首页    期刊浏览 2024年09月21日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Self-defeating austerity?
  • 作者:Holland, Dawn ; Portes, Jonathan
  • 期刊名称:National Institute Economic Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0027-9501
  • 出版年度:2012
  • 期号:October
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:National Institute of Economic and Social Research
  • 摘要:Government budget deficits rose sharply in almost all major industrialised countries in the aftermath of the global financial crisis. The associated Great Recession led to a sharp and prolonged fall in output which, together with fiscal stimulus packages and emergency financial sector support, transformed public finances, resulting in very large fiscal deficits and a sharp rise in government debt. This raised concerns about long-term fiscal sustainability and, in some Euro area countries, possible (and in the case of Greece, actual) default. As a result, most major economies have introduced fiscal consolidation packages, with the stated objectives of improving debt sustainability by lowering debt to output ratios.
  • 关键词:Austerity (Economic policy);Gross domestic product;Interest rates;Public finance

Self-defeating austerity?


Holland, Dawn ; Portes, Jonathan


Introduction

Government budget deficits rose sharply in almost all major industrialised countries in the aftermath of the global financial crisis. The associated Great Recession led to a sharp and prolonged fall in output which, together with fiscal stimulus packages and emergency financial sector support, transformed public finances, resulting in very large fiscal deficits and a sharp rise in government debt. This raised concerns about long-term fiscal sustainability and, in some Euro area countries, possible (and in the case of Greece, actual) default. As a result, most major economies have introduced fiscal consolidation packages, with the stated objectives of improving debt sustainability by lowering debt to output ratios.

However, while it is generally agreed that over the medium term fiscal consolidation is necessary for many--perhaps most--industrialised countries, there is considerable debate about whether the speed and magnitude of consolidation packages could, in practice, be self-defeating. Fiscal consolidation is likely to have a negative impact on growth; that in turn reduces tax receipts and may increase spending pressures. And, as we discuss below, there are good reasons to believe that, with interest rates at or near the zero lower bound, an impaired financial system and coordinated action by many governments, the impact is likely to be significantly larger now than in 'normal' economic times.

Some economists (for example, Delong and Summers, 2012) have argued that for at least some countries austerity could be 'self-defeating'; that is, that debt to output ratios might increase rather than decrease. For EU countries, this argument is strengthened by spillover effects; reduced growth in one country will also reduce growth in other countries, through trade linkages. While each country's fiscal consolidation could make sense in isolation, the impact of joint consolidation across the Euro zone could worsen the debt position. This would be a policy coordination failure of the sort John Maynard Keynes warned about in the last period of a Great Recession. (1)

This paper uses the National Institute Global Econometric Model, NiGEM (2) to assess the economic impact of fiscal consolidation plans for the period 2011-13. We examine the impact both in 'normal times' and under alternative scenarios where, as now, the interest rate channel is impaired and liquidity constraints are heightened. We also explicitly take account of spillover effects.

The main conclusion is that, while in 'normal times', fiscal consolidation would lead to a fall in debt to GDP ratios, in current circumstances this is likely to be 'self-defeating' for the EU collectively. That is, with the fiscal consolidation plans currently in place, debt ratios will be higher in 2013 in the EU as a whole rather than lower. This will also be true in almost all individual member states (including the UK, but with the exception of Ireland). The implication is that the current strategy being pursued by individual Member States, as well as the EU as a whole, is fundamentally flawed. Even on its own terms, it is making matters worse.

Fiscal multipliers

The fiscal impact multiplier is generally defined as the expected impact on output in the first year of a policy innovation that raises spending or cuts taxes by 1 per cent of ex ante GDP (Spilimbergo et al., 2009). Since the crisis, there has been considerable controversy about the likely magnitude, and indeed sign, of fiscal multipliers in industrialised countries. Some have argued that confidence and Ricardian equivalence effects could even lead to multipliers that were negative (that is, that fiscal consolidation would increase rather than reduce growth: see Alesina and Ardegna, 2009). Policymakers and the international institutions, however, have been sceptical about such claims, and have tended to assume multipliers that were between 0 and 1; IMF (2010) concluded that on average multipliers were about 0.5. Meanwhile, others (Fatas, 2012) have consistently argued that multipliers are in fact likely to be considerably larger.

The recent poor growth experience of many industrialised countries--in particular those that have undertaken large fiscal consolidations--has prompted the IMF to move towards the latter position (IMF, 2012a), concluding that "multipliers have actually been in the 0.9 to 1.7 range since the Great Recession. This finding is consistent with research suggesting that in today's environment of substantial economic slack, monetary policy constrained by the zero lower bound, and synchronized fiscal adjustment across numerous economies, multipliers may be well above 1".

Considerable controversy remains (see Giles, 2012, for a discussion in the UK context). However, there is general consensus on both theoretical and empirical grounds that, as Barrell et al. (2009) demonstrate, multipliers are time and state dependent. Fiscal multipliers differ across countries and over time because the structure, circumstances and behaviour of economic agents differ. They also differ within countries, depending on factors such as the fiscal instrument used and the wider policy response. Thus there is no single 'multiplier'. Moreover, since countries are connected through trade and capital flows, there are spillover effects; fiscal consolidation in country A will impact on GDP in country B, and vice versa.

Multipliers in 'normal' times

In order to establish a baseline estimate of fiscal multipliers in a cross-country comparative context, we first run a series of scenarios under a set of common assumptions. We compare the impact of two fiscal instruments--a cut in government consumption spending and a rise in personal sector income tax. (3) The transmission channels of fiscal policy are assumed to operate as they would under 'normal' equilibrium conditions.

Table 1 reports the estimates of the first year multipliers for twelve EU countries, for a 1 per cent (ex ante) GDP rise in taxes or cut in spending that is reversed after two years. We include the US as a comparator. Simulations are run one country at a time, so there are no spillovers across countries in this preliminary set of baseline multipliers. Fiscal multipliers tend to be less than 1, similar to previous estimates, primarily due to import leakages, the anticipated monetary policy response, and an offset through the consumption channel through savings. Generally multipliers peak in the first year and then decline, and the ex post improvement in government revenues will normally be less than 1 per cent of GDP, as tax bases change.

What influences the size of the multiplier?

Multipliers tend to be smaller in more open economies, because the more open an economy is, the more of a shock will spread into other countries through imports, and small open economies such as Ireland have small multipliers. Another factor is the degree of dependence of consumption on current income. This is often related to liquidity constraints, with a higher current income elasticity more common in financially unliberalised economies, such as Greece, than in Belgium or the United States. The degree of liquidity constraints in the economy is likely to vary over the cycle, and may be particularly heightened when the banking system is impaired. The extent of credit impairment is notoriously difficult to measure (due to credit rationing rather than just a higher cost of credit) but can result in liquidity constraints for even profitable businesses. (4) We explore the sensitivity of the multiplier to a parameter designed to capture liquidity constraints below. Finally the speed of response of the economy depends in part on the flexibility of the labour market and the speed at which policies feed into prices.

Table 2 compares the temporary government consumption spending and direct tax multipliers from table 1 to some of the key factors determining the differences in the magnitude of multipliers across countries: import penetration (measured as the volume of imports of goods and services in 2005 as a share of GDP) and the estimated short-term income elasticity of consumption. At the bottom of the table the correlations between each factor and the two multipliers are reported.

Multipliers in a 'depression'

So far, our results are broadly in line with the previous literature and the estimates used by international institutions and policymakers to inform policy during the current round of fiscal consolidations. However, the baseline multipliers reported in table 1 reflect the expected impact of fiscal innovations when introduced during normal times, when the economy is operating close to its equilibrium. However, we do not appear to be in normal times but in a prolonged period of depression, which we define as a period when output is depressed below its previous peak. As Delong and Summers (2012), Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012), IMF (2012b) and others point out, the impact of fiscal tightening during a depression may be very different.

There are a number of channels that the differences may feed through. In this study we consider two of these channels. First, there is the interest rate response. Under normal circumstances a tightening in fiscal policy can be expected to be accommodated by a relaxation in monetary policy. Our baseline fiscal multipliers reflecting the response in normal times allow an endogenous response in short-term interest rates. With forward-looking financial markets, the long-term interest rate, which determines the borrowing costs of firms for investment, is driven by the expected path of short-term interest rates over a 10-year forward horizon. As monetary policy loosens, long-term interest rates fall, stimulating investment and offsetting part of the fiscal contraction.

However, with interest rates already at exceptionally low levels, further tightening of fiscal policy is unlikely to result in such an offsetting monetary policy reaction. The Federal Reserve, and other major Central Banks, cut interest rates to near zero levels in 2009. More recently, the Federal Reserve has announced that these exceptionally low levels of interest rates are expected to remain warranted until mid-2015, and financial market expectations for the UK and Euro Area point to a similar interest rate path. While quantitative easing/ credit easing measures have been introduced, the effects of these measures are also limited by low interest rates on risk-free assets. It is unclear whether 'exceptional' monetary easing measures will eventually translate into easier credit terms when banking systems remain so heavily impaired by trading book losses and persistent pressure on loan book assets.

We consider the impact on the first-year fiscal multiplier of a fiscal innovation introduced during a period like the present, where there is little scope for downward flexibility in interest rates. This is compared to the estimated multiplier with full downward flexibility in interest rates. We use the United Kingdom as an example, but similar results can be expected in most of the other economies in our sample.

Figure 1 illustrates the impact on GDP of a 1 per cent of GDP fiscal consolidation enacted through cuts in government spending in the UK. The figure compares the expected impact under normal conditions when the interest rate response is endogenously driven by a targeting rule, to the same consolidation plan in an environment where there is no downward flexibility of interest rates. The first-year fiscal multiplier increases from 0.5 to 0.8 when the interest rate channel is impaired. The impact is also much more prolonged.

Second, during a downturn, when unemployment is high and job security low, a greater percentage of households and firms are likely to find themselves liquidity constrained. In the presence of perfect capital markets and forward-looking consumers with perfect foresight, households will smooth their consumption path over time, and consumer spending will be largely invariant to the state of the economy or temporary fiscal innovations. In the extreme example of Ricardian equivalence, the fiscal multiplier is effectively zero, as fiscal policy is simply offset by private sector adjustments to savings behaviour.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

However, at any given time, some fraction of the population is liquidity constrained; that is, they have little or no access to borrowing, so that their current spending is largely restrained by their current income. In the baseline multipliers, we make the assumption that savings behaviour and the number of liquidity constrained consumers are as in normal times. However, in a prolonged period of depressed activity, this is unlikely to be the case.

We next consider the effects of an increase in the share of consumers that are liquidity constrained. We operationalise this effect in the NiGEM model through an adjustment to the short-term income elasticity of consumption. As unemployment rises, a greater share of the population will be unable to access credit at reasonable rates of interest--at precisely the moment when they are in need of borrowing to smooth their consumption path. This means that consumption is likely to be cyclical, and that this elasticity is likely to be time varying and dependent on the position in the cycle. Following a banking crisis, the effects can be expected to be particularly acute, as banks tighten lending criteria, as discussed by Barrell et al. (2009). This also suggests that fiscal multipliers are dependent on the state of the economy--especially tax innovation multipliers--consistent with recent studies such as Delong and Summers (2012) and Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012).

The estimated impact on GDP of a 1 per cent of GDP rise in taxes in the UK, under different assumptions on the short-run income elasticity of consumption, is reported in table 3. With no liquidity constraints, we would expect a temporary rise in taxes to have essentially no impact on output, while with no options for borrowing to smooth consumption we would expect output to decline by 1/2 per cent. This illustrative example for the UK can be used as a guide for other countries, as to the sensitivity of multiplier estimates to this key parameter.

The impact of fiscal consolidation 2011-13

We now consider the impact of the actual fiscal programmes announced and enacted for 2011-13 in the EU. Table 4 reports the planned fiscal consolidation programmes in the countries covered in this paper for 2011-13. The policy impulse is defined as the expected impact of legislative changes to tax rates and spending commitments introduced in a given year on total government spending or revenue, as a per cent of ex ante GDP. A negative impulse represents contractionary policy (a tax increase or spending cut).

Fiscal policy became contractionary in all countries in our sample in 2011, with the deepest consolidation measures introduced in Portugal, Ireland and Greece--the three countries on bail-out programmes. Cumulative measures over the three-year period amount to close to 10 per cent of GDP in Greece and Portugal and 8 per cent of GDP in Ireland. Consolidation measures amounting to 5-6 per cent of GDP are planned in France, Italy, Spain and the UK, while only a modest adjustment is planned in Germany and Austria.

In order to assess the impact of these planned consolidation packages on GDP, the deficit and the stock of government debt, we consider two alternative scenarios. In the first scenario, we implement the policy plans detailed in table 4, under the assumption that the economy is behaving as in normal times, eg. with flexible interest rates that do not bind, and liquidity constraints in line with the long-run average. In the second scenario, we allow for an impaired interest rate channel and heightened liquidity constraints --assumptions we consider more realistic under current conditions. We raise the short-term income elasticity of consumption by 0.1 in Germany and by 0.4 in Greece, with proportional adjustments in other countries (these parameters are calibrated to a measure of financial sector impairment: see Holland, 2012b, for details).

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

Table 5 reports the estimated impact of the planned consolidation programmes in Europe on GDP under the two scenarios. These scenarios were run with all countries consolidating simultaneously, and so capture the spillover effects of policies between countries. Figures 2 and 3 illustrate the estimated impact on the fiscal balance and the debt stock of the programmes in 2013. While the budget balance is expected to improve in most countries under both scenarios, when liquidity constraints are heightened and the interest rate channel impaired, the improvement in the budgetary position is significantly weaker. For example, in Greece, the 10 per cent of GDP ex-ante consolidation programme is expected to improve the budget balance by just 2 per cent of GDP by 2013, as the level of output is expected to contract by 13 per cent as a result of the programme.

Even more strikingly, in the second scenario the fiscal consolidation programmes increase rather than reduce the debt-GDP ratio in every country except Ireland. This seemingly perverse outcome reflects the relatively modest adjustment to the stock of debt in the numerator of this ratio compared to the sharp contractions expected in the level of GDP in the denominator of the ratio. While the level of debt is expected to decline in most countries, the rate of decline cannot keep pace with the drop in output, leading to a rise in the debt--GDP ratio.

It is particularly striking that this is not just true in extreme cases like Greece; fiscal consolidation across the EU has the effect of increasing rather than reducing debt--GDP ratios in Germany and the UK as well. In both the UK and the Euro Area as a whole, the result of coordinated fiscal consolidation is a rise in the debt-GDP ratio of approximately 5 percentage points.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Of course, one argument frequently advanced in support of fiscal consolidation programmes is that they will reduce government borrowing premia in countries with high debt and deficits. But these simulations show that the opposite may in fact be the case; if we were to allow for endogenous feedback from the government debt ratio to government borrowing premia, this would in fact raise interest rates, exacerbate the negative effects on output, and in turn make debt--GDP ratios even worse; truly a 'death spiral'.

Spillovers

It is important to note that much of the explanation for these large negative impacts is that output in each country is reduced not just by fiscal consolidation domestically, but by that in other countries (through trade linkages). In order to gain insight into the magnitude of these impacts, we compare the multipliers from the second scenario to a set of unilateral scenarios based on the same assumptions of an impaired interest rate channel and heightened liquidity constraints.

Figure 4 illustrates the difference in the expected level of GDP in 2013 in each country in the joint scenario compared to the unilateral scenarios. On average, the negative impact of the programmes on the level of GDP in each country is 2 percentage points greater by 2013 when policies are enacted jointly rather than unilaterally. Negative spillovers are more severe in the very open economies, such as Belgium and the Netherlands, and more muted in the less open economies of France, Italy and the UK.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

Conclusions

It has been argued that the poor growth performance of most EU countries (including the UK as well as Euro Area countries) in the past two years cannot be primarily attributed to fiscal consolidation. This paper suggests the contrary: when account is taken of the magnified impact of consolidation in a depressed economy, and of the spillover effects of coordinated fiscal consolidation across almost all EU countries, fiscal multipliers will be considerably larger than in normal times, and the impact on growth correspondingly larger.

The direct implication is that the policies pursued by EU countries over the recent past have had perverse and damaging effects. Our simulations suggest that coordinated fiscal consolidation has not only had a substantially larger negative impact on growth than expected, but has actually had the effect of raising rather than lowering debt to GDP ratios, precisely as some critics have argued. Not only would growth have been higher if such policies had not been pursued, but debt--GDP ratios would have been lower. It is ironic that, given that the EU was set up in part to avoid coordination failures in economic policy, it should deliver the exact opposite.

REFERENCES

Alesina, A.F. and Ardagna, S. (2009), 'Large changes in fiscal policy: taxes versus spending', NBER Working Paper No. 15438, October.

Auerbach, A.J. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012), 'Fiscal multipliers in recession and expansion", American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4(2), pp. 1-27.

Bagaria, N., Holland, D. and Van Reenen, J. (2012), 'Fiscal consolidation during a depression', National Institute Economic Review, 221, pp. F42-54.

Barrell, R., Fic, T. and Liadze, I. (2009), 'Fiscal policy effectiveness in the banking crisis', National Institute Economic Review, 207.

Barrell, R., Holland, D. and Hurst, A.I. (2012), 'Fiscal consolidation Part 2: fiscal multipliers and fiscal consolidations', OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 933

DeLong, J.B. and Summers, L.H. (2012), 'Fiscal policy in a depressed economy', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2012.

Euroframe (2012), 'Economic Assessment of the Euro Area', winter 2011/12.

Fatas, A. (2012), 'Underestimating fiscal policy multipliers', blogpost, October.

Giles, C. (2012), Financial Times, October.

Holland, D. (2012a), 'Less austerity, more growth ?', paper prepared for ENEPRI Conference: EU Growth Prospects in the Shadow of the Crisis.

--(2012b), 'Reassessing productive capacity in the United States', National Institute Economic Review, 220.

IMF (2010), World Economic Outlook, October.

--(2012a),World Economic Outlook, October.

--(2012b), Fiscal Monitor Update, July.

Keynes, J.M. (1933), The Means to Prosperity, London, Macmillan.

Spilimbergo, A., Symansky, S. and Schindler, M. (2009), 'Fiscal multipliers', IMF Staff Position Note, SPN/09/11.

Stiglitz, J. and Greenwald, B. (2003), Towards a New Paradigm in Monetary Economics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

Dawn Holland and Jonathan Portes *

* National Institute of Economic and Social Research. e-mail: d.holland@niesr.ac.uk. This Commentary is a shorter version of Holland (2012a), which contains a fuller and more technical explanation of the modelling techniques used. It also draws heavily on two previous papers: Barrell et al. (2012) and Bagaria et al. (2012). We would like to acknowledge the significant contributions of our co-authors from both papers to this work. However, any errors in this current version of the paper are of course our own.

NOTES

(1) "It is as though two motor-drivers, meeting in the middle of a highway, were unable to pass one another because neither knows the rule of the road. Their own muscles are no use; a motor engineer cannot help them; a better road would not serve. Nothing is required and nothing will avail, except a little, a very little, clear thinking ... they will never get by, unless they stop to think and work out with the driver opposite a small device by which each moves simultaneously a little to his left." (From Keynes, J.M., 1933.)

(2) For a full description of NiGEM see http://nimodel.niesr.ac.uk.

(3) For a comparison with multipliers using other fiscal instruments in NiGEM see Barrell et al. (2012).

(4) See Stiglitz and Greenwald (2003).
Table 1. Fiscal impact multipliers

                  Government consumption   Income tax

Austria                   -0.52              -0.13
Belgium                   -0.62              -0.12
Finland                   -0.61              -0.06
France                    -0.67              -0.27
Germany                   -0.48              -0.26
Greece                    -1.35              -0.53
Ireland                   -0.36              -0.08
Italy                     -0.63              -0.13
Netherlands               -0.59              -0.20
Portugal                  -0.73              -0.11
Spain                     -0.81              -0.11
United Kingdom            -0.54              -0.09
United States             -0.92              -0.19

Note: Impact on GDP in the first year of a 1 per cent of ex-ante
GDP temporary cut in government consumption or rise in income
tax. No shift in the budget target. Experiments conducted in one
country at a time.

Table 2. Key factors determining cross-country
differences in multipliers

                    Temporary    Temporary      Import        Income
                     spending    income tax   penetration   elasticity
                    multiplier   multiplier

Austria               -0.52        -0.13         0.50          0.23
Belgium               -0.62        -0.12         0.80          0.17
Finland               -0.61        -0.06         0.39          0.00
France                -0.67        -0.27         0.30          0.51
Germany               -0.48        -0.26         0.39          0.68
Greece                -1.35        -0.53         0.34          0.48
Ireland               -0.36        -0.08         0.72          0.17
Italy                 -0.63        -0.13         0.27          0.14
Netherlands           -0.59        -0.20         0.70          0.23
Portugal              -0.73        -0.11         0.38          0.08
Spain                 -0.81        -0.11         0.37          0.00
UK                    -0.54        -0.09         0.29          0.17
US                    -0.92        -0.19         0.16          0.15
Spending correlation                             0.43         -0.12
Tax correlation                                  0.22         -0.73

Note: Consumption and direct tax multipliers from table I. Import
penetration is measured as the volume of goods and services
imports as a share of GDP in 2005. Income elasticity is the
estimated response of consumption to current changes in income,
from the consumption equations in NiGEM.

Table 3. Impact of consolidation programme (tax rise) on
UK GDP, under different short-term income elasticities of
consumption

Model    Short-run income    First year multiplier
           elasticity of
            consumption

I               0.0                  -0.01
2               0.1                  -0.06
3               0.2                  -0.11
4               0.3                  -0.15
5               0.4                  -0.20
6               0.5                  -0.25
7               0.6                  -0.31
8               0.7                  -0.36
9               0.8                  -0.41
10              0.9                  -0.47
11              1.0                  -0.52

Table 4. Ex-ante net fiscal impulses 2011-2013, as announced by
governments

                                2011

               Fiscal impulse   of which    of which
                 (% of 2011        tax      spending
                    GDP)          based       based

Austria             -0.9          -0.4        -0.5
Belgium             -0.7           0.0        -0.7
Finland             -0.3          -0.3        -0.1
France              -1.4          -1.1        -0.3
Germany             -0.5          -0.2        -0.3
Greece              -2.7          -1.2        -1.5
Ireland             -3.4          -0.9        -2.5
Italy               -0.5          -0.3        -0.2
Netherlands         -0.8          -0.3        -0.5
Portugal            -5.9          -2.7        -3.2
Spain               -2.5          -0.5        -2.0
UK                  -2.1          -1.1        -I.0

                                2012

               Fiscal impulse   of which    of which
                 (% of 2011        tax      spending
                    GDP)          based       based

Austria             -0.4          -0.2        -0.3
Belgium             -1.2          -0.5        -0.7
Finland             -0.6          -0.5        -0.1
France              -1.7          -1.1        -0.6
Germany             -0.2           0.0        -0.2
Greece              -5.1          -3.5        -1.6
Ireland             -2.4          -1.0        -1.4
Italy               -3.0          -2.4        -0.6
Netherlands         -0.6          -0.5        -0.1
Portugal            -2.1           0.0        -2.1
Spain               -2.1          -0.4        -1.7
UK                  -1.8          -0.2        -1.6

                                2013

               Fiscal impulse   of which    of which
                 (% of 2011        tax      spending
                    GDP)          based       based

Austria             -0.1           0.0        -0.1
Belgium             -1.3          -0.4        -0.9
Finland             -0.1          -0.1         0.0
France              -1.7          -0.8        -0.8
Germany             -0.1          -0.1         0.0
Greece              -2.0          -0.9        -1.1
Ireland             -2.1           0.7        -1.4
Italy               -1.5          -0.6        -0.9
Netherlands         -0.6          -0.5        -0.2
Portugal            -1.9          -0.5        -1.4
Spain               -1.4          -0.3        -1.1
UK                  -I.0           0.0        -1.0

Source: Euroframe (2012). Does not include fiscal plans introduced
after January 2012.

Note: Here we define the fiscal impulse as the ex-ante expected change
in revenue/spending as a % of 2011 GDP as a result of announced
policy changes. The impact on GDP will depend on the fiscal
multipliers in each country, and cannot be read directly from this
table. The  ex-post impact on government balances will depend on the
response of GDP, and so also cannot be read directly from this table.

Table 5. Impact of consolidation programmes on the level of GDP

Percentage difference from base

                        2011                      2012

              Scenario 1   Scenario 2   Scenario 1   Scenario 2

Austria          -0.2         -1.0         -0.2         -2.1
Belgium          -0.6         -2.2         -0.7         -4.3
Finland           0.0         -0.9          0.1         -1.8
France           -0.5         -1.4         -1.1         -2.9
Germany          -0.1         -1.0          0.0         -1.9
Greece           -2.4         -4.6         -6.7        -13.0
Ireland          -0.9         -1.2         -1.3         -3.1
Italy             0.0         -0.7         -0.7         -2.6
Netherlands      -0.6         -1.9         -0.7         -3.3
Portugal         -3.2         -4.4         -5.9         -7.8
Spain            -1.7         -2.5         -3.2         -5.3
UK               -0.5         -2.2         -1.2         -4.3
Euro Area        -0.5         -1.5         -1.0         -3.1

                        2013

              Scenario 1   Scenario 2

Austria          -0.3         -2.9
Belgium          -1.6         -5.2
Finland          -0.1         -2.2
France           -2.0         -4.0
Germany          -0.1         -2.2
Greece           -8.1        -13.2
Ireland          -2.3         -5.0
Italy            -1.9         -4.1
Netherlands      -1.1         -3.9
Portugal         -7.7         -9.7
Spain            -4.2         -6.7
UK               -1.8         -5.0
Euro Area        -1.7         -4.0

Note: Scenario I reflects expected impact were the economies operating
near equilibrium. Scenario 2 allows for heightened liquidity
constraints and impaired interest rate adjustment.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有