (2010), Green Budget 2010.
International Monetary Fund (2009), World Economic Outlook.
Irwin, D.A. (2010), 'Did France cause the great
depression?', NBER Working Paper No. 16350.
--(2012), Trade Policy Disaster, Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press.
Jacks, D.S., Meissner, C.M. and Novy, D. (2011), 'Trade booms,
trade busts, and trade costs', Journal of International Economics,
83, pp. 185-201.
Kamps, C. (2005), 'Is there a lack of public capital in the
European Union?', EIB Papers, 10(I), pp. 73-93.
Kee, H.L., Neagu, C. and Nicita, A. (2010), 'Is protectionism
on the rise?: assessing national trade policies during the crisis of
2008', Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.
Kneller, R., Bleaney, M. and Gemmell, N. (1999), 'Fiscal
policy and growth: evidence from OECD countries', Journal of Public
Economics, 74, pp. 171-90.
Kumar, M.S. and Woo, J. (2010), 'Public debt and growth',
IMF Working Paper No. 10/174.
Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2012), 'Systemic banking crises
database update', IMF Working Paper No. 12/163.
Larch, M. and Turroni, A. (2011), 'Received wisdom and beyond:
lessons from fiscal consolidation in the EU', National Institute
Economic Review, 217, pp. R1-R18.
Maddison, A. (2003), The World Economy: Historical Statistics,
Paris, OECD.
Mehrotra, A. and Valila, T. (2006), 'Public investment in
Europe: evolution and determinants in perspective', Fiscal Studies,
27, pp. 443-71.
Miles, D., Yang, J. and Marcheggiano, G. (2013), 'Optimal bank
capital', Economic Journal, 123, pp. 1-37.
Millward, R. (2011), 'Public enterprise in the modern western
world: an historical analysis', Annals of Public and Cooperative
Economics, 82, pp. 375-98.
Molnar, M. (2012), 'Fiscal consolidation part 5: what factors
determine the success of consolidation efforts?', OECD Economics
Department Working Paper No. 936.
Obstfeld, M. and Taylor, A. (2004), Global Capital Markets:
Integration, Crisis and Growth, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
OECD (2012), Economic Outlook.
--(2013), Economic Policy Reforms 2013: Going for Growth. Oulton,
N. (2012), 'Long-term implications of the ICT revolution: applying
the lessons of growth theory and growth accounting', Economic
Modeling, 29, pp. 1722-36.
Pew Research (2012), 'Pew Global Attitudes Project' at
http://www.pewglobal.org.
Prados de la Escosura, L., Roses, J. and Sanz Villaroya, 1. (2011),
'Economic reforms and growth in Franco's Spain', Revista
de Historia Economica, 30, pp. 45-89.
Reinhart, C.M. (2012), 'The return of financial
repression', CEPR Discussion Paper No. 8947.
Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. (2009), This Time is Different:
Eight Centuries of Financial Folly, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Reinhart, C.M. and Sbrancia, M.B. (2011), 'The liquidation of
government debt', NBER Working Paper No. 16893.
Rodrik, D. (1998), 'Why do open economies have bigger
governments?', Journal of Political Economy, 106, pp. 997-1032.
--(2000), 'How far will international economic integration
go?", Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(I), pp. 177-86.
Sapir, A. (2006), 'Globalization and the reform of European
social models', Journal of Common Market Studies, 44, pp. 369-90.
Timmer, M., Inklaar, R., O'Mahony, M. and van Ark, B. (2010),
Economic Growth in Europe: a Comparative Economic Industry Perspective,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Vietor, R.H.K. (1994), 'Contrived competition: economic
regulation and de-regulation, 1920-1980s', Business History, 36(4),
pp. 1-32.
Voth, H.-J. (2003), 'Convertibility, currency controls and the
cost of capital in Europe, 1950-1999', International Journal of
Finance and Economics, 8, pp. 255-76.
Wilson, D., Trivedi, K., Carlson, S. and Ursua, J. (2011),
'The BRICs I 0 years on: halfway through the great
transformation', Goldman Sachs Global Economics Paper No. 208.
Woessmann, L., Ludemann, E, Schutz, M. and West, M.R. (2007),
'School accountability, autonomy, choice and the level of student
achievement: international evidence from PISA 2003', OECD Education
Working Paper No. 13.
Wolf, N. (2008), 'Scylla and Charybdis: explaining
Europe's exit from gold, January 1928 to December 1936',
Explorations in Economic History, 45, pp. 383-401.
--(2012), 'Crises and policy responses within the political
trilemma: Europe, 1929-36 and 2008-2011', EHES Working Papers in
Economic History No. 16.
Wyplosz, C. (200 I), 'Financial restraints and liberalization
in postwar Europe', in Caprio, Honohan, G.P. and Stiglitz, J.
(eds), Financial Liberalization: How Far, How Fast?, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, pp. 125-58.
Notes
(1) In a country with no ICT production, a neoclassical growth
model whose Cobb-Douglas production function has two types of capital
(ICT and other) shows that the steady state rate of growth will be TFP
growth plus a term denoting the rate of real price decline for ICT
capital multiplied by the share of ICT capital in national income, all
divided by labour's share of national income (Oulton, 2012).
(2) Some reforms, notably to educational systems, take a long time
to pay off.
(3) Time-series econometrics can also be used to address this issue
(although the picture is muddied by World War II) and this also points
to a levels decrease--actually followed by a modest increase in trend
growth (Ben-David et al., 2003).
(4) Table 6 shows that for most countries it is ICT use rather than
ICT production that dominates the contribution that this GPT makes to
growth.
(5) In some cases such as Ireland (73 per cent), the increase has
been much greater than this.
(6) The OECD projections in table 4 do not incorporate this
prediction.
(7) The basic algebra related to stabilising the debt ratio is that
Ad = b + (i - [pi] - [DELTA]Y/Y)d where d is the debt/GDP ratio, b is
the primary budget deficit, i.e., the budget deficit without including
interest payments on the debt, i is the nominal interest rate, ]pi] is
the rate of inflation and [DELTA]Y/Y is the rate of growth of real GDP.
So for [increment of d] = 0, the required primary budget surplus -b =
d(i - [pi] - [DELTA]Y/Y). Price deflation means that [pi] is negative
and this clearly makes the fiscal task much harder given that i cannot
be negative. On the other hand if [DELTA]Y/Y > (i - [pi]), i.e., if
growth is greater than the real interest rate it is possible to
stabilise (or even reduce) d while running a primary deficit. Normally,
the primary balance has to take the strain but, interestingly, this was
not the case during the European Golden Age when in the era of rapid
catch-up and financial repression the growth rate was much greater than
the real interest rate (All Abbas et al., 2011). We return to the
implications of this point in the next section.
(8) This strategy is, of course, not available for Euro Area
countries,
(9) It should be noted that such effects are not taken into account
in the OECD projections reported in table 4.
(10) The validity of this claim for the recent experience of EU
countries is disputed by Larch and Turroni (2011).
(11) Pre-crisis, many EU countries were already investing too
little to maintain the stock of public capital at a growth-maximising
level (Kamps, 2005).
(12) If, however, the policy response at the ZLB is for reforms
that raise productivity and wealth, their impact on recovery is enhanced
because it is not offset by interest rate increases
(Fernandez-Villaverde et al., 2011).
(13) None of this should be taken to imply that fiscal multipliers
were low at the start of the crisis--on the contrary they were probably
greater than I in many countries at the ZLB and with a credit crunch,
see Blanchard and Leigh (2013) and Holland (2012).
(14) For the UK, it has been estimated that the financial
repression 'tax' yielded 3.6 per cent of GDP per year between
1945 and 1980 (Reinhart and Sbrancia, 2011).
(15) There have already been some in the form of financial
regulation (Reinhart, 2012) while cross-border investment in Europe has
fallen by over 50 per cent since 2008.
(16) In response to the question 'Are people better off in a
free market economy?' in 2012 only 44 per cent in Greece, 47 per
cent in Spain and 50 per cent in Italy agreed (Pew Research, 2012). In
2007, 67 per cent in Spain and 73 per cent in Italy had agreed (no data
for Greece).
(17) It should also be noted that enduring prolonged recessions,
perhaps in the attempt to comply with the golden straitjacket, helped
spawn the rise of extreme right-wing political parties although the
structure of the electoral system and the depth of democratic traditions
in determining political outcomes also mattered (de Bromhead et al.,
2012).
(18) More details of how it worked can be found it Crafts (2011).
(19) Eichengreen and Uzan (1992) estimate that the direct effects
on growth averaged only 0.3 per cent per year.
(20) See Eichengreen (1993) which also contains a detailed
description of the logic and mechanics of EPU.
(21) Exclusion from the Marshall Plan and EPU postponed but did not
necessarily preclude trade liberalisation, as is shown by the 1959
reform in Spain which raised the growth rate by 1 percentage point per
year for the next decade and a half (Prados de la Escosura et al.,
2011).
(22) This is surely not what those who have called for a new
Marshall Plan have in mind; their focus is typically on income transfers
not conditionality-based reform. For a fuller discussion of the idea of
a 'Real Marshall Plan', see Crafts (2012c).
Nicholas Crafts, Warwick University. E-mail:
N.Crafts@warwick.ac.uk. An earlier version of this paper was presented
at the inaugural CEPR-Modena conference, 'Growth in Mature
Economies', in November 2012. I am grateful to participants for
very helpful comments. The paper has also benefited from suggestions
made by Dawn Holland, Simon Kirby and two anonymous referees. Remaining
errors and omissions are my responsibility.
Table 1. Output and productivity in Europe and the
United States, 1950-2007
a) Growth rates (% per year)
Real GDP
Real GDP Real GDP /hour
Real GDP /person /worker worked
1950-73
EU 15 5.97 4.05 4.15 4.80
USA 3.92 2.45 2.30 2.56
1973-95
EU 15 2.25 1.89 2.00 2.69
USA 2.86 1.80 1.12 1.28
1995-2007
EU 15 2.58 1.80 0.92 1.17
USA 3.17 2.11 1.92 2.05
b) Decomposition of EU 15/USA real GDP/person gap, 1950-2007
Y/P Y/HW HW/E E/P
1950 0.482 0.381 1.190 1.063
1973 0.680 0.629 1.092 1.000
1995 0.700 0.853 0.974 0.843
2007 0.675 0.769 0.947 0.928
Source: Derived from The Conference Board Total Economy
Database (2012).
Note: The table shows the identity Y/P = Y/HW x HW/E x E/P for
the ratio of EU 15/USA.
Table 2. Labour productivity growth in the market sector,
1995-2005 (% per year)
a) Growth accounting
Non- Labour
Labour ICTK/ ICT TFP productivity
quality HW K/HW growth
Ireland 0.2 0.4 2.1 1.8 4.5
Sweden 0.3 0.6 I.I 1.6 3.6
UK 0.5 0.9 0.4 0.8 2.6
France 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.9 2.1
Portugal 0.2 0.6 1.3 -0.3 1.8
Germany 0.1 0.5 0.6 0.4 1.6
Spain 0.4 0.3 0.5 -0.8 0.4
Italy 0.2 0.3 0.5 -0.7 0.3
USA 0.3 1.0 0.3 1.3 2.9
b) Sectoral contributions
Labour
ICT Manu- Other Market productivity
production facturing goods services growth
Ireland 1.0 2.2 0.2 1.4 4.5
Sweden I.I I.0 0.2 1.4 3.6
U K 0.5 0.5 0.2 1.6 2.6
France 0.4 0.7 0.3 0.7 2.1
Portugal 0.5 0.5 0.2 0.6 1.8
Germany 0.4 0.6 0.3 0.2 1.5
Spain 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.4
Italy 0.3 0.0 0.2 -0.1 0.3
USA 0.8 0.6 -0.1 1.8 2.9
Source: Timmer et al. (2010).
Note: Reallocation effects not reported
Table 3. Potential impact on real GDP per person of
structural policy reforms
Product
Labour market Edu- Total
market Taxation regulation cation
Moving to OECD average
USA 0.3 1.4 0.0 2.5 4.2
France 4.5 10.9 2.2 2.1 19.7
Germany 6.1 9.9 0.0 0.0 16.0
UK 1.1 0.0 0.0 4.6 5.7
Sweden 6.5 6.4 0.0 0.1 13.0
Greece 6.0 10.1 22.0 5.8 43.9
Ireland 6.8 0.9 9.7 0.0 17.4
Italy 0.3 10.8 0.3 5.4 16.8
Portugal 7.3 0.7 8.5 21.8 38.3
Spain 3.5 4.6 0.0 6.3 14.4
10 per cent
reforms'
OECD
average 6.1 3.3 3.8 11.6 24.8
Source: Barnes et al. (2011).
Table 4. OECD long-term growth projections
1995- 2008- 2012-17 2012-17
2007 12 (actual) (potential) 2018-30
a) Real GDP growth (% per year)
OECD 2.8 0.5 2.4 2.1 2.3
Euro Area 2.3 -0.1 1.8 1.5 1.8
USA 3.1 0.6 2.7 2.1 2.4
France 2.2 0.1 2.2 1.8 2.1
Germany 1.6 0.6 1.7 1.6 1.1
U K 2.9 -0.5 1.9 1.5 2.1
Sweden 3.2 0.9 2.6 2.5 2.3
Greece 3.8 -2.8 1.7 0.6 2.4
Ireland 2.4 -1.7 2.6 1.2 2.6
Italy 1.5 -1.0 0.9 0.6 1.6
Portugal 3.2 -1.2 1.0 0.7 1.8
Spain 3.7 -0.4 2.3 1.5 2.3
b) Growth of Real GDP/worker (% per year)
OECD 1.7 0.5 2.1 2.3
Euro Area 1.0 0.3 1.5 1.8
USA 1.8 1.2 1.3 1.4
France 1.1 0.1 1.4 1.9
Germany 1.2 0.0 1.4 1.7
U K 1.9 -0.4 0.8 1.5
Sweden 2.4 0.4 1.8 1.9
Greece 2.5 -0.8 0.3 2.2
Ireland 2.3 1.2 0.9 1.3
Italy 0.3 -0.5 0.1 1.5
Portugal 1.4 0.2 0.5 1.7
Spain 0.1 1.7 0.8 1.6
Sources: 1995-2012: The Conference Board Total Economy
database; 2012-30: OECD (2012, ch. 4).
Table 5. Contributions to labour productivity growth in
the United States (% per year)
K/HW HK/HW TFP Y/HW
growth growth growth growth
1906-19 0.51 0.26 1.12 1.89
1919-29 0.31 -0.06 2.02 2.27
1929-41 -0.19 0.14 2.97 2.92
1941-48 0.24 0.22 2.08 2.54
1948-73 0.76 0.11 1.88 2.75
Source: Derived from Field (2013).
Note: Estimates are for private non-farm economy.
Table 6. ICT and long-run growth potential (% per year)
ICT- ICT-use
use own Swedish ICT
[beta] [beta] output
Austria 0.46 0.76 0.22
Belgium 0.64 0.73 0.13
Czech Republic 0.53 0.81 0.27
Denmark 0.62 0.70 0.20
Finland 0.67 0.76 0.57
France 0.48 0.68 0.17
Germany 0.44 0.68 0.33
Hungary 0.58 0.79 0.44
Ireland 0.39 0.94 0.51
Italy 0.36 0.70 0.19
Netherlands 0.51 0.71 0.10
Slovenia 0.28 0.62 0.28
Spain 0.53 0.76 0.10
Sweden 0.70 0.70 0.24
UK 0.60 0.66 0.16
Unweighted average 0.52 0.73 0.26
Source: Oulton (2012).
Note: [beta] is the factor share of ICT
capital; a high value indicates relatively successful diffusion and
is conducive to a higher growth contribution. These projections are
based on a neoclassical growth model with 2 types of capital, ICT
capital and other capital, and a production function y =
[Ak.sub.NICT][alpha][k.sub.ICT][beta] where y is output per worker
and k denotes capital per worker. In the traditional model with one
type of capital, steady state labour productivity growth is
([DELTA]A/A)/ SL, where SL is labour's share of national income. In
the modified model, this is augmented by an additional term
(([beta][DELTA]p/p)/[s.sub.L] where [DELTA]p/p is the rate of
decline of the price of ICT capital goods relative to other capital
goods. [DELTA]p/p will reflect technological progress in the production
of ICT capital. The estimates assume that the real price of ICT
equipment continues to fall at 7 per cent per year.
Table 7. Tariff rates, 1928, 1935 and 1938 (%)
1928 1935 1938
Austria 8.1 17.5 14.8
Belgium 3.4 8.3 6.7
Canada 15.9 15.4 13.9
Czechoslovakia 7.8 10.0 7.2
Denmark 5.5 8.2 7.3
France 6.6 16.9 16.6
Germany 7.9 30.1 33.4
Hungary 11.0 7.2 12.0
Italy 6.7 22.2 12.1
Japan 7.1 6.2 6.6
Netherlands 2.1 9.1 6.7
New Zealand 17.1 17.5 16.4
Norway 11.5 14.4 12.2
Spain 24.1 27.9 n/a
Sweden 9.3 10.1 9.5
Switzerland 9.3 23.3 18.1
United Kingdom 10.0 24.5 24.1
United States 13.8 17.5 15.5
Source: Eichengreen and Irwin (2010).
Note: Tariff rate is defined as customs revenue/value of imports.
Table 8. Crisis era protectionist measures recorded by
Global Trade Alert
Bailout/state aid 324 Migration 47
Trade defence 289 Investment 46
Tariff 166 Public procurement 41
Non-tariff barrier (n.e.s) 110 Export subsidy/incentives 38
Export taxes 85 Import ban 28
Source: Baldwin and Everett (2012).
Note: 'Trade defence' comprises antidumping, countervailing
duties and safeguard measures
Table 9. Dates of changes in gold standard policies and
economic recovery
Return to 1929
income level Devaluation
Austria 1939 09/1931
Belgium 1939 03/1935
Denmark (a) 09/1931
Finland 1934 10/1931
France 1939 10/1936
Germany 1935 (b)
Greece 1933 04/1932
Italy 1935 10/1936
Netherlands 1949 09/1936
Norway 1932 09/1931
Spain 1955 (c)
Sweden 1933 09/1931
Switzerland 1938 09/1936
United Kingdom 1934 09/1931
United States 1940 04/1933
Sources: Bernanke and James (1991); Maddison (2003).
Notes: (a) Real GDP per person never fell below the 1929 level in
Denmark. (b) Germany did not devalue but by imposing exchange
controls effectively left the gold standard in July 1931.
(c) Spain was not on the gold standard.
Table 10. Trade costs: Italy with various partner countries
Germany UK Spain USA
1929 1.10 1.22 1.63 1.26
1950 1.27 1.36 2.40 1.40
1960 1.01 1.25 1.54 1.29
1970 0.79 1.21 1.42 1.22
1980 0.61 0.86 1.08 1.13
1990 0.56 0.84 0.87 1.13
2000 0.66 0.90 0.87 1.14
Source: Data underlying jacks et al. (2011) generously provided
by Dennis Novy.
Notes: Trade costs are inferred from a gravity model of trade
flows and comprise both policy and non-policy barriers to
trade.