Reassessing productive capacity in the United States.
Holland, Dawn
This note considers the productive capacity of the United States economy, and highlights the key developments that have caused a
reassessment of potential output since 2007. This issue is central to
the debate on the size of the output gap in the US, which is a key input
into macroeconomic policy decision-making. The Congressional Budget
Office (CBO) made a downward revision to their estimate of potential
output in the US last September, due to persistent effects of the recent
recession (CBO, 2011). A permanent or persistent loss of output, often
called a 'scar', affects the estimates of the structural and
cyclical components of the government budget deficit, and hence the
sustainable level of government spending and the need for fiscal
adjustment.
A reassessment of potential output will also affect our judgement
on the level of spare capacity in the economy, a key indicator of
inflationary pressures used to guide monetary policy decisions.
President of the St Louis Federal Reserve, James Bullard, recently
expressed the view that the US output gap may be smaller than typical
estimates, and has sparked a heated debate around the roles of demand
and supply in determining the output gap.
The estimates reported here support the views expressed by the CBO
and Mr Bullard that the output gap in the US is indeed smaller than
typical estimates suggest. Our estimates of the scar on output relative
to expectations in 2007 exceed those reported in most other
studies--primarily because we consider not only the direct impact of the
financial crisis and recession, but also the steep rise in the price of
oil over the past four years. Some caution should be used when
interpreting the impact of the oil price rise, as it is difficult to
extract permanent from transitory shifts in volatile commodity prices or
to identify, a satisfactory explanation for the price rise over this
period. In addition, research into alternative energy sources and new
gas discoveries in the US may reduce oil dependency over the medium
term.
Methodology
The methodological approach of the analysis presented in this note
is based on the framework developed by Barrell (2009) and extended by
Barrell and Kirby (2011) and Barrell, Delannoy and Holland (2011). It is
based on a production function approach to measuring capacity output,
and is comparable to the methodology used by the CBO (2011) to measure
capacity in the US, as well as studies by the IMF (2010) for the UK and
OECD (2010) for a broader spectrum of OECD economies. This Review has
discussed the magnitude of the scar on output in the UK in this context
on numerous occasions, but this is the first in-depth study in this
Review that is focused on the United States.
We model the potential output of an economy through an underlying
production function that relates the aggregate productive capacity of
the economy to the available units of production and the current state
of technology. We assume an underlying functional form that can be
expressed as:
Q = [gamma] [[delta] [K-.sup.[rho]] + (1 -
[delta])[[([Le.sup.[lambda]t]).sup.-[rho]].sup.-(1-[alpha])/[rho]]
[M.sup.[alpha]] (1)
where Q is output, K is the capital stock, L is labour input, t is
a labour augmenting technology measure and M is energy input. The
parameter [gamma] captures neutral technical progress, while [delta] is
a distribution parameter, [lambda] is the average rate of labour
augmenting technical progress, p is related to the elasticity of
substitution between labour and capital ([sigma] = 1/(1+ [rho])) and
[alpha] is the oil share of output in a base year. This framework
imposes a unit elasticity of substitution between oil input and the
labour-capital bundle, so that the share of oil costs in production is
constant in the long run, although adjustment towards this long run in
response to a price rise may be very protracted. The inner function
imposes a CES relationship between capital and labour, with an
elasticity of substitution between these two factors of production of
about 0.5. (1)
A loss of potential output within this framework must reflect a
decline in one or more of the available factors of production (L, K or
M), or a decline in the average level or rate of technical progress (or
productivity), which would be captured through a shift in [gamma],
[lambda] or t. A shift in relative prices can affect the relative demand
for factor inputs, while a shift in input costs relative to output costs
will affect demand for all factor inputs and the potential level of
production.
The associated cost minimising factor demands can be derived by
setting the marginal product of each factor to its real cost. In the
next section we look at the shocks that the US economy has sustained in
terms of input prices and available factors of production since 2007,
distinguishing between developments that affect labour input, capital
input and energy input. The impact on potential output in the US is
assessed through simulations using the National Institute's Global
Econometric Model, NiGEM. (2)
Shocks to labour input
The total labour input available to the production process can be
decomposed into a demographic component reflecting growth in the working
age population (this includes net immigration), the rate of
participation in the labour force, the average hours worked per employee
and the inverse of the unemployment rate (the share of the labour force
that is employed). Figure 1 puts developments in the labour input in the
US since 2007 into context with other advanced economies that were
affected by the financial crisis.
According to NIESR estimates, the average level of labour input in
the US in 2012 will be about 2 1/2 per cent below its level before the
financial crisis in 2007. A closer look at the contributions to the
change in labour input since 2007 illustrates some worrying
developments. While average hours of work appear to have more or less
reverted to pre-crisis trends (contrary to developments in the UK and
Japan), the unemployment rate remains high and the participation rate is
significantly below pre-crisis levels. This is largely masked by the
continued growth of the labour force driven by demographic developments.
The total shift in labour input is broadly in line with that observed in
the UK, and significantly less than the labour losses incurred in
Ireland and Spain. Labour input in the US has also declined by less than
that in Japan, although this is a reflection of differences in the
demographic developments in the two countries. Labour input in Germany
and France, on the other hand, has increased since 2007. Of the
countries illustrated in figure 1, only in the US and Ireland do we see
strong evidence that the rate of labour force participation has
deteriorated significantly since 2007. This may have long-term
implications for the productive capacity in these economies, as we
discuss in the context of the US below.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Labour force participation
Figure 2 illustrates the steady deterioration of labour force
participation in the US since the onset of the financial crisis. This
decline is in contrast to the general upward trend over a longer time
horizon since 1970, and in contrast to developments in most other
advanced economies since 2007, as discussed above. Labour force
participation in the US increased steadily between 1970 and 1990, (3)
and was more or less stable over the following decade. The downward
drift between 2001-2003 was never recovered, and it is worrying that we
have yet to see any sign of a correction to the steep decline in
participation since 2009, whereas the unemployment rate has started to
recede and average hours of work have reverted towards pre-crisis
levels. The CBO suggests that some of this drift reflects early
retirement and other withdrawals from the labour force, highlighting the
rise in applications for disability benefits. Extended periods of
unemployment are also associated with disconnection from the labour
force of discouraged workers. While not necessarily permanent, these
types of withdrawals may prove protracted.
We assess the potential impact of the recent 2 percentage point
shift in labour force participation, under the assumption that the full
shift in labour force participation proves long-lasting. This is clearly
a strong assumption, and somewhat more pessimistic than the assumptions
of the CBO, who expect labour force participation to regain 2008 levels
by 2021. However, a recent study by Aaronson et al. (2012) concludes
that labour force participation may continue to decline through 2020,
reflecting shifts in the demographic composition of the labour force. In
this case we may well be underestimating the ongoing shock to labour
input in the US. We have not observed anything like the decline in
labour force participation since 2009 during previous recessions or
periods of high unemployment, so it would be difficult to ascribe the
development to 'normal' cyclical behaviour that will
necessarily be reversed as economic conditions improve. Estimates based
on NiGEM simulations indicate that a 2 percentage point decline in
labour force participation would reduce the level of potential output in
the US economy by about 2 per cent compared to where we expected it to
be in 2007. These estimates are somewhat bigger than those suggested by
the CBO, which attributes 1/2 per cent loss of potential output to
labour force withdrawal, and should be viewed with an appropriate degree
of uncertainty.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Equilibrium rate of unemployment
There is also some evidence that the equilibrium rate of
unemployment, often referred to as the NAIRU, has increased since the
onset of the financial crisis. Over the period 2000-2007, an
unemployment rate of not more than about 5 per cent was generally
thought to be sustainable in the US. The Federal Reserve now estimates
that a medium-term target of about 6 per cent is more likely. This is in
line with the assessment of the NAIRU published by the CBO, which is
illustrated in figure 3. The 'short-term' NAIRU, which
incorporates structural factors that are temporarily boosting the
equilibrium rate of unemployment, is estimated to be roughly 1
percentage point higher than it was in 2006, while the
'long-term' NAIRU has also increased according to these
estimates by about 1/2 percentage point.
Long-term unemployment is at exceptionally high levels, as
illustrated in figure 4. The median duration of unemployment exceeds 20
weeks, significantly higher than at any other point since at least 1950
for which comparable statistics are available, while the mean duration
of unemployment stands at 40 weeks. The rise is partly linked to the
extension of eligibility for unemployment benefits from the standard 26
weeks to up to 99 weeks in 2009. Extended periods out of work are linked
to a permanent rise in the equilibrium rate of unemployment, as skills
depreciate and connections to the workforce erode. Significant
structural shifts in the economy, such as that observed in the
construction and housing market, may also be associated with protracted
periods of high unemployment, as the reallocation of labour across
sectors may be obstructed by skill mismatches. A sharp rise in the share
of homeowners suffering from negative equity --about 20 per cent of
those with mortgaged homes--may also affect the mobility of labour in
the short to medium term, delaying the reallocation of resources across
locations to their most productive uses, which may raise the equilibrium
level of unemployment for a protracted period.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
According to NiGEM simulations, a 1 percentage point rise in the
equilibrium rate of unemployment can be expected to reduce potential
output by about 1 per cent compared to its expected level before the
onset of the crisis. (4)
Average hours
While average weekly hours of work have reverted to pre-crisis
norms, the share of the population working part-time for economic
reasons (ie involuntarily) remains stubbornly high. This may reflect a
shift in preferences, perhaps as a precaution against the heightened
risk of periods of unemployment. Alternatively, it may point to some
form of measurement error in the assessment of average weekly hours of
work. If average working time remains below levels indicated, the shock
to labour input suffered since the recession may prove larger than our
current estimates suggest.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Risk premia and capital demand
We have argued many times in previous issues of this Review that
the financial crisis has been associated with a reappraisal of risk, and
that this rise in risk premia has driven the long-term expected user
cost of capital upwards, leading firms to reassess their desired level
of capital. Barrell (2009) illustrates that the magnitude of the output
scars suffered from this channel depend both on the magnitude of the
rise in the user cost of capital and on the initial capital-output ratio
of the economy. More capital intensive economies such as the US can be
expected to suffer greater losses as the economy adjusts to a lower
capital-output ratio.
Figure 6 illustrates the spread between corporate and government
bond yields in the US, which we use as a proxy for the corporate sector
borrowing premium to capture both the price and availability of credit
to firms. Corporate spreads in the US have receded from the peaks
reached in 2008-9, but remain elevated compared to their average level
in 2000-2006. We interpret this as a rise in the risk premium on
corporate borrowing relative to what had been expected and used in firm
development plans and bank lending decisions during the period leading
up to the financial crisis.
If we assume that this reappraisal of risk has raised the effective
user cost of capital by about 0.6 percentage points on a permanent
basis, compared to where we expected it to be before the financial
crisis, NiGEM simulations indicate that this will have reduced potential
output in the US by about 1/2 per cent. The CBO estimates also include a
scar from the loss of capital accumulation, although they do not
explicitly offer an explanation for this loss, only that the rebound in
investment "will probably not be enough by 2021 to offset all of
the capital accumulation that was foregone during the recession and
early recovery". Their estimates suggest that this reduces the
potential level of output in the US by about 1 per cent - roughly double
our estimates. We should allow for a margin of error around our
estimates.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Oil price and productive capacity
While it would be difficult to attribute the rise in the oil price
over the past four years to the financial crisis and global recession,
the price of energy nonetheless plays an important role in determining
the productive capacity of the economy. The unexpected upward shift in
prices must cause us to reassess the level of potential output in the US
compared to where we expected it to be in 2006. Figure 7 illustrates the
oil price assumptions underlying NIESR's current forecast, compared
to our average assumptions in 2007. While we observed significant
volatility at the height of the financial crisis itself, the dramatic
rise in the trend level of the oil price over this period is striking.
The average price in 2012 is expected to be roughly $55 per barrel
higher than anticipated in 2007--a rise of closes to 90 per cent in the
price level. While it is difficult to say with any certainty that the
observed rise is permanent, pricing in the futures markets is currently
consistent with this assumption.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
It is difficult to explain the sharp rise in the price of oil over
the last several years using simple models. Some studies have argued
that the shift partly reflects an unexpected rise in demand for energy
from China and India, and that this may be associated with an unexpected
rise in demand for other goods and services in these countries. The
stimulus from a global demand shock may partly offset the negative
impact of the price rise itself, which suggests that treating the rise
as exogenous, as we do in this study, may overstate the associated
decline in capacity. These estimates, therefore, should be interpreted
with caution.
In the longer term, we can expect the shift in the relative price
of factor inputs to induce firms to shift towards more energy-efficient
production processes and partially substitute the oil input with other
factors of production, such as labour and capital. A shift in the
relative price of oil will lead to a decline in demand for oil as a
factor input and a relative increase in demand for labour and capital.
If the initial factor bundle was optimal this will lead to a decline in
the productive potential of the economy and a permanent loss of output.
The magnitude of the long-term impact on output is driven by the oil
intensity of production, which is also given by [alpha] in our
production function described in equation (1) above.
Barrell, Delannoy and Holland (2011) relate the expected loss of
trend output in response to a permanent oil price rise to the oil
intensity of production across countries. As production in the US is
much more energy intensive than in countries such as the UK and France,
losses are expected to be greater in the US than elsewhere. (5)
According to our NiGEM simulations, the rise in the trajectory of oil
prices since 2007 may have reduced the potential level of output in the
economy by up to 4 per cent compared to where we expected it to be in
2007. This reassessment of the productive capacity of the US economy is
an important factor that most production function based studies of the
US output gap, such as the estimates of the CBO, are lacking.
Measuring the output gap
Output gap measurement is typically addressed either through
filtering techniques that extract a trend from the actual and projected
level of GDP, or through production function techniques, such as we
adopt in this study. The Hodrick-Prescott (HP) filter is the most
commonly used tool, although Barrell and Sefton (1995) demonstrate that
HP filters are subject to severe endpoint problems, especially if the
endpoint is affected by an unknown structural break. The HP filter tends
to follow the data too closely, because it is a symmetric filter. This
point is illustrated by the HP filter around US output produced by
Bullard (2012), which suggests that the US output gap had closed in the
second half of 2010, an assertion that would be difficult to reconcile
with an unemployment rate of 9 1/2 per cent and a level of output that
remained below its pre-crisis peak.
The production function approach that we adopt is similar to that
of the OECD, the IMF and the CBO, with our measure of trend output
related to inputs of labour, capital and oil, as discussed above. In
order to calibrate an estimate of the level of trend output we require
two assumptions--the total magnitude of the scar on potential output
that the economy has suffered since 2007 and underlying trend rate of
capacity growth abstracting from this loss. We estimate underlying trend
growth through the assumption that labour force participation and
average hours of work remain constant at the average levels of 2006-7,
while relative factor prices also remain stable, so that the desired
capital-output ratio and energy intensity of production are constant.
Trend growth can then be described through demographic developments and
through an assumption on the trend rate of productivity growth.
While endogenous growth theory tells us that productivity gains are
not exogenous, and indeed may be slower at a lower level of investment,
we make the simplifying assumption that the technology frontier has the
capacity to expand by roughly 1.8 per cent per annum, in line with its
historical average over the 15-year period leading up to the financial
crisis. Actual labour productivity growth in the US since 2008 has been
somewhat less than this on average, but the sample period is rather
short to establish a shift in the trend. In any case, if the scar on
output exceeds the scar on employment, we would expect a decline in the
level of productivity that may not necessarily affect the underlying
trend rate of growth. Nonetheless, this suggests that our estimates may
slightly overestimate trend growth since the crisis. The CBO makes an
explicit assumption on the effect of recession on productivity growth
until 2014, arguing that the downturn may delay the reallocation of
resources to their most productive uses, slow the rate at which workers
gain new skills as technologies evolve and curtail businesses'
spending on research and development. They estimate that the gross
impact on the level of potential output from the decline in productivity
growth is about 1/2 per cent, implying a decline of not more than 0.1
percentage points per annum for five years.
In figure 8, we illustrate the path of actual GDP in the US, and
compare this to a series of estimates for capacity output, cumulating
the potential scars on output discussed in this note. These can be
decomposed into the components attributable to the decline in labour
force participation, the rise in the NAIRU, the rise in risk premia and
the rise in the oil price. Our estimates point to a cumulative loss of
capacity of up to 7 1/2 per cent since 2007. Of this, about half is
attributable to the rise in risk premia and decline in labour input,
with the other half attributable to the unexpected 90 per cent rise in
the oil price over this period. The loss of labour input probably
reflects a combination of lingering effects from the financial crisis as
well as effects from the rise in commodity input prices, and it is
difficult to distinguish between the two. Studies that focus exclusively
on the scarring from the financial crisis are clearly omitting a vital
component of factors driving a reassessment of the level of potential
output across oil importing nations. There is also a question around the
extent to which the calibrated losses to potential output are permanent,
or whether they can either self-correct or be corrected through policy
intervention. The scars on labour input clearly have the potential to be
reversed, although it is not yet clear that this reversal will take
place without policy assistance. We would also reiterate the risk around
our oil price assumptions as there is a high level of uncertainty around
the future path for oil prices.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Our estimates reported in figure 8 suggest that the US economy is
still suffering from a shortfall in demand, with an output gap of at
least 2 per cent. Estimates that take no account of the loss of output
potential since 2007 would put the gap at something closer to 9 per
cent, which is clearly out of line with other measures of spare capacity
in the economy, such as the unemployment rate and the rate of capacity
utilisation in industry (although caution should be attached to business
survey estimates of capacity utilisation, since by definition they only
capture the spare capacity of the existing firms and not the wider
economy). An output gap of 2 per cent would be significantly smaller
than most studies suggest. The CBO puts the US output gap at about 5 3/4
per cent, while the OECD estimates a gap of 3.6 per cent and the IMF a
gap of 4.9 per cent. This note highlights the risk that these estimates
may overstate the level of spare capacity in the US. An output gap of 2
per cent would not be out of line with other measures of spare capacity
in the economy. The unemployment rate is currently about 2 percentage
points above the CBO and Federal Reserve estimates of the equilibrium
rate. The Federal Reserve's estimate of the rate of total
industrial capacity utilisation stands at roughly 1 1/2-2 percentage
points below its average in 2006-7. NIESR's forecast presented in
this Review sees both the output gap and the unemployment rate gap in
the US closing by 2015-16.
REFERENCES
Aaronson, D., Davis, J. and Hu, L. (2012), 'Explaining the
decline in the US labor force participation rate', Chicago Fed
Letter, March 2012, No. 296.
Barrell, R. (2009), 'Long-term scarring from the financial
crisis', National Institute Economic Review, 210, pp. 36-38.
Barrell, R. and Kirby, S. (2011), 'Trend output and the output
gap in the UK', National Institute Economic Review, 215, pp.
F63-F74.
Barrell, R. and Sefton, J. (1995), 'Output gaps: some evidence
for the UK, France and Germany', National Institute Economic
Review, 151.
Barrell, R. and Pain, N. (1997), 'Foreign Direct Investment,
technological change, and economic growth within Europe', Economic
Journal, 107, pp. 1770-6.
Barrell, R., Delannoy, A. and Holland, D. (2011), 'Monetary
policy, output growth and oil prices', National Institute Economic
Review, 215, pp. F37-F43.
Bullard, J. (2012), 'The U.S. monetary policy outlook',
presented at InvestMidwest Venture Capital Forum, St. Louis, Missouri,
April 2012.
CBO (2011), 'Persistent effects of the recent recession on
potential output', Box 2.2 in The Budget and Economic Outlook: An
Update, August 2011, pp. 54-5.
Ellis, C. and Price, S. (2004), 'UK business investment and
the user cost of capital', Manchester School, 72, pp. 72-93.
IMF (2010), United Kingdom: Selected Issues Paper, IMF country
report 10/337.
OECD (2010), 'Prospects for growth and imbalances beyond the
short term', Economic Outlook, 2010/1.
NOTES
(1) Our estimate of the elasticity of substitution is in line with
studies such as Barrell and Pain (1997) and Ellis and Price (2004) and
outperforms the standard unit elasticity imposed by a Cobb-Douglas
relationship between labour and capital.
(2) A brief overview of NiGEM is given in the Key Assumptions
section of the world economy forecast chapter and further detail is
available from http://nimodel.niesr.ac.uk.
(3) This is largely a reflection of increased female participation
in the labour force.
(4) Technically this is effected by introducing a wedge between
wages and prices, sufficient to reduce demand for labour by I per cent
and increase the unemployment rate by I percentage point relative to
baseline.
(5) The calculation of energy intensity is based on final
consumption, which nets out the effects from the oil production sector
itself.
doi: 10.1177/002795011222000108