Fiscal consolidation during a depression.
Bagaria, Nitika ; Holland, Dawn ; Van Reenen, John 等
The financial crisis and resulting recession led to sharp rises in
government deficits in almost all major industrialised countries,
primarily because of falls in tax receipts. This was further increased
by fiscal stimulus packages and emergency financial sector support. This
in turn has led to a sharp rise in global government debt, giving rise
to concerns about long-term fiscal sustainability. Despite this,
long-term interest rates remain low in virtually all major developed
economies outside the Euro Area, reflecting the fact that growth is weak
and short-term interest rates are expected to remain low. However, many
of the major economies have introduced fiscal tightening measures in
recent years despite the widespread slowdown in GDP growth, and a level
of GDP that remains well below that of 2007. The IMF estimates that the
overall global fiscal position tightened by 1 per cent of GDP in 2011
(IME 2012a). Meanwhile, in the Euro Area, where countries can neither
finance their deficits through quantitative easing or adjust via the
exchange rate, market pressures on some countries have been intense, and
austerity programmes have been introduced in a number of countries in an
attempt to stem the rise in sovereign debt and ease the pressure on bond
yields.
Although the long-term government borrowing rates are at historic
lows in the UK, it is clearly the case that over the medium to long term
fiscal consolidation is essential for debt sustainability. The UK has
announced fiscal consolidation measures amounting to a total of 7.4 per
cent of GDP over the fiscal years 2011-12 to 2016-17. Table 1 details
the current plans by period and instrument.
In this paper we assess the impact of the scale and timing of this
fiscal consolidation programme on output and unemployment in the UK. We
begin by using the National Institute's model, NiGEM, to analyse the impact of the ongoing policy on the UK economy using the standard
version of the model, which would reflect the impact in
'normal' times. However, we do not appear to be in
'normal' times but in a prolonged period of depression, which
we define as a period when output is depressed below its previous peak.
As Delong and Summers (2012), Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) and
others point out, the impact of fiscal tightening during a depression
may be different from that in normal times. There are a number of
channels that the differences may feed through; for each we modify NiGEM
to take account of the differential impacts.
First, there is the interest rate response. Under normal
circumstances a tightening in fiscal policy can be expected to be
accommodated by a relaxation in monetary policy. However, with interest
rates already at exceptionally low levels, further tightening of fiscal
policy is unlikely to result in such an offsetting monetary policy
reaction. While quantitative easing/credit easing measures have been
introduced, the effects of these measures are also limited by low
interest rates on 'risk-free' assets. It is less clear that
monetary easing measures have a significant impact on the risk premia
attached to assets that bear a greater risk of default.
Second, during a downturn, when unemployment is high and job
security low, a greater percentage of households and firms are likely to
find themselves liquidity constrained. This is likely to be particularly
acute when the downturn is driven by an impaired banking system, as
lending conditions will tighten beyond what would be expected in a
normal downturn. There is less scope to smooth consumption in response
to short-term income losses through an adjustment in savings.
Finally, long spells of depressed output and high unemployment can
lead to 'hysteresis' which keeps the productive capacity of
the economy persistently or even permanently lower (for example through
the 'scarring' effect of unemployment which we discuss below).
The economy may converge to the steady state levels of output and
employment in the very long run, but in the medium term output levels
could be substantially lower due to hysteresis effects. The time the
economy takes to converge to the long-run steady state is also
prolonged.
In this note we consider the potential impact on the economy, both
in the short and long term, of postponing the planned consolidation
measures that were introduced from 2011-12 onwards until the UK economy
has emerged from the current period of depression and the output gap has
narrowed significantly. While our analysis is not strictly dependent on
the length of this delay, NiGEM-based estimates suggest that, in the
absence of fiscal tightening, the output gap in the UK would be
approaching balance by 2014. In the absence of deeper and more prolonged
financial distress driven by events in the Euro Area, we would then have
anticipated a 'normal' response to the fiscal consolidation
measures after 2014, rather than the rather larger response that may
result in the current period of depressed output and high unemployment.
In order to decompose the channels of transmission, we present four
separate scenarios. In the first scenario, we illustrate the expected
impact on output and employment of the fiscal programme detailed in
table 1, had it been introduced in normal times, rather than during a
period of depression. We then consider, one at a time, three channels
that may differ during a period of depression: the impacts of an
impaired interest rate channel; the impacts of heightened liquidity
constraints; and the impacts of hysteresis, all of which exacerbate the
impact of the consolidation programme on output and unemployment. In the
final section, we construct a combined scenario that cumulates the
effects of all three channels, and illustrates our estimate of the
impact of the consolidation programme as it has been put forward, during
a period of depression with limited downward flexibility in interest
rates, heightened liquidity constraints and rising levels of long-term
unemployment. We compare this to a scenario with no fiscal
consolidation, and one where the same consolidation programme is
introduced with a delay (2014-20), when the economy is expected to have
returned to normal conditions. This allows us to estimate the cumulative
impact that may be associated with the early introduction of the
consolidation programme.
Scenario 1: Impact of fiscal programme in normal times
Fiscal multipliers (1) are not uniform either across countries
(e.g. Ilzetzki et al., 2010), across time or across instruments (e.g.
tax vs. spending). Barrell et al. (2012) provides an overview of NiGEM
and compares estimates of fiscal multipliers across instruments for a
set of seventeen OECD economies. In general, spending multipliers tend
to be larger than tax multipliers in the first year, as tax adjustments
are partially offset through savings and feed in more gradually. For the
UK, they find a direct spending multiplier of about 0.5-0.7 per cent in
the first year, while tax multipliers averaged about 0.1-0.2 per cent.
(2) Much of the current consolidation plan is spending based, and so can
be expected to have a more significant impact on GDP in the short term.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
In figure 1, we illustrate the impact on the level of GDP and the
unemployment rate that we would expect in response to the current fiscal
programme outlined in table 1, were it introduced in 'normal'
times, e.g. when the output gap is close to balance and unemployment is
close to its equilibrium level. We hold the exchange rate fixed in this
scenario, as exchange rate behaviour depends not just on the policy
adopted in the UK, but on the relative stance of UK fiscal policy in a
global context. Where many major economies are consolidating
simultaneously, the assumption of a neutral impact on the exchange rate
is probably justified. If the UK is tightening relatively more than its
trading partners, we would expect to see a modest depreciation of the
exchange rate, whereas if it is tightening relatively less than its
partners the exchange rate would appreciate, holding all other risk
factors constant.
We would expect the level of output to decline by 0.4 per cent
relative to the baseline in the first year, reaching a peak of 2.3 per
cent below base after six years. Over the longer term, we would expect
both GDP and unemployment to return to levels that would have been
anticipated in the absence of fiscal consolidation. The normal cyclical behaviour of the model suggests that output would rise slightly above
base and unemployment fall slightly below base after year 11, although
these effects would not persist over the longer term. The loss of
government investment can be expected to have a negative impact on the
productive capacity of the economy in the longer term, but these effects
are relatively small. Unemployment is brought back towards base levels
as output recovers, and through an adjustment in real wages.
In general, a fiscal tightening can be expected to be accompanied
by a monetary loosening, as an inflation targeting central bank
maintains a given inflation target with rower rates of interest.
However, not all fiscal instruments have the same impact on inflation.
One of the instruments employed in the fiscal consolidation programme
outlined in table 1 is the indirect tax, or VAT, rate. A rise in the VAT
rate will initially put upward pressure on inflation, as it is a direct
shock to the price level. This may induce an inflation targeting central
bank to raise interest rates in the short term. After the first year or
so, the jump in the price level would fall out of the inflation rate,
and we would expect inflation to be somewhat below what it would have
been in the absence of the VAT rise, allowing a lower interest rate over
the medium term.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Our preliminary scenario reflecting the response in
'normal' times allows an endogenous response in short-term
interest rates. (3) In normal times, the fiscal programme described in
table 1 would initially put upward pressure on interest rates, as the
indirect tax rate rises by 250 basis points, with a direct impact on
inflation in the first year of the shock. As the effects of the VAT rise
dissipate, this is followed by an extended period of short-term policy
interest rates below base. With forward-looking financial markets, the
long-term interest rate, which determines the borrowing costs of firms
for investment, is driven by the expected path of short-term interest
rates over a 10-year forward horizon. As such, despite the initial rise
in the short-term rates, long-term interest rates fall immediately,
stimulating investment and offsetting part of the fiscal contraction.
The expected impact on short-term and long-term interest rates in
response to the policy, were it to be introduced during
'normal' times, is illustrated in figure 2. Long-term interest
rates would be expected to fall by about 150 basis points for an
extended period, allowing a strong boost to investment.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Impact of fiscal programme in a depressed economy
Scenario 2: Impaired interest rate channel
In the previous section we considered the impact of a fiscal
consolidation in normal times, and demonstrated that, under normal
circumstances, the consolidation programme detailed in table 1 would be
expected to reduce long-term interest rates by about 150 basis points
for several years. However, when interest rates are close to zero, their
downward flexibility may be restricted (the 'zero lower
bound'). With no offsetting stimulus from lower interest rates, the
impact of the fiscal consolidation programme on GDP would be somewhat
higher. Ten-year government bond yields in the UK are not at zero, but
are exceptionally low, suggesting that there may be little scope for
further reductions. If we hold long-term interest rates fixed, rather
than allowing them to decline as in the first scenario, the negative
effects on output and unemployment would be amplified. Figures 3 and 4
compare the impact on GDP and the unemployment rate under normal times
with an endogenous interest rate response, to the same consolidation
programme in an environment where there is no downward flexibility of
interest rates. The impact on GDP would be about 1 1/2 per cent greater
after four years if the interest rate adjustment channel is impaired,
while the unemployment rate would be expected to rise by a further 3/4
percentage point.
Scenario 3: Heightened liquidity constraints
In the presence of perfect capital markets and forward-looking
consumers with perfect foresight, households will smooth their
consumption path over time, and consumer spending will be largely
invariant to the state of the economy or temporary fiscal innovations.
In the extreme example of a fully Ricardian world, the fiscal multiplier
is effectively zero, as fiscal policy will simply be offset by private
sector adjustments to savings behaviour. However, at any given time,
some fraction of the population and of firms is liquidity constrained;
that is, they have little or no access to borrowing, so that their
current spending is largely restrained by their current income. In the
first scenario, we make the assumption that savings behaviour and the
number of liquidity constrained consumers and businesses are as in
normal times. However, in a prolonged period of depressed activity, this
is unlikely to be the case, especially when the downturn has at its
roots an impaired banking system.
In this section we consider the effects of an increase in the share
of consumers and firms that are liquidity constrained. We operationalise
this effect in the NiGEM model through an adjustment to the short-term
income elasticity of consumption and investment. If liquidity
constraints are not important, households and firms can borrow when
incomes or profits are low in order to smooth their spending path. In
this case, the path of consumption and investment will be less sensitive
to short-term fluctuations in income or profits. However, when liquidity
constraints are high, there is less scope to borrow to smooth spending,
and consumption and investment will be much more reliant on current
revenue streams. A detailed illustration of the sensitivity of the
scenarios to assumptions on the short-term income elasticity parameters
is given in the Appendix.
In the standard version of NiGEM, the short-term income elasticity
of consumption in the UK is given by 0.17, suggesting a relatively low
level of liquidity constraints. Barrell, Holland and Hurst {2012) put
this into an internationally comparative context, which suggests that UK
liquidity constraints are on the low side, but not out of line with
other advanced economies. The short-term elasticity of investment to GDP
is between 1 and 2 per cent, with business investment more sensitive to
the state of the economy than housing investment.
We now consider the impact on output and unemployment that we would
expect when liquidity constraints are heightened. Figures 4 and 5
illustrate the expected impact on output and the unemployment rate of
the consolidation programme detailed in table 1 if it were introduced in
'normal' times (scenario 1), and compares this to a scenario
with moderately heightened liquidity constraints (model 4 in the
Appendix) and high liquidity constraints (model 7 in Appendix table A1).
The moderate scenario can be interpreted as representing an environment
where the number of liquidity constrained consumers is roughly double
that in normal times, while the high liquidity constraints scenario
reflects an environment where the number of liquidity constrained
consumers is twice that in the moderate scenario. In all three scenarios
we allow an endogenous adjustment of both short-term and long-term
interest rates. Under high liquidity constraints, we would expect output
to decline by 1/2 per cent more in the first year than it would in
normal times. The unemployment rate can be expected to increase by 0.25
percentage points more in the first year compared to the first normal
times scenario. By year 7, the differences between the three scenarios
are largely eliminated.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Scenario 4: Presence of hysteresis
Extended periods of depressed output and high unemployment can have
long-term implications for the productive capacity of the economy. A
host of mechanisms could be responsible for these hysteresis effects.
These include reduced capital investment, premature capital scrapping,
reduced labour force attachment on the part of the long-term unemployed
resulting in lower wage pressures, scarring effects on young workers who
have trouble beginning their careers and changes in managerial
attitudes. In particular, the incidence of long-term unemployment may
reduce the downward pressure on wages exerted by a high general
unemployment rate and thus lead to unemployment hysteresis or
persistence long after the shocks have dissipated. We focus on this
labour market channel of hysteresis in this paper. This does not mean
that the other potential channels of hysteresis are unimportant. (4)
A potential explanation of hysteresis effects is that a decrease in
aggregate demand initially causes a rise in short-term unemployment, but
this turns into long-term unemployment if the depression continues. As
the survival rate (in unemployment) for the long-term unemployed is
higher, (5) they put less downward pressure on wages and inflation and
so can contribute to the persistence of unemployment into the medium
term. Machin and Manning (1999) model this in an efficiency wage
framework. Similar results are found in Blanchard and Diamond (1994) in
a matching model context, Calmfors and Lang (1995) and Manning (1993) in
the context of a union bargaining model. Thus, high long-term
unemployment has been argued to be a cause of high unemployment itself.
However, it is still possible that the unemployment rate returns to its
steady state NAIRU in the very long run.
Alternatively, it is highly likely that the long-term unemployed
may cease to participate in the labour market altogether. There is
sparse evidence on the decline in participation rate of those who have
been unemployed for a prolonged period. More recently, it has been
observed that in the US, the labour force participation rate plummeted
during the Great Recession. It declined from a peak of 66.5 per cent in
2007 to 62 per cent in 2012. (6) The demographic trend relating to the
retirement of the 'baby boom' generation, which has been
ongoing since the turn of the century, is a slow-moving generational
trend and cannot explain this substantial recent decline. This seems to
suggest that this decline is at least in part a result of the labour
market pressures arising from the 2008 crisis. (7) By contrast, in the
UK, labour force participation has held up relatively well compared with
previous recessions, although long-term unemployment has risen sharply.
The standard model for wages within NiGEM is based around a profit
maximising condition that sets the marginal product of labour equal to
the real wage. The price and wage equations are determined by the first
order profit maximising conditions. Using a CES-style of production
function, this can be described as:
ln (w/p) = [alpha] + 1/[sigma] ln (ycap/l) - 1-[sigma]/[sigma]
techl (1)
where w/p is the real wage, ycap is potential or capacity output, 1
is labour input, techl is labour augmenting technical progress, [sigma]
is the elasticity of substitution between labour and capital and [alpha]
is a constant term.
This forms the long-run relationship and the firm side of the wage
bargain. The unemployment rate acts as the bargaining instrument to
bring labour demand in line with labour supply. We embed this into a
dynamic equation of the form:
[DELTA]ln(w) = [[omega].sub.1] +[[omega].sub.2]{ln[(w/p).sub.-1]-
1/[sigma] ln [(ycap/l).sub.-1] + 1 - [sigma]/[sigma] [techl.sub.1} +
[[omega].sub.3][DELTA] ln(p)+(1-[[omega].sub.3])[DELTA] ln([p.sup.e]) +
[[omega].sub.4] ([U.sub.-1]) (2)
where U is the unemployment rate, [DELTA] is the difference
operator, [[omega].sub.1]- [[omega].sub.4] are parameters and
superscript e denotes expectations.
When the unemployment rate rises, this puts downward pressure on
real wage growth. Firms can then afford to employ more workers, which
brings labour demand in line with labour supply, and pushes unemployment
back towards its equilibrium.
Arguably, those who have been unemployed for an extended period of
time begin to search for work less intensively, or because of
'scarring' effects on skills or motivation, may simply not be
regarded as suitable potential workers by employers. They may thus exert
less pressure on wages than those who have been unemployed for only a
short period. A more sophisticated model would, therefore, differentiate
the unemployed by their duration out of work, and allow the wage
elasticity to decline as the duration rises. In order to allow for this
form of hysteresis we consider what we define as the long-term
unemployed (LTU)--those who have been unemployed for twelve months or
longer--separately from total unemployment.
It is difficult to identify empirically differences in the wage
elasticities of different groups of unemployed, given the very strong
correlation among the duration groups and unobserved heterogeneity between groups. In order to calibrate the differences in wage pressure,
we draw on the study by Elsby and Smith (2010), who calculate the
unemployment-to-employment transition rate by duration for the UK (see
figure 9, p. R35 in Elsby and Smith, 2010). Those unemployed for longer
face markedly lower job-finding rates. Job seekers with more than twelve
months duration find jobs at an average rate of just over 4 per cent per
month, whereas the total pool of unemployed find jobs at an average rate
of 10 per cent per month, using a sample that covers 1992-2010. This
would suggest that long-term unemployed exert about 60 per cent less
pressure on wages than the total pool of unemployed.
We, thus, construct an augmented wage equation, which incorporates
wage-bargaining that is less sensitive to the long-term unemployment
rate, using an equation of the form:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
where LTU is the long-term unemployment rate. We assume
[[omega].sub.4] < 0 to reflect the bargaining process.
Some older studies, for example Nickell (1987), find a somewhat
stronger feedback from LTU to wages. The sample used for estimation in
his paper covers 1953-83, and so may be less relevant for today, given
the significant changes to the labour market that have occurred since
1979. Nonetheless, we consider an alternative scenario, where the
long-term unemployed have essentially stopped searching altogether, and
so put no pressure on wages:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
This can be viewed as an upper limit to the potential effects
through this channel. However, it should not be interpreted as an upper
limit to the effects of hysteresis overall. Hysteresis may set in
earlier than we allow for here--for example after six months rather than
after twelve months. And the potential for labour market withdrawal
could lead to significantly more prolonged effects on the productive
capacity of the economy.
The impact of LTU on wages will also depend on how we model the
rate of long-term unemployment itself. OECD (2009) estimates a simple
relationship between the total unemployment rate and the long-term
unemployment rate. For the UK, the relationship they identify is:
LTU = 0.76 * [LTU.sub.-1] - 0.29 * [LTU.sub.2] + 0.34 * U (5)
We use this relationship, rewritten in error correction format, to
model LTU in the revised NiGEM model. The equation can be written as:
[DELTA]LTU = 0.29 * [[DELTA]LTU.sub.-1] + 0.34 * [DELTA]U
-0.53{[LTU.sub.-1] - 0.64 * [U.sub.-1]} (6)
Figures 7 and 8 illustrate the expected impact on output and the
unemployment rate in the presence of labour market hysteresis effects,
and compares our 'normal times' scenario to the two augmented
wage equations discussed above-where the long-term unemployed exert 60
per cent less pressure on wages than shorter-term unemployed, and where
the long-term unemployed exert no pressure on wages. In order to
decompose the effects, we assume the interest rate channel is not
impaired and liquidity constraints are not important. An important point
of comparison with the baseline (scenario 1) is the much slower speed
with which output returns to supply equilibrium; in other words,
hysteresis not only magnifies the negative impacts of fiscal
consolidation on output and employment, but means that they are much
more long-lasting.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
By introducing tightening during a period of high unemployment and
large output gap, the negative impacts of the consolidation programme
can be expected to persist for 2-4 years longer than they would have if
the policy had been postponed until the level of unemployment had
reverted to its long-run equilibrium.
Cumulative impacts
Based on the results of the scenarios presented above, we can
calibrate an estimate of the cumulative impacts on the economy from
introducing fiscal tightening starting in 2011, rather than postponing
the measures until output and unemployment had recovered from the
downturn. The impact is partly driven by the heightened magnitude of
fiscal multipliers, and exacerbated by the prolongation of their impact
due to hysteresis effects. As an illustrative scenario, we assume that
the interest rate response is impaired, with no adjustment in the
long-term interest rate. We allow for moderately high liquidity
constraints, so assume that the number of liquidity constrained agents
is roughly double what it is in normal times (model 4 in the Appendix),
and model wages as in equation 3 above, with the long-term unemployed
exerting 60 per cent less pressure on wages than total unemployment.
Changing this set of assumptions could lead to a stronger or weaker
impact on the economy than shown here, as demonstrated by the
sensitivity of the results to the scenarios reported above.
Figures 9-11 illustrate projections for GDP growth, the
unemployment rate and government debt as a ratio to GDP that we would
anticipate under three different scenarios. The first reflects our
assessment of the fiscal consolidation programme for 2011-17 as reported
in table 1, introduced during the current environment of a depressed
economy with moderately high liquidity constraints. This is consistent
with the baseline forecast for the UK presented in this Review, and we
designate this scenario as 'consolidate during a depression'.
The second scenario illustrates the path that we would have expected had
the consolidation programme been , delayed until economic recovery was
well underway, b which model-based estimates suggest would have been by
about 2014 in the absence of early fiscal tightening.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
The programme detailed in table 1 is implemented, but the timing is
shifted so that it is enacted over the period 2014-20, with no
consolidation measures introduced 2011-14. We designate this scenario as
'consolidate during normal times'. Finally we illustrate a
scenario that shows the economic path that would have been expected in
the absence of any consolidation programme, which we designate as
'no consolidation'. Scenarios 2 and 3 are identical for the
first three years.
A number of studies have looked at the links between the risk
premium on government borrowing and fiscal sustainability, captured by
current or expected values of the general government deficit or the
stock of government debt (Laubach, 2009; Baldacci and Kumar, 2010;
Schuknect et al, 2010; Bernoth and Erdogan, 2012 and others). These
studies suggest that rising government debt is likely eventually to put
upward pressure on interest rates, so that fiscal tightening is likely
to be necessary at some point. Figure 11 indeed illustrates that in the
absence of any fiscal tightening, the stock of government debt would
have been on a steadily rising and almost certainly unsustainable path
over the next decade. The option not to consolidate at all, therefore,
was and is not a viable one. However, the differences between the debt
profiles reflecting early consolidation and delayed consolidation are
relatively modest, and the likely impact on interest rates is therefore
small. Empirical estimates, on average, point to a 2-4 basis point rise
in interest rates for a 1 per cent of GDP rise in the government debt to
GDP ratio. A 10 percentage point differential, therefore, would be
expected to induce at most a 40 basis point rise in borrowing costs.
Even this may overstate the impacts for non-Euro Area countries. IMF
(2012b) points out that, "fiscal indicators such as deficit and
debt levels appear to be weakly related to government bond yields for
advanced economies with monetary independence".
The scenarios suggest that the recession in 2012 could have been
avoided had fiscal tightening measures been delayed. Table 2 details the
differences between the two scenarios in level terms. Our estimates
indicate that the cumulative loss of output from early consolidation
accumulated over the period 2011-21 amounts to 239 billion [pounds
sterling] in constant 2010 prices. This is equivalent to 16 1/2 per cent
of 2010 GDP (or about 1.3 per cent of total output over the entire
period). These losses are sustained despite the fact that the growth
rate of GDP is expected to be higher after 2016 under the early
consolidation scenario compared to the delayed consolidation scenario,
as consolidation measures in the latter are ongoing until 2020. In the
long run, the level of GDP in the three scenarios should converge to a
common level. Figure 1 indicates that the negative impact on output of
the fiscal consolidation programme initiated in normal times can be
expected to dissipate by eleven years after the onset of the programme,
so that by 2025 the growth rate of GDP should converge in all three
scenarios. A substantial permanent deadweight loss associated with the
early consolidation programme will persist, as the amplified losses in
the early years will not be fully offset by amplified gains once
recovery sets in.
Similarly, the unemployment rate is expected to be higher until
2018 under the early consolidation programme than it would have been
with a delayed fiscal tightening, as shown in figure 10. In the long
run, the level of the unemployment rate can be expected to converge to
the same level in all three scenarios. It may take 10-11 years for these
effects to feed through. The 'consolidate in a depression'
scenario sees the unemployment rate falling below that of the
'consolidation in normal times' scenario over the period
2019-21. This reflects the fact that the delayed consolidation programme
comes to an end only in 2020, whereas in the early consolidation
scenario the recovery has been ongoing for three years, and the
differences can be expected to dissipate by 2024. More importantly, the
unemployment rate in the delayed scenario would never be expected to
exceed 7 per cent.
Conclusions
The concern today is that the Great Recession starting in 2008 and
the consequent early fiscal tightening policies may lead to significant
losses in output and a protracted period of high unemployment. The
analysis presented in this note indicates that these concerns are
well-founded. Under current policy plans the unemployment rate is
expected to remain above 7 per cent until 2016. Had tightening measures
been delayed until economic recovery was well underway, cumulation
output on the period 2011-21 would have been significantly higher, and
the unemployment rate would have been expected to rise no higher than 7
per cent over the next decade. In light of the above results, it can be
argued that fiscal policy choices have to be considered in the light of
the monetary policy response function. When monetary policy is
constrained by the zero lower bound on interest rates, the impact of
fiscal policy (the fiscal multiplier) will be magnified compared to
normal times. The health of the banking sector is also an important
determining factor. When unemployment is high or job security low, a
greater percentage of households and firms are likely to find themselves
liquidity constrained. This is likely to be particularly acute when the
downturn is driven by an impaired banking system, as lending conditions
will tighten beyond what would be expected in an ordinary downturn.
Heightened liquidity constraints amplify the effects of any
contractionary policy on output and unemployment.
This study is necessarily narrow, and does not take into account a
number of factors that may also cause the impacts of a policy innovation
introduced in normal times to differ from that observed during a
prolonged downturn. For example, there may be additional effects on
savings behaviour, hysteresis effects may also be deeper and more
prolonged, and interest rates may respond more significantly if the link
between the magnitude of government debt and government borrowing premia
is important.
Ball (1996) finds that inadequate responses to recessions have
contributed to hysteresis in some countries. A corollary conclusion is
that policies of deficit reduction in the presence of substantial output
shortfalls will have adverse impacts in both the short and long run. The
standard policy prescription--to delay deficit reduction until after
recovery is clearly under way and the output shortfall significantly
reduced--remains valid.
Appendix A. Fiscal multipliers and liquidity constraints
In this appendix we illustrate the sensitivity of the estimated
fiscal multipliers to assumptions on the short-term income elasticity of
consumption and investment. In the presence of perfect capital markets
and forward-looking consumers with perfect foresight, households will
smooth their consumption path over time, and consumer spending will be
largely invariant to the state of the economy or temporary fiscal
innovations. However, some fraction of the population at any given time
is liquidity constrained with little or no access to borrowing, so that
their current consumption is largely restrained by their current income.
The share of the population that is liquidity constrained will affect
the short-term income elasticity of consumption, given by parameter [b.sub.1] from equation (A1) below:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A1)
where C is consumption, TAW is total asset wealth, which is the sum
of net financial wealth (NW) and tangible wealth (HW), RPDI is real
personal disposable income, [DELTA] is the difference operator, and the
remaining symbols are parameters.
Cross-country differences in the average short-term income
elasticity of consumption have a strong correlation with the tax
multipliers, as highlighted by Barrell, Holland and Hurst (2012).
However, access to credit is dependent both on credit history and on
current income, and so is necessarily sensitive to the state of the
economy. As unemployment rises, a greater share of the population will
be unable to access credit at reasonable rates of interest--at precisely
the moment when they are in need of borrowing to smooth their
consumption path. This means that consumption is likely to be cyclical,
and that [b.sub.1] is likely to be time varying and dependent on the
position in the cycle. Following a banking crisis the effects can be
expected to be particularly acute, as banks tighten lending criteria, as
discussed by Barrell, Fic and Liadze (2009). This also suggests that
fiscal multipliers are dependent on the state of the economy--especially
tax innovation multipliers--and this is consistent with recent studies
such as Delong and Summers (2012) and Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012).
Investment is always more cyclically sensitive than consumer
spending, but these effects may be particularly amplified when the
banking system is impaired. We model investment as an adjustment towards
a desired capital stock. The stock of capital is one of the factors of
production underlying the supply-side of the economy, and a profit
maximising condition that sets the marginal product of capital equal to
its price (the user cost of capital) leads to the following long-run
relationship.
ln(K/ycap] = [[alpha].sub.1] - [sigma] ln(user) (12)
where K is the capital stock, ycap is potential GDP, user is the
tax adjusted user cost of capital and [sigma] is the elasticity of
substitution between labour and capital.
Embedded within a dynamic framework, the standard equation to model
capital demand in NiGEM is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A3)
Where y is real GDP.
From this we determine investment through the identity
relationship:
[I.sub.t] = [K.sub.t] - (1 - dep)[K.sub.t-1] (A4)
Where I is gross investment and dep is the depreciation rate.
We distinguish between housing and business investment as the
dynamics of behaviour are significantly different for the two. The
parameters [[delta].sub.4] and [[delta].sub.5] may be sensitive to the
position of the cycle and particularly to the health of the banking
sector.
In order to assess the sensitivity of fiscal multipliers to the
magnitude of liquidity constraints, we run our consolidation scenario
under a series of eleven different models, allowing the parameters
[b.sub.1], [[delta].sub.4] and [[delta].sub.5] to rise incrementally.
The models allow [b.sub.1] to rise from 0, which implies perfect capital
markets with no liquidity constraints, to 1, which implies that all
current income is spent on consumption, with no scope for saving and
smoothing consumption. In our standard model, the estimated parameter
for [b.sub.1] is given by 0.17056, suggesting a relatively low level of
liquidity constraints historically. Barrell, Holland and Hurst (2012)
put this into an internationally comparative context, which suggests
that UK liquidity constraints are on the low side, but not out of line
with other advanced economies. Choosing appropriate values for
[[delta].sub.4] and [[delta].sub.5] is somewhat less straightforward, as
a 1 per cent increase in the capital stock is equivalent to a 50-100 per
cent increase in the investment flow. The estimated parameters of the
standard NiGEM model are 0.042 ([[delta].sub.4b]) and 0.013
([[delta].sub.5b]) for business capital and ([[delta].sub.44]) and 0.01
([[delta].sub.5]h) for housing capital. We calibrate the parameters by
centring so that the NiGEM standard model is between model 2 and 3 in
the table below. The [[delta].sub.5] parameters are set to maintain the
ratio of [[delta].sub.4]/[[delta].sub.5] in the standard version of
NiGEM.
The estimated impact on GDP of the consolidation scenario, under
different assumptions on the short-run income elasticity of consumption
and investment are reported in table A1 below. With no liquidity
constraints, we would expect the policy to reduce output by just 0.2 per
cent in the first year, while with no options for borrowing to smooth
consumption we would expect output to decline by 1.4 per cent. Our
standard model predicts that the fiscal policy would reduce output by
0.4 per cent in the first year, under normal conditions with limited
liquidity constraints. Differences between the different models
dissipate by year 7.
Table A1. Impact of consolidation programme on UK GDP, under different
short-term income elasticities consumption and investment
Model 1 2 3
Short-run income elasticity of
consumption ([b.sub.1]) 0 0.1 0.2
Short-run capital-output
elasticity (business) ([[delta].sub.4b]) 0.035 0.042 0.049
Short-run capital-output
elasticity (housing) ([[delta].sub.4h]) 0.012 0.015 0.018
Year 1 -0.22 -0.30 -0.39
Year 2 -0.44 -0.51 -0.59
Year 3 -0.77 -0.84 -0.90
Year 4 -1.20 -1.29 -1.39
Year 5 -1.80 -1.90 -2.00
Year 6 -2.13 -2.21 -2.29
Year 7 -2.04 -2.06 -2.08
Year 8 -1.66 -1.66 -1.65
Year 9 -1.16 -1.16 -1.15
Year 10 -0.63 -0.63 -0.64
Year 11 -0.14 -0.14 -0.16
Year 12 0.26 0.26 0.23
Model 4 5 6
Short-run income elasticity of
consumption ([b.sub.1]) 0.3 0.4 0.5
Short-run capital-output
elasticity (business) ([[delta].sub.4b]) 0.057 0.064 0.071
Short-run capital-output
elasticity (housing) ([[delta].sub.4h]) 0.020 0.023 0.026
Year 1 -0.48 -0.58 -0.68
Year 2 -0.67 -0.76 -0.84
Year 3 -0.97 -1.03 -1.09
Year 4 -1.48 -1.58 -1.67
Year 5 -2.10 -2.19 -2.29
Year 6 -2.36 -2.43 -2.49
Year 7 -2.09 -2.09 -2.08
Year 8 -1.64 -1.61 -1.58
Year 9 -1.14 -1.12 -1.11
Year 10 -0.64 -0.64 -0.64
Year 11 -0.17 -0.18 -0.20
Year 12 0.22 0.20 0.17
Model 7 8 9
Short-run income elasticity of
consumption ([b.sub.1]) 0.6 0.7 0.8
Short-run capital-output
elasticity (business) ([[delta].sub.4b]) 0.078 0.086 0.093
Short-run capital-output
elasticity (housing) ([[delta].sub.4h]) 0.029 0.031 0.034
Year 1 -0.80 -0.92 -1.05
Year 2 -0.93 -1.01 -1.10
Year 3 -1.14 -1.19 -1.23
Year 4 -1.77 -1.87 -1.97
Year 5 -2.39 -2.49 -2.59
Year 6 -2.56 -2.62 -2.67
Year 7 -2.07 -2.04 -2.00
Year 8 -1.54 -1.49 -1.43
Year 9 -1.09 -1.07 -1.05
Year 10 -0.66 -0.67 -0.70
Year 11 -0.23 -0.27 -0.32
Year 12 0.13 0.09 0.04
Model 10 11
Short-run income elasticity of
consumption ([b.sub.1]) 0.9 1.0
Short-run capital-output
elasticity (business) ([[delta].sub.4b]) 0.100 0.107
Short-run capital-output
elasticity (housing) ([[delta].sub.4h]) 0.037 0.040
Year 1 -1.20 -1.36
Year 2 -1.18 -1.27
Year 3 -1.25 -1.26
Year 4 -2.08 -2.19
Year 5 -2.69 -2.79
Year 6 -2.72 -2.76
Year 7 -1.95 -1.89
Year 8 -1.36 -1.28
Year 9 -1.04 -1.03
Year 10 -0.74 -0.80
Year 11 -0.38 -0.47
Year 12 -0.02 -0.08
REFERENCES
Auerbach, A.J. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012), 'Fiscal
multipliers in recession and expansion", American Economic Journal:
Economic Policy, 4(2), pp. 1-27.
Baldacci, E. and Kumar, M. (2010), 'Fiscal deficits, public
debt and sovereign bond yields', IMF Working Paper 10/184.
Ball, L.M. (1996), 'Disinflation and the NAIRU', NBER Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, pp. 167-94.
Barrell, R., Fic, T. and Liadze, I. (2009), 'Fiscal policy
effectiveness in the banking crisis', National Institute Economic
Review, 207.
Barrell, R., Holland, D. and Hurst, A.I. (2012), 'Fiscal
consolidation Part 2: fiscal multipliers and fiscal
consolidations', OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 933
Bernoth, K. and Erdogan, B. (2012), 'Sovereign bond yield
spreads: a time-varying coefficient approach',Journal of
International Money and Finance, 3 I, pp. 639-56.
Blanchard, O.J. and Diamond, P. (1994), 'Ranking, unemployment
duration and wages', Review of Economic Studies, 61(3), pp. 417-34.
Calmfors, L. and Lang, H. (I 995), 'Macroeconomic effects of
active labour market programmes in a union wage-setting model',
Economic Journal, 105(430), pp. 601-19.
DeLong, J.B. and Summers, L.H. (2012), 'Fiscal policy in a
depressed economy', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2012.
Elsby, M.W.L. and Smith, J.C. (2010), 'The great recession in
the UK labour market: a transatlantic perspective', National
Institute Economic Review, 214, p. R26.
Holland, D. (2012), 'Reassessing productive capacity in the
United States', National Institute Economic Review, 220.
Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E.G. and Vegh, C.A. (2010), 'How big
(small?) are fiscal multipliers?', Centre for Economic performance
Discussion Paper I 016.
IMF (2012a), Fiscal Monitor Update, July.--(2012b), United Kingdom
2012 Article IV Consultation, Country Report No. 12/190.
Laubach, T. (2009), 'New evidence on the interest rate effects
of budget deficits and debt', Journal of the European Economic
Association, 7, pp. 858-85.
Machin, S. and Manning, A. (1999), 'The causes and
consequences of long term unemployment in Europe', Handbook of
Labour Economics, Vol. 3.
Manning, A. (1993), 'Wage bargaining and the Phillips curve:
the identification and specification of aggregate wage equations',
Economic Journal, 103(416), pp. 98- 118.
Nickell, S.J. (I 987), 'Why is wage inflation in Britain so
high?', Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 49(I ), pp.
103-28.
OECD (2009), 'Adjustment to the OECD's method of
projecting the NAIRU', OECD Economics Department.
Schuknecht, L., yon Hagen, J. and Wolswijk, G. (2010),
'Government bond risk premiums in the EU revisited. The impact of
the financial crisis', European Central Bank Working Paper, No.
1152.
NOTES
(1) The fiscal multiplier is generally defined as the expected
impact on output in the first year, following a policy innovation that
raises spending or cuts taxes by I per cent of GDP (ex ante).
(2) Fiscal multipliers tend to be less than I, primarily due to
import leakages, the anticipated monetary policy response, and an offset
through the consumption channel through savings.
(3) The policy rule followed is the standard two-pillar rule in
NiGEM, which is described in Barrell et al. (2012).
(4) IMF's recent report, 'United Kingdom 2012 Article IV
Consultation', IMF Country Report No. 12/190, also focuses on the
labour market channel of hysteresis to explain changes in the NAIRU. It
stresses a slightly different channel, namely, labour employment
protection laws as the driver of hysteresis impacts.
(5) Comparing the short-term and long-term unemployed, evidence
shows that the outflow rates for the long-term unemployed have always
been lower than that for the short-term unemployed. The lower outflow
rate for the long-term unemployed, compared to the short-term
unemployed, is called negative duration dependence. The most natural
interpretation is that the long-term unemployed have a lower chance of
finding a job.
(6) Authors' calculations based on data from The U.S. Bureau
of Labor Statistics.
(7) Holland (2012) assesses the impact of labour force withdrawal
in the US on potential output.
Nitika Bagaria, * Dawn Holland ** and John Van Reenen *
* London School of Economics and Centre for Economic Performance.
E-mails: n.bagaria@lse.ac.uk and J.Vanreenen@lse.ac.uk. ** NIESR.
E-mail: d.holland@niesr.ac.uk. The authors are grateful to Simon Kirby,
who provided the details on the UK budget plans in table I that underlie
all the scenarios in this note, as well as the UK forecast baseline
reported in figures 9-11. We would also like to thank Angus Armstrong,
Richard Layard and Jonathan Portes for useful discussion and comments on
the modelling work and paper. Ali errors remain our own.
Table 1. Fiscal consolidation plans, ex ante, per cent of GDP
2011-12 2012-13 2013-14 2014-15
Spending
Consumption -0.44 -0.76 -0.46 -0.78
Investment -0.27 -0.28 -0.36 -0.04
Transfers to households -0.09 -0.20 -0.37 -0.19
Subsidies -0.05 0.01 -0.02 0.00
Revenue
Direct tax, households 0.10 0.40 0.20 0.33
Direct tax, business 0.15 0.01 0.04 -0.12
Indirect tax 0.70 0.00 0.09 0.03
Total 1.80 1.64 1.54 1.24
2015-16 2016-17 Cumulative
Spending
Consumption -0.81 -0.34 -3.58
Investment -0.22 0.00 -1.16
Transfers to households -0.03 0.02 -0.85
Subsidies -0.01 0.00 -0.07
Revenue
Direct tax, households -0.11 0.01 0.92
Direct tax, business -0.02 0.02 0.08
Indirect tax -0.06 -0.02 0.76
Total 0.87 0.33 7.42
Note: Here we define the fiscal impulse as the ex-ante expected
change in revenue/spending (as a % of GDP) as a result of announced
policy changes. Tax credit policy changes are classified as changes
to direct taxes in this analysis. The impact on GDP will depend on
the fiscal multipliers in each country, and cannot be read directly
from this table. The ex-post impact on government balances will
depend on the response of GDP and the endogenous response of
government interest payments, and so also cannot be read directly
from this table.
* London School of Economics and Centre for Economic Performance.
E-mails: n.bagaria@lse.ac.uk and J.Vanreenen@lse.ac.uk. ** NIESR.
E-mail: d.holland@niesr.ac.uk. The authors are grateful to Simon
Kirby, who provided the details on the UK budget plans in table I
that underlie all the scenarios in this note, as well as the UK
forecast baseline reported in figures 9-11. We would also like to
thank Angus Armstrong, Richard Layard and Jonathan Portes for
useful discussion and comments on the modelling work and paper. All
errors remain our own.
Table 2. GDP in [pounds sterling] billion, 2010 prices under two
scenarios
Consolidate Consolidate Difference %2010
during a in normal GDP
depression times
2011 1478 1489 11 0.8
2012 1476 1505 29 2.0
2013 1495 1535 40 2.8
2014 1531 1575 44 3.0
2015 1572 1622 49 3.4
2016 1614 1660 45 3.1
2017 1654 1686 33 2.3
2018 1694 1708 14 1.0
2019 1738 1737 -1 -0.1
2020 1785 1775 -10 -0.7
2021 1832 1817 -15 -1.0
Sum
2011-21 17869 18109 239 16.6
Source: NiGEM simulations.