Mitigating systemic spillovers from currency hedging.
Chung, Kyuil ; Park, Hail ; Shin, Hyun Song 等
Korea has been a forerunner in incorporating macroprudential
policies to mitigate the vulnerabilities from currency crises that can
turn into a more generalised liquidity crisis. This paper examines
longer-term design issues for a more resilient and stable financial
system that could be expected to complement the existing macroprudential
measures in achieving a more stable financial system. In particular, the
paper examines the rationale and mechanics of a new public financial
institution, provisionally called the Exchange Stabilisation and
Guarantee Corporation (ESGC) whose main role is to buy dollar forward
positions from Korean exporting companies who wish to hedge the currency
exposure from long-term export orders. The ESGC is intended to mitigate
the risks arising from the reliance on the role of the banking sector in
providing currency hedging services to exporters. Rapid growth of
short-term foreign currency denominated debt has been the result of
banks receiving forward dollar sales by exporters, and then hedging the
long dollar position by borrowing short in dollars. A public institution
that can buy dollars forward, but which is designed so that there is no
need to hedge by taking short dollar debt, can mitigate the rapid
increase in short-term dollar debt in booms.
Keywords: Currency hedging; banking stability; exchange rate
overshooting
JEL Classifications: F31; F33
I. Introduction
External financial conditions provide the backdrop to domestic
financial conditions, especially when the domestic banking system is
open to funding from crossborder banks. An IMF report on capital flows
(IMF, 2011) identifies three epochs of capital flows, the first being
the period 1995Q4-1998Q2 associated with the Asian crisis, the period
2006Q4-2008Q2 associated with the credit boom that led to the recent
global financial crisis, and the most recent period in the aftermath of
the crisis (2009QB-2010Q2).
The distinguishing feature of the credit boom that preceded the
global financial crisis of 2007-9 is the role played by banking sector
inflows. In contrast to the other two episodes where banking sector
inflows account for less than 20 per cent, banking sector inflows surged
during the period leading up to the Lehman bankruptcy and the subsequent
global crisis.
Figure 2, from the IMF's Global Financial Stability Report in
2010, shows the capital inflows into 41 countries including many
emerging economies, where the flows are disaggregated into the four main
categories of capital flows. Aggregate FDI flows are steady and
portfolio equity flows are small in net terms. However, banking sector
flows display the signature procyclical pattern of surging during the
boom, only to change sign abruptly and surge out with the deleveraging
of the banking sector.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Korea has been vulnerable to 'twin crises' in which a
banking crisis and currency crisis reinforce each other. Although twin
crises show many different forms across countries and across time, the
common thread that links them is the balance sheet mismatch at the
aggregate economy level arising from excessive short-term debt
denominated in foreign currency.
In this paper, we explore the extent to which the buildup of
short-term foreign currency of the banking sector can be attributed to
the currency hedging activity of firms who seek to reduce the risks
arising from currency movements. For the case of Korea, we present
estimates for the period up to the 2008 crisis that suggest that the
build-up of foreign currency liabilities of the banking sector can be
attributed in large part to such currency hedging activity.
In Korea's case, the vulnerability to reversals of capital
flows is owed in large part to the currency hedging need of exporting
companies, since exporting companies acquire long-term dollar
receivables through their export orders, and then wish to hedge the
currency exposure until receiving final payment in dollars. Hedging
takes the form of selling dollars forward to banks in Korea.
However, the counterparty to the forward transaction (the bank)
must then hedge its own long dollar exposure, which it does by borrowing
in dollars, and then investing the proceeds in Korean won.
Hedging is a desirable activity from the point of view of each
individual firm undertaking the hedging operation, but may entail a
collective outcome where the financial system is left vulnerable to a
sudden shift in external financial conditions, especially from a sudden
reversal of capital inflows as was experienced in 2008.
In this paper, we review the rationale for an institution--dubbed
the Exchange Stabilisation and Guarantee Corporation (ESGC)--which can
provide the public good of providing hedging services to individual
firms, but which does not have the harmful side-effect of generating
short-term foreign currency liabilities that lie at the heart of the
vulnerability of an economy to financial shocks.
2. Background
Before sketching the details of the institutional design, we first
review evidence on the spillovers of hedging activity and how such
spillovers undermine systemic stability.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Figure 3 gives an overview of total customer lending by the banking
sector in Korea and how it was financed. Up to the end of 2005, core
liabilities consisting of customer deposits were adequate to fund total
lending, so that the loan to deposit ratio was below 1. However, lending
outstripped deposits in the period leading up to the Lehman crisis, and
banks resorted increasingly to noncore funding, especially the non-core
funding in foreign currency as seen in figure 3.
The reliance on foreign currency funding of the banking sector
makes the financial system more vulnerable to 'twin crises',
as amply demonstrated by the Asian financial crisis of 1997 and the
turmoil in global financial markets in the autumn of 2008. Such crises
are particularly dangerous due to their mutually reinforcing nature, and
the rapid deterioration of economic fundamentals caused by the
amplification of the crisis.
From 2005-7, Korean banks and the foreign bank branches in Korea
saw rapid increases in short-term foreign currency liabilities (see
figure 4). The severity of the financial crisis in Korea in 2008 can be
attributed largely to the rapid deleveraging that took place in the
banking sector (both domestic and foreign) with the onset of the 2008
financial crisis.
Figure 5 shows the contrast in the pattern of capital inflows and
outflows for two sectors--the equity sector and the banking sector.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The banking sector saw very substantial capital outflows from
Korea. Although Korean banks also held dollar claims, such as the long
dollar forward positions on Korean corporations, such assets could not
be used to meet maturing dollar liabilities without exacerbating the
economy-wide liquidity crisis. Non-financial firms in Korea had dollar
receivables, such as the receivables of the shipbuilders, but they were
long-term dollar receivables that could not be realised immediately.
Korea's vulnerability to currency crises arises from the large
hedging needs of exporting companies. Since these companies acquire
long-term dollar receivables through their export orders, they prefer to
hedge the currency risk by selling dollars forward.
The banking sector in Korea (including foreign bank branches) has
been the counterparty, buying the forward dollars sold by the exporters.
However, the counterparty to the forward transaction (the bank) must
then hedge its long dollar exposure. The bank can hedge its long dollar
position by borrowing in dollars, and then investing the proceeds in
Korean won, thereby hedging the long dollar forward position with a
carry trade position in the Korean won.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
By hedging the exchange rate risk in these long-term dollar
receivables, the exporting companies could transfer to the banking
sector the long-term dollar claims, but the banks then would engage in
maturity transformation by borrowing short in dollars.
In this way, the overall currency mismatch on the consolidated
balance sheet, consisting of the corporate and banking sectors, could be
eliminated through the hedging activity, a maturity mismatch between
long-term dollar claims and short-term dollar liabilities taking its
place. In effect, the currency mismatch was replaced by a maturity
mismatch which left the Korean financial system vulnerable to the global
financial crisis in 2008 that followed in the wake of the bankruptcy of
Lehman Brothers.
Figure 6 depicts the stylised aggregate balance sheet of the
banking sector as a result of the hedging transaction by Korean
exporting firms. The figure illustrates a shipbuilder in Korea who has
received an order and wishes to hedge the foreign currency risk by
selling a long-term dollar forward contract to a bank. The forward
contract shows up as an off-balance sheet claim on the bank's
balance sheet, and entails a long dollar position for the bank.
The bank can hedge the currency risk by borrowing in dollars and
holding the proceeds in Korean won by purchasing local assets, or by
entering into a hedging transaction of its own with another bank in
Korea. However, in aggregate, the banking sector in Korea will have the
form depicted in figure 6, where the long dollar forward position is
offset by a 'carry trade' position that funds the purchase of
local Korean assets with short-term dollar liabilities. Figure 4 refers
to the 'banking sector inside Korea' in order to highlight the
role of foreign bank branches that operate in Korea. As shown in figure
4, the foreign bank branches had larger outstanding amounts of
short-term foreign currency denominated liabilities in the run-up to the
2008 crisis.
3. Banking sector foreign currency liabilities due to hedging
activity
The main findings from a survey conducted jointly by the Bank of
Korea and the Financial Supervisory Commission (FSC) in November 2007
were announced in January 2008 as a press release (Bank of Korea, 2008).
This survey found that in the nine months from January to September
2007, 67 per cent of the receivables of exporting companies in Korea
were hedged for currency risk, while only 15 per cent of the future
orders of importing companies were hedged. The asymmetry between the
large hedging activity of the exporters and the relatively much smaller
hedging activity of the importers created the preconditions for a
mismatch in the demand and supply of long-dated dollars, with supply
outstripping demand. Of the importing firms in Korea, the hedging by the
petroleum refining sector and the steel sector were found to be
particularly low, at only 2-6 per cent of total orders.
The imbalance in the hedging activity of the exporting and
importing sectors reflects both the nature of the goods involved and
also the market structure in Korea. The receivables of exporting
companies tend to be medium- to longer-term, involving large indivisible items typified by shipping orders. In contrast, importing
companies' liabilities are short-term and relatively easier to
predict. Moreover, the market power of companies in the importing
sectors in the domestic Korean market enables them to pass on any cost
increases resulting from exchange rate changes onto the final consumer.
The same is not true of exporting companies who face relatively stiffer
competition in global markets.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
In addition to the hedging activity of Korean exporting companies,
another important source of hedging activity in the run-up to the 2008
crisis came from the asset management sector in Korea. The asset
management sector includes both stock mutual funds serving retail
investors, as well as institutional investors in the insurance and
pension sector.
Figure 7 plots the monthly capital flows in the equity sector,
distinguishing the flows generated by foreign and domestic investors.
The sum of the two series in figure 7 gives the net equity sector flows
depicted in figure 5. The downward pointing bars indicate capital
outflows while upward pointing bars indicate capital inflows.
We see from figure 7 that domestic investors in Korea sharply
increased their holding of foreign stocks in the period before the 2008
crisis, especially in late 2006 and in 2007. However, the boom in the
sale of managed equity funds to retail investors during 2007 took place
during a period of sustained appreciation of the Korean won, and asset
managers offered retail products that hedged the currency risk in the
equity fund. A survey by the Financial Supervisory Commission (FSC,
2007) found that 84 per cent of the retail funds investing in foreign
securities were hedged for currency fluctuations. For such
currency-hedged products, Korean investors were promised a return in
Korean won terms equal to the change in the foreign stock index itself
rather than the stock index change combined with exchange rate changes.
In practice, the currency hedging by asset managers took the form
of selling forward contracts in dollars to banks, in a similar way to
the hedging transaction of the exporting firms shown in figure 6. In one
respect, however, the hedging demand from the asset management sector
was more sensitive to market conditions than for the export sector in
Korea. The reason is that hedging of currency risk for foreign equity
holdings entails marking to market the outstanding stock at any moment
in time, so that changes in market prices and the exchange rate entails
shifts in the hedging need. A buoyant stock market when prices are
rising entails hedging demand that applies to the whole outstanding
amount, rather than just the new flows that are generated in each time
period.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
Figure 8 plots the net increase in foreign stock holdings of
domestic investors from 2003 to 2007. The sharp increase in 2007
reflects both the large new outflows and the marked-to-market increases
in the value of existing foreign equity holdings of domestic Korean
investors. Figure 8 also plots the new orders received by Korean
shipbuilders in the same period. The two series combined represent the
underlying demand for currency hedging that had to be met by the banking
sector in Korea. By utilising information on the percentage of exposures
that were hedged by the shipbuilders and asset managers, we can
calculate the approximate amount of the banking sector's foreign
currency liabilities attributable to the hedging activity of the
exporters and asset managers, and this is shown in table 1. The two
series shown above in figure 8 are presented in table 1. The first row
of table 1 shows the new orders of shipbuilding firms in Korea, while
the seventh row shows the net increase in the value of foreign stock
holdings of domestic investors.
Starting with these series, we can then estimate the increase in
banking sector foreign currency debt that is attributable to the
respective hedging activities. Consider first the hedging activity by
shipbuilders. For shipbuilders, we have both the series for new orders
and the purchase of dollar forwards by the sector (first and third rows
of table 1). We then net out the settlement of maturing forward dollar
contracts (fourth row) to calculate the net new sales of dollar forward
contracts by the shipbuilding sector. Figure 9 plots the series
associated with the hedging activity of the shipbuilders.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
The banking sector is on the other side of these sales, and hence
accumulates long positions in dollar forwards. The banks then hedge
their own exposure by taking on dollar liabilities which in turn are
used to purchase local assets. However, the hedging activity by the
banks does not translate into a one-for-one increase in foreign exchange
liabilities, as the banking sector will have pre- existing foreign
currency liabilities which are unrelated to hedging activities by
non-banks. In any case, the banks' ability or willingness to bear
some currency risk will mean that the increase in foreign currency debt
due to its purchase of dollar forwards will not be one- for-one. The
Bank of Korea/FSC joint survey (Bank of Korea, 2008) estimated that
approximately 73 per cent of the shipbuilders' new orders were
hedged for currency risk by the banking sector.
Figure 10 applies the 73 per cent estimate of banks' hedging
activity to estimate the increase in banking sector foreign currency
liabilities directly attributable to the hedging activity of the
shipbuilders. It is calculated as 0.73 times the net new purchase of
dollar forwards by the shipbuilding sector.
We can use an analogous procedure to estimate the increase in
banking sector foreign currency liabilities directly attributable to the
hedging activities of asset managers. First, we use the estimate from
the survey by the Financial Supervisory Service (FSC, 2007) that
approximately 84 per cent of the holdings in foreign equity retail funds
are hedged by asset managers. We then combine this with the Bank of
Korea/FSC survey estimate that 73 per cent of forward dollar contract
purchases by banks are hedged by their taking on foreign currency
liabilities.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
Thus, the estimated increase in the banking sector foreign currency
liabilities directly attributable to asset managers' hedging
activities is given by
0.73 x 0.84 x outstanding foreign equity holding
Figure 11 plots the increase in banking sector foreign currency
liabilities attributable to asset managers' hedging activity and
adds the analogous series for the foreign currency liabilities arising
from shipbuilders' hedging activities. In figure 12, we plot our
constructed series given by the sum of the two series in figure 11
(dashed line), and then compare it with the actual increase in banking
sector foreign currency liabilities (red line).
With the exception of 2006, we see that the two series are very
close to each other, adding weight to the hypothesis that the increase
in foreign currency liabilities of the Korean banking sector can be
largely attributed to the hedging activity of domestic non-bank market
participants.
The interaction between hedging activity by non- banks and the
banks' own profit incentives is an important potential explanatory factor in the exchange rate dynamics leading up to the 2008 crisis.
There is the potential for a feedback loop that links exchange rate
movements, hedging demand and exchange rate changes.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]
The feedback loop generated by hedging activity can be depicted as
in figure 13. Hedging activity by exporters and asset managers implies
sale of forward dollars to banks. In order to hedge the forward dollars,
the banks take on short-term dollar liabilities and either sell the
dollars in the spot market for Korean won, or enter into a currency swap agreement for delivery of dollars in the future in exchange for delivery
of Korean won at the contracting date. Either way, the banks' own
hedging activity generates sales of dollars and purchase of Korean won
in the spot market, leading to the appreciation of the Korean won value
in the spot market. The spot market appreciation of the won sets off
marked-to- market valuation changes on banks' balance sheets and
possibly also expectations of further appreciation of the Korean won,
which in turn further exacerbates the hedging demands of the non-banks.
Dynamic hedging by the bank that adjusts the amount of foreign currency
liabilities in line with changes in the valuation changes on its balance
sheet entails borrowing more dollars and selling them on the spot market
as the Korean won comes under further appreciation pressure.
The feedback loop is potentially potent for those exporting firms
(such as shipbuilders) where the gains or losses from foreign exchange
movements constitute a large component of total profit.
As well as the demand for hedging, the incentives of the banks in
generating business should also be taken into consideration. The Bank of
Korea/FSC survey (Bank of Korea, 2008) reports that the banks entered
into a period of intense competition to increase market share in the
foreign currency hedging services. Banks engaged in intensive marketing
to customer firms, through site visits, customer seminars, training and
educational programmes for customers, and so on. The BoK/ FSC survey
visited six banks in Korea over the survey period. (1)
During the nine-month survey period from January to September 2007,
the six banks visited 2,453 customer firms, 80 per cent of which were
export firms. The banks made a total of 10,802 visits--an average of 4.4
visits for each customer firm. During this period, the banks issued
research reports that consistently and unanimously forecast continued
strong appreciation of the Korean won. The research was then used in the
marketing effort by the banks to induce customer firms to engage in
further hedging activity. Part of the marketing drive by the banks was
to point to the potential advantages of pre-emptive hedging in which
firms hedge in anticipation of further hedging need, rather than hedging
based on realised need.
Pre-emptive hedging may have led to a systematic over- hedging by
exporting firms, which left them exposed to the sharp fall in the Korean
won with the onset of the crisis in 2008. It is difficult to gauge the
precise amount of over-hedging by exporting companies, even ex post.
When the customer of a shipbuilder cancels an order, then the
shipbuilder will be left with a hedge against the cancelled contract,
leaving it exposed to the depreciation of the Korean won. However, the
shipbuilder may have entered into the hedging of the order in good
faith. Nevertheless, the 2008 crisis and the sharp depreciation of the
Korean won left many Korean exporters exposed to exchange rate movements
that exacerbated the financial distress of 2008.
Figure 14 plots the capital flows reflected in the banking sector
foreign currency liabilities (left-hand scale), plotted against the
USD/KRW exchange rate (right-hand scale). We see that throughout 2006
and 2007 the Korean won appreciated steadily, touching 900 won to the
dollar in late 2007. During this period of won appreciation, research
emanating from the banks predicted in unison further appreciation of the
Korean won. The market consensus at the time was that the exchange rate
would eventually break through the 900 level. Intense marketing by the
banks based on such research could have further fuelled the feedback
loop in Korean won appreciation by encouraging firms to engage in more
aggressive hedging against it.
Figure 13 also explains why the Korean won exchange rate moves in
line with the increase in bank foreign currency liabilities in figure
14, rather than with the equity sector capital flows. The period when
bank foreign currency liabilities are increasing coincides with the
period of increased hedging activity which is then amplified through
appreciation of the Korean won. The feedback loop then goes into reverse
once the bank liability flows reverse, as happened with the onset of the
crisis in 2008. We see in figure 14 that the Korean won falls very
sharply in the summer of 2008 coinciding with the deleveraging of the
banking sector in Korea. Notice that during the crisis period, there was
actually a net inflow in the equity sector, as foreign investors'
sales of Korean equity were outweighed by the repatriation flows by
Korean investors.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
The close link between the hedging activities of non- banks with
the increase in the foreign currency liabilities of Korea's banking
sector has important lessons for the financial stability implications of
real activity. Given the very high economic costs associated with
financial crises, we need to take account of the negative spillover effects of the banks' hedging activity using foreign currency
liabilities. An institution that can alleviate the negative spillovers
of currency hedging activity may enhance system stability. We outline
the possible workings of such an institution here. We give it the
hypothetical name of the Exchange Stabilisation and Guarantee
Corporation (ESGC). The purpose of the ESGC is to cut the link between
the need for non- banks to hedge their exposures to currency risk and
the creation of vulnerabilities to financial stability.
4. Exchange Stabilisation and Guarantee Corporation (ESGC)
The discussion so far has highlighted the double-edged nature of
hedging activity. Hedging is an activity that is privately optimal, but
it generates significant negative spillover effects on the broader
economy through increased fragility of the financial system and the
greater amplification of exchange rate movements. The main channel of
the negative spillover is the banking sector's role in being the
counterparty to hedgers and the fact that the bank needs to neutralise its own currency mismatch by increasing its foreign currency
liabilities. In practice, banks' foreign currency liabilities tend
to be short term, which exacerbates the fragility of the financial
system. The Exchange Stabilisation and Guarantee Corporation (ESGC) is
intended as an alternative to the banking sector whose core role is to
be the counterparty to exporters or asset managers who wish to hedge the
currency risk. The ESGC would have the following three balance sheet
attributes.
* The ESGC is a public entity which is 100 per cent equity
financed.
* The ESGC is valued in US dollars for computing gains and losses.
However, the ESGC is permitted to hold Korean won denominated
assets as well as foreign currency denominated assets.
The exact corporate form of the ESGC would depend on governance and
accountability imperatives, but its charter and mission would be to
promote the public good through enhancing financial stability.
The primary purpose of the ESGC is to play the role of the
counterparty to exporting firms or other private sector economic
entities who wish to hedge currency risk. The ESGC could also serve a
subsidiary role of providing trade finance as part of the currency
hedging service to those small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) that
do not have access to export trade financing, or face high costs of
obtaining such funding.
The ESGC would buy dollars forward when an exporter wished to sell
dollars forward. The difference between the ESGC and the banking sector
is that the ESGC is fully equity financed. Hence its ability to provide
hedging services does not result in the creation of volatile short- term
banking sector foreign currency liabilities. In this sense, for every
dollar that the ESGC buys from a Korean export company, there will be
one fewer dollar's worth of short-term bank liability created.
Crucially, the ESGC can hedge its own currency exposure by holding
Korean won assets (such as Korean government bonds or Bank of Korea
bonds) but be valued in US dollars. The fact that the ESGC holds Korean
won assets but is valued in US dollars creates a natural short dollar
position, which creates the capacity to take on long dollar
exposures--for instance, by buying forward dollar positions from Korean
exporting companies.
The basic idea can be illustrated in terms of the schematic in
figure 15, which illustrates the balance sheet of the ESGC at its
inception and then after a series of transactions. At its inception, the
ESGC holds US dollar assets, such as short-term US Treasury bills. The
ESGC is fully equity financed, and valued in dollars.
However, the ESGC would then begin a series of transactions and
modify its portfolio of assets. An exporting firm wishing to hedge its
long-term currency exposure can sell forward contracts for US dollars to
the ESGC. For its part, the ESGC can hedge its own currency risk by
adjusting its portfolio of assets. The ESGC sells an amount of US dollar
assets equivalent to the discounted face value of the forward contract,
and purchases safe Korean won assets, such as short-term Korean
government bonds.
Through this adjustment of its asset portfolio, the ESGC creates a
short position in the US dollar which exactly offsets the long dollar
exposure created by the forward position. However, unlike a bank, the
ESGC is fully equity financed, and the vulnerabilities created by the
banking sector's short-term foreign currency debt can be avoided.
When the forward contract matures, the ESGC reverses the initial set of
transactions. When the exporting firm delivers dollars at the maturity
date, the ESGC sells Korean won assets and purchases US dollar assets to
rebalance its portfolio so that the ESGC remains perfectly hedged
against currency fluctuations. In general, the day-to-day operation of
the ESGC will entail fine-tuning of the mix of Korean won and US dollar
assets held in its portfolio, in order to offset exactly the long
forward dollar position bought from the Korean exporting companies.
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
Although the currency risk is perfectly hedged through these
transactions, the ESGC bears some counterparty risk from the possibility
that the exporting company is unable to deliver dollars at the maturity
date of the forward contract. In order to deal with such counterparty
risk, additional safeguards can be put in place. For instance, the
counterparty risk could be mitigated by imposing a haircut on the
notional value of the forward contract relative to the notarised value
of the invoice for the export order, or the collateralisation of the
forward contract through letters of credit or other securities.
For small and medium sized enterprises (SMEs) unable to provide
such collateral, the credit guarantees that are currently provided by
the Korea Credit Guarantee Fund (KODIT) could be used to secure the
forward transaction. By combining credit guarantees with its own
operations, the ESGC will be able to provide trade financing as well as
hedging services, as we will detail below.
We now provide a more detailed description of the workings of the
ESGC through a series of examples. For simplicity of illustration, we
assume that the risk-free interest rate for both the Korean won and the
US dollar is zero.
Example 1: ESGC as counterparty to US dollar forward contract sold
by exporter
* Date 0 (initial date): The ESGC has equity of $100 million, and
holds $100 million of US treasury bills.
* Date 1 (transactions date): The exchange rate at the transactions
date is 1,000 Korean won for one US dollar. The ESGC conducts two
transactions.
** First, the ESGC buys a forward contract from an exporter for the
delivery of $1 million at date 2 (the maturity date) in exchange for KRW 1 billion.
** Second, the ESGC sells $1 million worth of dollar-denominated
assets and buys KRW 1 billion worth of short-term Korean government
bonds.
Through this paired transaction, the ESGC ensures that its value
remains at $100 million irrespective of subsequent exchange rate
fluctuations. Any gains or losses (in US dollar terms) on its on-balance
sheet portfolio of assets are exactly offset by the reverse
marked-to-market gains and losses on its off-balance sheet forward
position. Notice the crucial importance of valuing gains and losses for
the ESGC in US dollars for this immunisation property to hold.
* Date 2 (settlement date): The forward contract matures and
settlement takes place. The exchange rate will have changed from the
contract date, but the ESGC can ensure its value remains unchanged after
settlement.
** The ESGC sells the KRW 1 billion worth of Korean government
bonds on its portfolio, and delivers the won to the exporter, as
specified in the forward contract.
** In return, the exporter delivers $1 million dollars to the ESGC,
as stipulated in the forward contract. The ESGC then purchases $1
million worth of US dollar safe assets, to bring its on-balance sheet
portfolio to $100 million worth of US dollar-denominated safe assets.
After the settlement date, the ESGC's balance sheet is back to
its initial portfolio. Provided that counterparty risk can be
eliminated, the ESGC's trades enable it to remain perfectly hedged
against currency fluctuations between the contract date and the
settlement date.
Example 2: ESGC as counterparty to US dollar currency swap
Suppose that a Korean bank wishes to sell a US dollar currency swap
contract with face value of $1 million. Suppose that the exchange rate
at the transactions date is 1,000 Korean won for one US dollar. Under
the swap contract, the Korean bank delivers KRW 1 billion in exchange
for $1 million at the contracting date, and receives KRW 1 billion for
$1 million at the settlement date (recall that interest rates are zero
for illustration). The ESGC can play the counterparty to such a swap as
follows.
* Date 1 (transactions date):
** The ESGC delivers $1 million to the bank in exchange for KRW 1
billion as specified in the swap.
** The ESGC conducts no further transactions. The
KRW 1 billion proceeds stay on the ESGC's balance sheet until
maturity.
In the swap transaction, the ESGC does not adjust its on-balance
sheet portfolio of assets. By keeping the KRW 1 billion proceeds on its
balance sheet, the ESGC can fully hedge its obligation to deliver Korean
won at the settlement date. Notice that any gains or losses on its
on-balance sheet portfolio of assets are exactly offset by the reverse
marked-to-market gains and losses on its off-balance sheet position.
* Date 2 (settlement date): The swap contract matures and
settlement takes place. The exchange rate will have changed from the
contract date, but the ESGC can ensure its value remains unchanged after
settlement.
** The ESGC delivers KRW 1 billion to the Korean bank.
** In return, the Korean bank delivers $1 million dollars to the
ESGC.
After the settlement date, the ESGC's balance sheet is back to
its initial portfolio, provided that counterparty risk can be eliminated
in some other way.
Example 3: ESGC as provider of combined hedging and trade credit
services
Suppose that a Korean manufacturing firm from the SME sector wishes
to accept an export order for a long-dated project. The project entails
significant currency risk but also entails financing needs. The small
firm does not have the financing in hand, and lacks collateral for
obtaining trade finance from the banking sector.
Under these circumstances, the ESGC can provide a combination of
trade financing and currency hedging by working in unison with existing
agencies such as the Korea Credit Guarantee Fund (KODIT) which provides
credit guarantees for small and medium sized companies that lack
collateral demanded by banks. The ESGC can provide the combination of a
loan and a forward contract as depicted in figure 16.
[FIGURE 16 OMITTED]
In this example, the small exporting firm has obtained an export
order for $1 million, but also needs to borrow in Korean won for working
capital to fulfill the order. Say that the firm needs working capital of
1 billion Korean won, which is exactly equal to the $1 million export
order at today's exchange rate of $1 = KRW 1,000.
In this example, the ESGC acts as a discounter of the export
invoice. The discounting of receivables is known as
'factoring', and the ESGC provides factoring as well as
hedging services. The specific transactions are as follows.
* Date 1 (transactions date):
** The ESGC sells $1 million and obtains KRW 1 billion. The ESGC
lends this sum to the export firm, with promised repayment of 1 billion
won at the settlement date. This loan is secured on the export invoice
and the credit guarantee from KODIT.
** Simultaneously, the exporting firm enters into a forward
contract with the ESGC and sells $1 million forward to the ESGC at
today's exchange rate of $1 = KRW 1,000. The forward contract is
also guaranteed by KODIT.
Provided that there is no credit risk--either on the loan to the
exporting firm, or on the export invoice, the ESGC's claim of 1
billion won exactly offsets the obligation to deliver 1 billion won at
the settlement date. Meanwhile, any currency risk is eliminated by the
fact that the ESGC expects to receive $1 million at the settlement date.
In this way, any gains or losses on its on-balance sheet portfolio of
assets are exactly offset by the reverse marked-to-market gains and
losses on its off-balance sheet position.
* Date 2 (settlement date): The forward contract matures and
settlement takes place. Meanwhile, the export firm receives $1 million
from its customer. The final settlement then takes place.
** The export firm receives $1 million from its customer and
delivers it to the ESGC. In return, the ESGC delivers KRW 1 billion to
the exporter, as stipulated in the forward contract.
** The export firm uses the 1 billion won to repay the loan of the
same amount to the ESGC.
After the settlement date, the ESGC's balance sheet is back to
its initial portfolio, provided that counterparty risk can be eliminated
through KODIT.
In all the examples sketched above, the main benefit of the ESGC is
that every dollar's worth of exposure that is hedged by the ESGC
entails one less dollar of short-term foreign currency dollar
liabilities of the banking sector. The direct benefit of the ESGC is to
reduce the vulnerability of the financial system to crises by reducing
the short-term foreign currency liabilities of the banking sector. We
may also expect additional stabilisation effects of the ESGC by
mitigating the feedback loop generated by the hedging via the banking
sector.
Example 4: ESGC as intermediary
Although the ability of the ESGC to provide hedging services is
limited by its capital, one way to increase its overall capacity would
be to play the role of a central counterparty in forward transactions
between sellers and buyers. Figure 17 illustrates such an example.
In figure 17, the ESGC acts as a central counterparty between an
export firm wishing to sell dollars forward and an importing firm (such
as an oil refiner or steel producer) wishing to buy dollars forward. Any
matching transactions can free up the equity of the ESGC to provide
hedging to other parties.
Due to the potential maturity mismatch between the selling and
buying leg of the two forward transactions (exporters have longer-dated
needs), the role that the ESGC plays in figure 17 could not be taken
over by a currency futures exchange. Moreover, by playing the role of
the central counterparty, the ESGC can reassure both sides of the
transaction that the counterparty risk can be minimised.
The central counterparty role of the ESGC might be expected also to
contribute to the development of a more active market between sellers
and buyers of forwards and thus lower the costs of hedging both for
exporters and importers.
[FIGURE 17 OMITTED]
The fact that the ESGC has a narrow mandate for providing hedging
services provides a much stronger political economy rationale in the
international context, and is much less susceptible to accusations of
exchange rate manipulation through intervention. This advantage
distinguishes the ESGC from the current Exchange Equalization Fund (EEF)
of the Korean government, which is designed specifically for
intervention purposes to smooth out exchange rate movements.
The ESGC has another advantage over the current Exchange
Equalization Fund (EEF) from a political economy perspective, this time
viewed from the domestic political context. The current EEF has both
dollar-denominated and won-denominated accounts, and is used for
intervention purposes. Since the objective is to smooth out exchange
rate movements, the EEF can accumulate substantial gains or losses. From
a domestic political economy perspective, the won-denominated gains and
losses can be a sensitive political issue. During a time of sustained
Korean won appreciation, the market intervention to slow the
appreciation of the won will result in substantial marked-to-market
losses in Korean won terms. Such Josses can sometimes be portrayed in
the media as reckless gambling by the government and the central bank at
the expense of the national budget. Such criticisms are not confined to
Korea, as we have seen recently in the case of Switzerland and the Swiss
policy of pegging the Swiss Franc to the euro.
The advantage of the ESGC is that it is designed to be perfectly
hedged, so that there are no value gains or losses. The fact that it is
valued in US dollars is crucial for this political economy advantage.
Not only is the ESGC relatively free from political economy
pressures, it would be possible to construct a highly effective
political economy case to highlight the many benefits that the ESGC can
provide to the small and medium sized enterprise (SME) sector in Korea.
The combination of lending for working capital financing as well as
hedging services that are accessible to the SME firm sector would be
highly beneficial to small exporters, and thereby level the playing
field vis-a-vis the large firms in Korea. In this respect, the ESGC
would chime in well with current consensus in policy circles on the
desirability of levelling the playing field between small and large
firms by reducing the competitive disadvantage of small firms.
6. Concluding remarks
In this paper, we have examined the rationale for an institution
that can provide the public good of permitting economic entities to
hedge their currency exposure while minimising the harmful spillover
effects of their hedging activities for systemic stability as a whole.
The key feature of the institution that allows us to perform its task is
its capital structure financed with equity. As well as systemic
stability, we have discussed the potential political economy advantages
of such an institution, both domestically and internationally.
REFERENCES
Bank of Korea (2008), 'Preliminary findings of study on demand
and supply imbalance in the currency forward market' (in Korean),
Bank of Korea Press Release 2008-1-41, 19 January.
Financial Supervisory Commission (2007), 'Trends in mutual
funds in domestic and foreign assets' (in Korean), Financial
Supervisory Commission Press Release, 16 November.
Hahm, J.-H., Mishkin, F.S., Shin, H.S. and Shin, K. (2010),
'Macroprudential policies in open emerging economies', NBER working paper 17780, http://www.nber.org/papers/w17780. pdf.
Hahm, J.-H., Shin, H.S. and Shin, K. (2011), 'Non-core bank
liabilities and financial vulnerability', working paper
http://www.princeton. edu/=hsshin/www/noncore.pdf.
International Monetary Fund (2010), Global Financial Stability
Report, April.
--(2011), 'Recent experiences in managing capital
inflows--crosscutting themes and possible policy frameworks',
Strategy, Policy and Review Department, February.
Shin, H.S. and Shin, K. (2010), 'Procyclicality and monetary
aggregates', NBER discussion paper w16836, http://www.nber.
org/papers/w16836.
NOTE
(1) Shinhan, Korea Development Bank (KDB), Citibank Korea, Standard
Chartered, Credit Agricole (Calyon) and Deutsche Bank.
Kyuil Chung, * Hail Park * and Hyun Song Shin **
* Economic Research Institute, Bank of Korea. ** Princeton
University. E-mail:hsshin@princeton.edu. The views expressed here are
those of the authors and not necessarily the official views of the Bank
of Korea. The authors are grateful to Philip Davis for comments on an
earlier version of this paper.
Table 1. Underlying calculation for the increase in foreign currency
debt of the banking sector attributable to hedging activity
($ billion)
2003 2004 2005
Shipbuilders' new orders 23.90 31.80 31.27
Estimated increase in foreign debt due
to shipbuilders' hedging activities 1.15 4.64 5.70
Sale of dollar forwards by shipbuilders 4.47 12.50 16.82
Settlement of maturing forwards
by shipbuilders -2.89 -6.14 -9.01
Net sale of dollar forwards by shipbuilders 1.58 6.36 7.81
Net increase in foreign stock holding
of domestic investors 1.63 5.59 4.90
Estimated increase in foreign debt due to
hedging activity of asset managers 1.00 3.43 3.00
Estimated increase in foreign debt due to
hedging activity of shipbuilders and
asset managers 2.15 8.07 8.70
Increase in total foreign debt 8.89 8.98 10.79
Increase in banking sector foreign debt 9.26 6.76 8.94
2006 2007 2008
Shipbuilders' new orders 61.70 97.50 71.79
Estimated increase in foreign debt due
to shipbuilders' hedging activities 14.00 19.97 5.24
Sale of dollar forwards by shipbuilders 35.25 53.26 41.49
Settlement of maturing forwards
by shipbuilders -16.07 -25.90 -34.31
Net sale of dollar forwards by shipbuilders 19.18 27.36 7.18
Net increase in foreign stock holding
of domestic investors 22.91 68.04 -56.98
Estimated increase in foreign debt due to
hedging activity of asset managers 14.05 41.72 -34.94
Estimated increase in foreign debt due to
hedging activity of shipbuilders and
asset managers 28.05 61.69 -29.70
Increase in total foreign debt 63.79 108.23 -16.06
Increase in banking sector foreign debt 53.11 56.34 -23.46
2009 2010
Shipbuilders' new orders 18.33 46.30
Estimated increase in foreign debt due
to shipbuilders' hedging activities -12.99 -7.11
Sale of dollar forwards by shipbuilders 16.04 22.60
Settlement of maturing forwards
by shipbuilders -33.84 -32.34
Net sale of dollar forwards by shipbuilders -17.80 -9.74
Net increase in foreign stock holding
of domestic investors 24.44 9.60
Estimated increase in foreign debt due to
hedging activity of asset managers 14.99 5.89
Estimated increase in foreign debt due to
hedging activity of shipbuilders and
asset managers 2.00 -1.22
Increase in total foreign debt 28.31 13.76
Increase in banking sector foreign debt 10.84 -7.18
Figure 1. Components of capital flows to emerging economies
1995Q4-1998Q2 2006Q4-2008Q2 2009Q3-2010Q2
Portfolio Inflows 40% 17% 48%
Other Inflows
(incl. Banking) 20% 41% 18%
Direct Inflows 40% 42% 34%
Source: IMF (2011, p. 14).
Note: Table made from bar graph.