首页    期刊浏览 2024年09月21日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:The world economy.
  • 作者:Armstrong, Angus ; Delannoy, Aurelie ; Fic, Tatiana
  • 期刊名称:National Institute Economic Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0027-9501
  • 出版年度:2012
  • 期号:October
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:National Institute of Economic and Social Research
  • 摘要:The stop-start nature of the world economy continues to be disappointing. Five years since the crisis began, and four years since the Lehman failure, the world economy is yet to show signs of a broad self-sustaining expansion. In the advanced economies unemployment is at its highest rate for thirty years and the fast growing emerging economies have also slowed. Some European countries have depression-era unemployment rates with no sign of improvement. If there are any bright spots, they are that the world's largest economy is no longer at the centre of the crisis and the global inventory cycle is likely to provide some short-term support to world demand. Bold monetary policies by the US Federal Reserve Board (Fed) and the European Central Bank (ECB) have reduced the tail-risk on future growth prospects but central (median) forecasts for world growth next year have been revised lower. For example, the IMF's forecasts for growth in the world and advanced economies next year have been lowered by 0.3 percentage points to 3.6 per cent and 1.5 per cent respectively, very similar to our forecast.
  • 关键词:Foreign banks

The world economy.


Armstrong, Angus ; Delannoy, Aurelie ; Fic, Tatiana 等


World Outlook

The stop-start nature of the world economy continues to be disappointing. Five years since the crisis began, and four years since the Lehman failure, the world economy is yet to show signs of a broad self-sustaining expansion. In the advanced economies unemployment is at its highest rate for thirty years and the fast growing emerging economies have also slowed. Some European countries have depression-era unemployment rates with no sign of improvement. If there are any bright spots, they are that the world's largest economy is no longer at the centre of the crisis and the global inventory cycle is likely to provide some short-term support to world demand. Bold monetary policies by the US Federal Reserve Board (Fed) and the European Central Bank (ECB) have reduced the tail-risk on future growth prospects but central (median) forecasts for world growth next year have been revised lower. For example, the IMF's forecasts for growth in the world and advanced economies next year have been lowered by 0.3 percentage points to 3.6 per cent and 1.5 per cent respectively, very similar to our forecast.

In this issue of the Review we have added our forecasts for 2014. Over the long run, our National Institute Global Econometric Model (NiGEM) converges to a steady state which influences medium-term projections. However, the short-term dynamics provide important forecast information for the next two years. Our forecast for OECD growth in 2014 is well below the average growth rate in the ten years prior to the crisis and unemployment is predicted to be still over 8 per cent by the end of 2014. Perhaps most tellingly, for all the fiscal consolidation we expect the ratios of government debt to GDP to be higher in all external deficit countries in 2014 than at the end of this year. This outlook implies that the stop-start nature of the world economy will persist and that the economy will be vulnerable to shocks. This overview looks at three such vulnerabilities to our forecasts.

Multiple or single equilibrium?

Since the crisis began it has become fashionable to see the world economy through the lens of multiple equilibria. IMF Chief Economist, Prof Olivier Blanchard, believes that "the world economy is pregnant with multiple equilibria--self-fulfilling outcomes of pessimism or optimism with major macroeconomic implications." (1) Were it not for unrelated and unforeseeable shocks, the world economy would be in an altogether stronger position. Since Diamond and Dybvig's (1983) seminal work on bank runs, the paradigm of multiple equilibria has dominated interpretations of financial crises. All is well until, for an unspecified reason, there is a sudden loss of confidence or depositor run which becomes self-fulfilling. For example, had confidence suddenly not eroded or speculators attacked European capital markets without cause, then presumably we would not be facing the crisis in Europe.

Another interpretation is that recent events are connected and this is a single unfolding equilibrium from the subprime crisis in the US to the crisis in European periphery economies. So far the crisis has followed a depressingly familiar path from the non-bank financial sector (asset backed securities conduits) to the banking sector (sponsors of the conduits) then to the real economy (through tighter lending conditions) creating a negative feedback on asset values. No matter how distasteful, the well-trodden path is for impaired private sector debt to become public sector debt and increased sovereign credit risk. Credit risk in one country impairs the cross-border asset holdings in the banking system of another country. (2) The optimal private response is for risk officers to respond by selling the debt of the next country with similar characteristics (deleveraging through particular asset sales). (3) Because the crisis has involved the largest financial institutions and countries in the world, this limits the capacity of unaffected institutions or regions to provide a much needed offsetting stimulus. And the event which started the process is rarely an irrational loss of confidence; like banks that are run, the subprime securitisations turned out to have more risk than reported. (4)

This is not just about economic semantics. The current macroeconomy policy debate is cast in terms of those who favour austerity as a means to normalise government debt ratios, and those who believe this will be largely self-defeating (see the Commentary by Holland and Portes in this issue). Put another way, the debate is between those who believe that the fiscal multiplier is between 0.5 and 1.0 and that those who expect that multiplier is significantly more than 1.0 and the lower output will reduce fiscal revenue and hence prove self-defeating. When judging how an economy will respond to substantial change in government spending the context is decisive. Prof. Robert Solow gave an eloquent explanation of this point in a speech to the IMF at the start of 2011. (5) One view is that the world economy is suffering from a series of bad (unrelated) multiple equilibria, otherwise at, or moving back towards, a steady state. The alternative view is that the world financial system deleveraging which began in 2007 (shedding assets with similar characteristics) continues to affect a wider circle of marginal borrowers. In the latter view, capital markets are very far from perfect so Ricardian Equivalence cannot hold. The multiplier for fiscal tightening is likely to be larger than in normal times as private agents cannot smooth expenditure patterns. If all countries rspond in the same way the multiplier is also likely to be larger.

The economic and financial context is important for policy judgements. The Bank of England Governor's description of the current government's fiscal policy as a "textbook response" was correct for a hypothetical textbook world, but not necessarily the world economy which currently exists. The IMF's latest World Economic Outlook contains a well designed reassessment (given the inevitable limits of such work) of the size of multipliers to show that in the period 2010-11 the multiplier is more likely to be 0.9 to 1.7 than the previously understood 0.5. (6) This is an appropriate range and a welcomed reappraisal.

The National Institute has argued many times that the UK government's aggressive fiscal tightening will compound the private sector adjustment and worsen the economic outlook. Yet as critics of this policy it does not follow that we are unconcerned about government debt or in favour of an aggressive fiscal expansion. Some public investment makes good sense at current interest rates, but the fiscal deficit and debt ratios must be lowered. The critical point is how. The first step is to quickly address the underlying financial problem which will create the conditions, including where near zero interest rates provide a stimulus, whereby the multiplier will be less than 1.0. The second step is to carry out the fiscal retrenchment. This sequence is an efficient approach to consolidation. (7) A series of articles in this publication over the past year have been critical of the UK's financial reforms (especially the Vickers Report) and have presented alternative proposals (see Armstrong, 2012a; 2012b). The economic expansion in the world economy in 2010 was a missed opportunity for substantive financial reform.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The vulnerability of the global financial system can be summarised by the vast accumulation of cross-border gross exposures in assets classes which are opaque and poorly understood. In 2009 the UK Treasury's Risk, Reward and Responsibility publication pointed out that between 2002 and 2007 gross cross-border flows in the US, UK, Euro Area and Japan had increased from 6.8 per cent to 21.3 per cent of combined GDP. Figure 1 shows a similar rate of increase for a wider set of countries. This is an enormous increase in cross-border flow in a region which had only a modest aggregate current account deficit. Even countries with current account surpluses such as Switzerland, Germany and the Netherlands experienced very large increases in gross cross-border flows.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

It is very difficult to justify an increase in flow at this magnitude as necessary to hedge increased idiosyncratic risk. Shin (2011) describes how European banks created conduits which purchased foreign assets funded by issuing asset backed commercial paper to investors in that country. The net financial flow is zero (consistent with zero current account balance) but there are two gross flows and transformation risk. Obstfeld (2012) makes a similar point looking at the average stock rather than flow of gross international exposures, see figure 2. The stocks are very poorly reported and understood. For example, FDI is no longer a slow moving real investment but can simply be a hedge position of a moderate-sized leveraged investor. Annual revaluations to assets and liabilities can dwarf current accounts even in unbalanced economies. These exposures connect the gains and losses in one region with changes in flows to another. Where the information is opaque investors often resort to quantity rather than price rationing.

Euro Area

The first risk to the forecast, and one which has been discussed in past issues of the Review, is the possibility and consequences of a Eurozone break-up. The fall in demand and sudden stop in cross-border flows (figure 1) exposed those countries which had relied on capital inflows. Where the counterparts of the inflows had persistent current account deficits, this raised concerns about the condition of bank assets and property markets. Since systemic bank losses are almost always socialised, without the option of currency depreciation this led to higher sovereign credit risk. This has triggered capital flight and fragmentation of the Eurozone.

Our forecast is for the periphery or deficit Euro Area economies (Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal and Spain) to suffer another year of recession in 2013 with only a meagre expansion in 2014. The most likely scenario is that the Euro Area survives intact. In the last issue of the Review we discussed lower probability outcomes (but which would have major impacts) of either a Greek and/or German exit. An important reason for this view was that the ECB would become the outright buyer of last resort for Sovereign bonds. While this violates the EU's Maastricht Treaty Article 125 (the no bail-out clause) we know of no central bank where the board chose to destroy itself. ECB President Draghi confirmed this view by announcing that he would do whatever it takes to preserve the euro. The Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) scheme has reduced the probability of a nation being unable to rollover its sovereign debts and led to an improvement in the spread of periphery versus core sovereign bond yields. The success of the scheme ultimately depends on the conditionality attached to new support and whether any discipline can be imposed on a larger country. This would be the ultimate test for northern ECB board members, in particular the head of the Bundesbank.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

The transition of private sector Eurozone exposures in periphery countries to the public sector is illustrated in figure 3 below. As banks have reduced cross-border exposures, withdrawn loans and received inflows from the periphery and current account balances, the Eurozone payments system (Target 2) shows large credits (around 330 billion euros) to the Bundesbank as holder of German banks' reserves and corresponding debits of the periphery central banks as holders of their banks' reserves. The ECB has purchased bonds through the Securities Markets Programme (SMP) and European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and European Financial Stabilisation Mechanism (EFSM). There is a heated discussion on what happens to these exposures if the Euro Area breaks apart. The most likely outcome is that actual losses would be limited to the paid-up capital of the ECB on the basis that the euro remains the currency in circulation without necessary fiscal transfers for the Target 2 balances.

According to the IMF, capital flight in the year to June was 27 per cent of GDP in Spain and 15 per cent of GDP in Italy. (8) This increases credit tightening and the reliance of banks on wholesale funding. Consequently we expect Spain and Italy eventually to require further funding support which will be the test of the OMT. Other countries which have indirectly benefited from the OMT are Germany and France, which have the largest bank exposures to Spain and Italy. French banks have a particularly high reliance on wholesale funding and so the outlook for France is very much connected to conditions in these two countries. The largest revisions to our 2013 growth forecasts have been for France and Germany, which are lowered by 0.5 and 0.6 percentage points respectively. The good news for the Euro Area is the commitment to a banking union. Assuming that it is appropriately designed, this would be an important step towards resolving the crisis. There are major hurdles to overcome, such as primacy of European bank regulations over national laws and agreed burden sharing for losses which will inevitably occur. If the banking union can be achieved, this would be a fundamental break between sovereign risk and national banking systems and a key part of creating a coherent union.

Large, fast growing emerging economies

The second risk to the forecast is around the outlook for the fast growing emerging market economies of Brazil, Russia, India and China (BRICs) which provided essential support to the world economy in the worst of the global financial crisis. While they are a diverse set of nations, they are, to an extent, integrated together. For example, China is the largest trading partner for Brazil and India. They also share somewhat similar cyclical paths: each country followed expansionary policies in 2008-9 followed by a steady tightening in 2010-11 and subsequently easier monetary and fiscal conditions this year. The economy in all four countries has slowed noticeably this year to rates below long-term potential. A critical issue for the world economy forecast is whether this marks the start of a more protracted downturn which would make recoveries in the West even more problematic.

Since the start of the crisis there has been a significant change in competitiveness. Figure 4 shows the average (PPP weighted) real effective exchange rate for Brazil, Russia, India and China versus the US, Euro Area and UK. There is a very substantial appreciation relative to the advanced economies in the West. This poses a challenge to the BRIC economies which must rely less on external and more on internal demand to generate future growth. Monetary policy in each country has been eased, significantly so in the case of Brazil and China. Yet there are challenges. In Brazil the value of credit extended by private domestic and foreign banks has required the state banks to expand loans to avoid a significantly worse credit tightening. In China the authorities have reverted to supporting investment spending despite the acknowledged over-reliance on investment and desire to increase consumption. Capital flight which has occurred throughout the year appears to be easing, which will lead to a further currency appreciation. In India capital inflows have weakened and the slowdown has revealed the persistence of the twin deficits which may lead to a downgrade of sovereign debt to below investment grade.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

In our forecasts we have attached only a small probability to a hard landing for the BRIC economies. However, we expect growth rates in all countries, with the possible exception of China, to be below rates considered to be the long-term potential growth rate. This is likely to weigh on world growth, although there will be a substitution effect towards the advanced economies from the exchange rate movement.

Monetary policy risks

The third risk to our forecast is more balanced. Central banks have resorted to further unconventional measures to support their economies. The Fed announced so-called QE3, which is a commitment to buy $40 billion of mortgage backed securities each month, without sterilisation, until there is a 'substantial' improvement in the labour market. They also pre-committed to keeping the current low level of interest rates until mid 2015. Tying policy to the real economy appears to have scotched any early perceptions of inflation targeting. The ECB's OMT discussed above allows the outright purchase (without resale agreement) of sovereign bonds where the central bank ranks pari pasu with private investors. The Bank of Japan has announced its intention to increase asset purchases further over the coming year.

Figure 5 shows the extent to which selected central banks have increased the size of their balance sheets since the start of the crisis. These are bold measures but there is some uncertainty about their efficacy. First, it does not necessarily follow that monetary policy is accommodative. Money supply in most countries is either declining or weak, which monetarists would typically regard as a sign of tight policy. Second, the transmission mechanism appears to be via a wealth effect from higher asset prices. It is not clear that private agents will suffer from this illusion on a repeated basis. Third, this is another example of the shift in risk assets from the private to the public sector. While this is not necessarily problematic, the clear demarcation between fiscal and monetary policy has been removed.

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

The most important risk to the forecast is over the medium term. What happens when economies recover to the large central bank balance sheets? While central bankers are confident that they have enough options to reverse the process, this is based on an untested proposition. If inflation is driven by the output gap, there will be a convergence between a full recovery and a very gradual increase in inflation to allow central banks time to reduce balance sheets, if necessary, without damaging the real economy. However, this is only one possibility. If, when the recovery arrives, there is a jump in inflationary expectations caused by central banks' balance sheets then the task of controlling inflation will prove much more challenging. In our forecast we have assumed that central banks are right and inflation will be driven by output gaps, hence the very accommodative monetary policies over the forecast horizon. However, the risks will be revisited in future Reviews.

Prospects for individual economies

United States

Policymaking in the US is pulling the economy in different directions. On the monetary side, the FOMC surprised markets on 13 September, by announcing a more aggressive expansionary stance than anticipated. On the fiscal side, uncertainty regarding policy following the Presidential election held one week after our publication date, is acting as a restraint on investment, hiring and confidence. There are two further policy questions facing the US economy. How will the latest round of monetary easing affect growth prospects? What effect will the election outturn have on the probability of avoiding the so-called 'fiscal cliff'?--i.e. a political deadlock that could lead to a breach of the government debt ceiling and a dramatic tightening of the fiscal stance.

Our forecast assumes that the aggressively loose monetary stance will be sufficient to offset pressures on bond yields that may arise from a political stalemate on fiscal policy amendments. However, it is unlikely to provide sufficient stimulus to bring GDP growth towards levels currently projected by the Federal Reserve. We forecast GDP growth of 2 per cent per annum in 2012 and 2013, rising to just 2.4 per cent in 2014. This compares to the central tendencies of forecasts by the Federal Reserve of 1.7-2.0 for 2012, 2.5-3.0 for 2013 and 3.0-3.8 for 2014.

Given the subdued external environment, it is difficult to see how such rates of growth can be achieved, unless driven by a significant expansion, rather than consolidation, of fiscal policy and a boom in investment that goes well beyond our current forecast. NiGEM model simulations suggest that if the Federal Reserve were to provide sufficient monetary stimulus to achieve these rates of growth, we would need to see close to a further $3.5 trillion in QE in 2013-14. This would be expected to push inflation well above rates that are considered consistent with the Federal Reserve target--reaching above 5 per cent in 2014.

The actions of the FOMC in September 2012 were beyond what was expected by financial markets. In the absence of scope for cuts in interest rates, the FOMC has engaged three alternative channels to ease monetary conditions. They used rhetoric to flatten the yield curve, by extending the period over which they expect to maintain an exceptionally low interest rate from late-2014 to at least mid-2015. They continued the programme of extending the average maturity of its holdings (Maturity Extension Program or 'Operation Twist'). They announced a third round of quantitative easing, purchasing agency mortgage-backed securities at a pace of $40 billion per month. Most importantly, they made an open-ended commitment to extend and increase policy accommodation for as long and by as much as it takes to see a substantial improvement in the labour market. The monetary stance will remain highly accommodative for a considerable period after economic recovery strengthens.

Supported by the highly accommodative monetary stance, markets remain broadly confident that policy makers will avoid the 'fiscal cliff' and amend the debt ceiling in time to avoid a default, regardless of the election outcome. Current legislation mandates an extreme fiscal tightening amounting to about 3.7 per cent of GDP in 2013. Roughly two-thirds of this is related to expiring tax provision, while the remainder reflects spending caps and agreed automatic spending cuts mandated by the 2011 Budget Control Act. Both presidential candidates intend to extend most of the 'temporary' (9) tax cuts due to expire in 2013, at least for the next financial year, and to delay at least a third of the legislated spending cuts. While we expect the necessary policy agreements to be delayed until the very last minute, with considerable market volatility expected at the turn of the year, our forecast assumes that these policy amendments are achieved. As such, fiscal consolidation measures are expected to amount to just 1 per cent of GDP next year.

Our fiscal assumptions going forward are broadly in line with the proposals made by President Obama in February 2012. With a Republican president in the White House, the composition of fiscal consolidation would be biased more towards spending cuts, with tax rates expected to remain stable or decline. This would change the composition of GDP growth underlying our forecast, with somewhat higher growth in consumer spending and weaker growth in government spending, and may slightly dampen the outlook for near-term growth, as the fiscal multiplier associated with spending cuts tends to be higher than that for tax rises. We may also see a somewhat tighter monetary stance, as Governor Romney has criticised the inflation risks associated with the FOMC's expansionary policy.

Canada

Canada has weathered the crisis relatively well, partly because of a relatively sound financial system and well sequenced fiscal response. The fiscal stimulus resulted in a budget deficit of 5.5 and 4.4 per cent of GDP in 2010 and 2011, respectively. The government has now decided to withdraw this stimulus, as proposed in the 2012 budget plan, targeting a return to surplus by 2015. Total spending cuts planned for 2011-14 amount to 1.2 per cent of GDP, and about 70 per cent of these savings are planned to be generated by 'operating efficiency' gains. However, efficiency savings are always difficult, and our forecast allows for more spending cuts to pass through to the real economy. We forecast GDP growth of 1.7 per cent in 2013 and 2 per cent in 2014.

Domestic demand has been supported by low interest rates and expansive credit growth. Easy access to mortgages has resulted in rising house prices, with apparent signs of overheating in Toronto and Vancouver, and the government has enforced tighter mortgage regulation to contain this. However, a substantial or persistent fall in house prices could put a severe strain on the indebted household sector. Due to inexpensive credit, household debt has risen sharply and now stands above the US level, at around 160 per cent of GDE As we expect efforts to deleverage households in future, this will curb domestic demand.

Export revenue remains strong, supported by rising oil prices. The US is the current destination of over 70 per cent of exports, which makes Canada heavily reliant on the US. Efforts to diversify trade towards the emerging markets will offer better prospects of growth potential.

[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]

Brazil

GDP growth rate remains well below the average annual rate of around 5 per cent achieved during the pre-crisis period of 2004-7. We expect the slowdown to persist in the short-to-medium run due to deep rooted problems in the Brazilian economy. Despite ten consecutive rounds of cuts in the central bank interest rates, currently down to a historic low of 7.25 per cent, which has allowed a substantial decline in real interest rates, there is no evident sign of improvement in key economic indicators.

Domestic demand has remained weak. This is due to the fact that Brazil's fast growth in private consumption was largely based on substantial household borrowing. The private household credit to disposable income ratio currently stands above 43 per cent. Although this ratio does not appear unreasonable when compared to other countries, it is the pace of increase which is a cause for concern. Since 2006, the household debt ratio has nearly doubled. As households use a larger portion of their disposable income to pay off debt, this indicates that the credit finance model of consumer spending is coming to a halt. Declining real interest rates are expected to have only a modest impact on future credit growth.

In August 2012 the government introduced a privatisation programme that it hopes will stimulate investment in the outdated and underdeveloped infrastructure. Infrastructure investment will have a positive effect on productivity in the longer run, and may provide a mild stimulus to the economy over the next five years.

Interest rate cuts have resulted in a depreciation of the real exchange rate. Despite this, exports have been disappointing and dropped sharply in the first half of 2012. This can be attributed to softer growth in Brazil's main export partners as well as relatively uncompetitive export prices, which reflect high unit labour costs. Measures aimed at improving competitiveness may involve a reduction in shipping and electricity costs, lowering the tax burden and increasing the base of skilled workers. However, these structural measures will need time to take effect, and are unlikely to have a substantial impact in the short run. Growth is expected to remain below the potential growth rate for the next two years.

Japan

Japanese government indebtedness is the highest among the major developed nations (figure 7). While domestic ownership of government debt makes a debt crisis similar to that of Europe unlikely in the near term, unclear domestic politics raise concerns about the government's ability to put public finances on a more sustainable trajectory. The debt to GDP ratio currently stands at around 205 per cent and is expected to exceed 210 per cent by the end of 2012. (10) A current account surplus enabled net inflows of money to be invested in domestic government bonds. However, the surplus is likely to evaporate. A declining current account surplus threatens to lead to gradually higher interest rates on government borrowing, raising concerns over debt levels over time.

Japan has had a high savings rate, which has allowed the government to sell a large proportion of its bonds to the public. However, an ageing population alters household saving and spending patterns. Older people tend to spend rather than build their savings. This reduces demand for government bonds. In addition, the increase in social and health care spending will further widen the gap between government revenue and spending. Even before the 2011 earthquake, the budget deficit exceeded 8 per cent of GDP.

There has been additional funding pressures on the government since the earthquake. They stem from the reconstruction needs and the necessity to import extra fuel required to plug the gap in electricity generation after the shutdown of the nuclear plants. Both the high volume of energy imports and record high prices have caused the trade balance to deteriorate. Pressure on the current account is not expected to ease soon as there is no quick solution for power generation problems.

[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]

Japan's competitive advantage in a number of key industries has been declining. Current budgetary pressures restrict the long-term R&D investment that once helped the country to become a global leader in manufacturing. In addition, an appreciation of the Yen vis-a-vis both the dollar and the euro makes exports less competitive. The external environment has also become less favourable. A dispute with China (Japan's largest export market with a 20 per cent share) over the ownership of a chain of islands, and the ongoing debt crisis in Europe (Japan's third largest export market with around a 12 per cent share), are negatively affecting export demand and the trade balance. In addition, both factors have a damaging effect on a stream of income from Japanese foreign assets, thus further complicating funding of a budget deficit. If nothing is done to address these issues, over time Japan will end up seeking international investors to fund its deficit. Once investors realise that the status quo has changed, rates on government bonds will gradually rise.

In an attempt to solve the deficit and debt problem the government has approved an increase in consumption tax, scheduled for April 2014 and October 2015. Our forecast shows that it will shift consumption towards the end of 2013 and the beginning of 2014. On the assumption that about half of consumed goods attract a consumption tax, we simulated the effect of the increase in the consumption tax on inflation and the budget deficit, using NiGEM. Based on the simulation results, an increase in consumption tax will increase inflation by an average of 0.3 percentage points over 2015 and 2016, and decrease the budget deficit to GDP ratio only marginally by about 0.2 percentage points in the medium terra.

Japan's strong economic performance at the beginning of this year has come almost to a standstill. A deteriorating external environment also weighs on growth. Annual GDP growth this year is expected to be about 2 1/4 per cent due to strong output in the first half of the year. We anticipate that the external environment will hinder activity and we project growth of just under 1 per cent in 2013.

China

China's growth outlook has weakened. As both external and domestic factors are expected to continue to dampen activity, the critical issue is whether China is heading towards a 'hard' rather than a 'soft' lending.

GDP grew by 7.6 per cent in the second quarter of this year. This is the lowest reading for the past three years. The last time China experienced a similar pace of growth deceleration was in 2009, during the global financial crisis. Yet the current slowdown is mostly engineered by the government, who aim to reduce the economy's reliance on investment and steer it further towards consumption. The slowdown of output growth in itself is not necessarily of great concern.

Weaker activity initiated by the government has coincided with a worsening external environment, although there are counterbalancing factors. First, infrastructure investment projects by the government have been speeded up, and this seems to have stabilised growth in fixed asset investment. Second, the labour market and retail sales have been holding up quite well.

Heavy reliance on investment to generate growth has led to a high investment to output ratio, which according to the latest data is around 46 per cent. In comparison the ratios for the US and Japan are 15 and 20 per cent respectively. In general, when rapid economic growth is generated by fast growing investment, funded by a financially repressed banking system, debt structures become risky. Companies and governments tend to overuse capital as an input when the cost of capital is artificially low.

The latest figure for the government debt to GDP ratio is around 26 per cent. (11) However, this excludes contingent liabilities, hidden banking debt, regional government balances and the effects of a slowing economy on the balance sheet. Nonetheless, given the low government debt ratio and the high reserve requirement ratios for the banks, there is still room for fiscal and monetary stimulus. The government has already planned a number of infrastructure schemes. In order to avoid excessive debt accumulation, it is vital to invest in those projects where an increase in productivity supersedes the cost of the investment. If the government continues its cautious approach towards internal rebalancing, our forecast envisages output growth of about 7 1/2 per cent per annum this year and next, with a further moderation to about 7 per cent per annum in the medium term.

South Korea and Taiwan

The outlook for growth in both of these North East Asian economies has weakened. Performance in both countries is considered to be a leading indicator for the direction of the world economy. How much should we be reading into their current weakening growth and worry about a future global downshift?

South Korea and Taiwan are small and very open economies with a share of total trade to GDP of 96 and 130 per cent respectively. Their economies are highly cyclical and geared towards the electronics sector. A decline in new orders in these countries may be driven by problems specific to this sector. Given generally weaker consumer demand in Europe and the US, it is not surprising to see a lack of demand for electronic products. Capital spending by companies, including expenditure on technology, has also fallen. Both economies are an important part of a global supply chain. A reduction in orders could point to an impending fall in production in other countries using components from South Korea and Taiwan. For example, as China has export shares in total trade of around 26 and 41 per cent in South Korea and Taiwan respectively, the effects of a decline in export growth can permeate the entire supply chain.

While the bias towards the electronics sector is of wider interest, the slowdown in both countries must not be ignored. We project about 2 1/2 and 1 per cent growth for South Korea and Taiwan respectively this year.

[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]

Australia and New Zealand

Unlike many other advanced economies, economic growth has been and remains strong. Yet this performance is uneven across sectors, with the raw materials and mining sector the key driver. Australia's challenge is to extend growth beyond the mining boom, although in the medium term we expect this to remain a strong pillar for growth. GDP is forecast to grow by 2.4 and 3.3 per cent in 2013 and 2014, respectively.

Although non-oil commodity prices have fallen, they are expected to remain firm over the medium term, supported by the industrial transformation in emerging Asia, which takes over 40 per cent of Australia's merchandise exports. The current construction of large natural gas and iron ore projects will add a further boost to private sector investment and exports.

While the commodity and related services sectors have experienced strong growth, this may have had a cost to other sectors of the economy, a modern version of the so-called 'Dutch disease'. The vigorous export performance of the mining sector has resulted in a strong Australian dollar, damaging other industries in the country, such as tourism and manufacturing. The government needs to develop a strategy to ensure more diversified growth in the long run, beyond the mining boom. Notably, the government has commissioned a white paper on how the country can benefit from the Asian boom more broadly, rather than solely as a commodity supplier.

New Zealand's medium-term growth will largely rely on the speed and delivery of the rebuilding of the Canterbury region after the earthquake in 2011. We expect growth to accelerate, after having been restrained in recent years by the withdrawal of fiscal stimulus, a strong currency and a decline in commodity prices. We forecast GDP growth of 2 per cent this year and 2.7 per cent in 2013.

Canterbury was hit by an earthquake with several aftershocks which destroyed large parts of Christchurch, the capital of the Canterbury region and the third largest urban area in the country. So far, the reconstruction has been delayed due to continuing aftershocks. Repair work is ongoing and, as the seismic activity is finally calming down, rebuilding is predicted to pick up in the medium term. While this is expected to add a substantial boost to the economy, households have high levels of debt which will limit the growth momemtum.

India

The outlook for growth has weakened significantly. Although the government has recently introduced measures aimed at revitalising the economy, it remains to be seen if it will be enough to have an effect on slowing activity.

Growth in the second quarter of this year eased to 4.0 per cent, the slowest for three years, creating a risk that India's sovereign credit rating is downgraded to below investment grade. A downgrade itself is not expected to cause a significant problem; solvency rules force local banks and insurance companies to buy government bonds, which they will continue to do irrespective of the rating. India is not heavily dependent on external borrowing- its total external debt in 2011-12 was 20 per cent of GDP, with short-term debt less than a quarter of the total. However, with the current account in deficit, having an investment grade rating is important to minimise the cost of capital. The government needs foreign investment to fund infrastructure projects to support medium-term growth.

The government has increased the price of diesel by 14 per cent in an effort to decrease the energy subsidy. The fiscal effect of this will be small, but it shows a readiness to adopt difficult reforms. It has followed this by liberalising FDI restrictions in retail, insurance and pension industries. Although this is a step in the right direction, more serious reforms will take time and there is always a risk of slippage. We do not expect growth to recover quickly and forecast it to be around 5 1/4 per cent this year, with a mid-term projection of just under 7 per cent per annum.

[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]

Russia

Growth started slowing down in the middle of last year from 1.7 per cent in the third quarter to only 0.1 per cent in the second quarter of this year. Traditional growth drivers--domestic demand, supported by nominal wage growth and rising commodity prices and government spending, which increased from 16 per cent of GDP before the crisis to 25 per cent at its peak, have exhausted their potential. If the government does not embark on a course of structural reforms to improve the business environment and the investment climate, growth will moderate to around 3 per cent per year, which is well below Russia's potential of 4-5 per cent.

A rising labour share of income has been the main driving force behind growth in recent years. The share of earnings in GDP increased from 44 per cent in 2005 to 53 per cent in 2009, levelling off at just below 50 per cent in 2010-11. Real wages have been eroded this year by increasing inflation, which breached the 6 per cent upper limit set by the Bank of Russia which led to an increase in the refinancing rate by 25 basis points to 8.25 per cent.

The oil price has partly recovered from a drop in the second quarter. However, it is unlikely that we will see the record-breaking oil price growth observed over the past decade which provided a windfall for the Russian economy. Increased production of oil is also improbable. In a situation of weak global demand and the high costs of developing alternative supply sources, the impact of oil revenue on growth will be at best neutral and potentially negative over the next several years.

The Federal Budget proposal for 2013-15 sets the target for a balanced budget by 2015 and introduces a new budget rule. The government budget will have to be calculated based on an average price of oil for the past five years, increasing gradually to ten years. Excess revenues (if any) will be stored in the Reserve fund. This is a wise decision considering the volatility of commodity prices and the substantial growth of the non-oil and gas deficit in recent years--from below 5 per cent of GDP in 2008 to above 10 per cent now. However, this puts significant pressure on government spending, especially taking into account the President's pre-election promises. As a result, the Ministry of Finance included less than half of these pledges into the Federal budget, moving the rest into the regional budgets, which raises doubts about their implementation.

European Union

The Euro Area economy continues to contract. The link between fragile banking systems and weak fiscal positions has raised concerns over sovereign credit risk. International capital flows have created a fractured Eurozone, with northern and southern European countries facing very different prospects. Policy measures aimed at restoring confidence and growth and increasing integration within the Euro Area are a step in the right direction. The banking union is an important complement to the financial safety net for the Euro Area. Although the plans will not solve the current crisis, it is the first sign of a coherent strategy for addressing the underlying issues.

Under the OMT bond-buying programme, the ECB can buy an unlimited amount of bonds of indebted Euro Area members, on condition that these countries make a formal request for bail-out. Conditions will be attached to the support and the critical test will be the terms and enforcement mechanisms. Steps have been taken to improve the resilience of banks in Europe; but they remain weak and vulnerable to shocks. The main objectives of the banking union are to guarantee effective supervision and crisis management and to preserve a single market for financial services. It will imply Euro Area wide banking supervision by the ECB, common rules for bank resolution and a common deposit guarantee scheme. Euro Area banks can be recapitalised directly by the ESM if recapitalisation by national governments is insufficient (the details of the process of injecting cash from the ESM directly into European banks are still under discussion). However, the terms of a common bail-out are very far from agreed and involve a difficult process of balancing realism without encouraging moral hazard.

Table 2 lists the largest banks in Europe. In 2011 ten banks each had total assets exceeding 1 trillion [euro], with the largest, Deutsche Bank, exceeding 2 trillion [euro]. In relation to domestic GDP, eight banks had total assets exceeding 100 per cent of national GDP, with assets of the largest, Nordea, exceeding 197 per cent and those of Danske Bank amounting to 194 per cent. Clearly many banks are still far too big to fail. Given the limited capacities of the ESM (about 500 billion [euro]) and the size of systemically important banks, either a fail-safe resolution system is required or the business model of very large banks is inconsistent with system stability.

The Liikanen Report published in October suggests that proprietary trading of securities and derivatives, and deposit taking within the banking group, should be separated. Separation would in theory make banking groups simpler and more transparent, and it would facilitate market discipline and supervision. Whether such rules can be designed in practice has yet to be demonstrated. The Liikanen Group also emphasises the importance of bank recovery and resolution systems, as well as stronger capital requirements. Again the key issue will be the politics of burden sharing and not the concepts.

Compliant with the EBA recommendation as of end of June 2011 to increase the ratio of core capital to risk-weighted assets, the majority of banks have increased the level of their capital above the 9 per cent target after accounting for the sovereign buffer. In the case of four banks (Banca Monte Dei Paschi Di Siena S.p.A, Cyprus Popular Bank Public Co Ltd, Bank of Cyprus Public Co Ltd and Nova Kreditna Banka Maribor d.d.) backstops have been undertaken, with support of the corresponding national governments. The capital strengthening exercise resulted in an injection of 200 billion [euro] in the European banking system between December 2011 and June 2012, the bulk of it through direct capital measures. Figure 10 shows the ratio of core tier 1 capital to risk-weighted assets ratio after sovereign capital buffer in the largest European banks.

Although the situation in the banking sector has improved, macroeconomic prospects for the Euro Area remain bleak. We forecast that the Euro Area economy will contract this year by 0.5 per cent. Next year will see nearly flat growth at 0.3 per cent and a modest recovery in 2014. The wide divergences between individual member states persist and make managing the crisis difficult. The worst performers next year are likely to be Greece, Portugal, Spain and Italy, while Finland, Austria and Germany are expected to be on the other end of the growth spectrum. The Southern European economies are constrained by tight fiscal policies, very unfavourable financial conditions and large capital flight. The core economies will see low, but positive, growth supported by low interest rates. However, we have revised our forecasts for growth in 2013 lower in both France and Germany.

The difficult domestic situation in the Euro Area is exacerbated by slowing external demand. Given the level of openness, the smaller members of the EU, Estonia, Slovakia and Slovenia, as well as Belgium and Ireland, are expected to be affected by the global slowdown to a larger extent through the trade volume channel than the economies of southern Europe. At the same time, the less open countries of southern Europe, such as Greece, Italy or Spain, face competitiveness issues which may feel more acute during the slowdown.

[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]

Germany

The fiscal crisis and tight financial conditions in a number of Euro Area countries and the global economic slowdown are weighing on the outlook for Germany. The domestic situation remains relatively robust. Favourable conditions for domestic demand are supported by a relatively sound banking sector.

The uncertainty triggered by the debt crisis is weighing on domestic demand and households' purchasing decisions. However, the situation in the labour market remains favourable. Low unemployment and strong wage growth are supporting consumer spending. The unemployment rate remains at historically low levels (see previous Reviews) and recently the social partners have negotiated significant wage rises throughout various sectors of the economy. While it was agreed that in the service sector wage increases would be spread over a longer period of time, wage increases in industry would be introduced in the short term. On top of the agreements for core staff, wage bargainers in the metal-working and electrical engineering sector and the chemical industry agreed on wage add-ons for agency-hired temporary workers. Figure 11 shows wage growth in Germany and selected European countries. The acceleration in wage growth in Germany, especially in the context of declining wages in some Southern European countries, has been contributing to internal Euro Area rebalancing.

Despite the unfavourable external situation, Germany's exports increased in the first half of 2012. While export growth to the non-Euro Area countries continued unabated, exports to Euro Area countries stagnated. The demand for German exports from the individual Euro Area members reflects their macroeconomic situation; exports to Spain and Italy declined, while exports to the Netherlands and Austria remained on an upward course, and the value of goods exported to France stagnated. The growth in exports was driven by exports of information and communication technology products, electrical equipment, motor vehicles, and chemical industry products. Manufacturers of metals and metal products suffered a setback in the international market and it is expected that this tendency will deepen, as the economic growth in international markets and in particular China is forecast to slow down.

[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]

The situation in public finances is sound by international standards. The budget deficit fell to 1 per cent of GDP last year, and is expected to fall further this year and next as a result of the favourable growth structure for government revenue, relatively moderate spending on pensions and unemployment benefits, and very good financing conditions. Unfortunately, the debt to GDP ratio is likely to rise again, after the impact of liquidation of the regional bank WestLB and the European Stability Mechanism contributions. In line with the recommendation of the European Banking Authority regarding banks' recapitalisation, German banks have increased their levels of capital. After deduction of the sovereign capital buffer, all 12 German institutions achieved the minimum core tier 1 capital ratio of 9 per cent. The average ratio at 10.7 per cent implies that the minimum requirement was exceeded by 15.5 billion [euro]. Table 3 shows results by individual bank. The overall resilience of the banking sector in Germany has improved.

France

The economy has been at a standstill for four consecutive quarters and shows little sign of an early return to growth. Recent developments in European monetary policy have eased tensions on financial markets, but further austerity measures in the Euro Area and relatively weak trade prospects will hinder growth. Overall, our forecast has been revised downward, with the economy expected to remain essentially flat this year and next, while recovering only slowly in 2014. This stagnation mainly reflects a lack of domestic demand. Rising unemployment and falling real disposable income are holding back household consumption and residential investment. Deteriorating business sentiment also points to weak investment (figure 12). Exports should continue to grow in 2013, but very weak conditions in the Euro Area will limit any upturn.

The 2013 budget brings further risks to the economy. An announced 30 billion [euro] in additional tightening measures, mainly in tax rises for high earners and large businesses, aim to reduce the fiscal deficit from 4.5 to 3 per cent of GDP. The optimistic growth assumption underlying this budget (0.8 per cent) raises risks of fiscal slippage and/or further austerity measures. (Lending to the private sector remains weak.) The ECB's OMT policy has improved financial market sentiment. However lending to the private sector remains weak. French banks are exposed to Spanish and Italian creditors and so prospects will depend on how events unfold in the neighbouring economies.

[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]

Italy

The economic outlook is poor, as the recession will deepen this year and extend into 2013. The introduction of the ECB's OMT programme has reduced insolvency risk but the longer-term challenges remain. The government has avoided a bailout despite rescuing its third largest bank. Nevertheless, the recent EBA stress test showed that Italian banks have lower capital ratios compared to the European average. Under these circumstances, the likelihood of Italy requesting a bailout is increasing.

In this recession, in contrast to 2008-9, consumer confidence is falling at the same pace as business confidence due to a rapid increase in the unemployment rate (figure 13). This will weaken domestic demand. The weak external environment also takes its toll on the economy, with Europe 'muddling through' the sovereign debt crisis and the emerging markets slowing down. Consequently output is expected to contract by 2.3 per cent this year and 0.7 per cent next year.

The government plans to meet its fiscal target despite the deepening recession. Tight austerity measures raise concerns from both parties, and the coming elections could moderate fiscal consolidation plans. Fiscal slippage may also emerge if further bank rescues are required. Falling household income may erode bank balance sheets, forcing them to tighten lending conditions.

[FIGURE 13 OMITTED]

Spain

Spain's economic prospects remain poor. The economy is expected to be in recession this year and next. The banking sector was bailed out in the summer, a severe fiscal austerity programme has been put in place, house prices continue to fall and unemployment continues to rise. Nevertheless, the recent programme of intervention by the ECB in the secondary bond markets has alleviated conditions in the short terra, hence reducing sovereign bond yields. However, it has not eliminated the risk of Spain needing further international support.

Output is expected to contract by 1.8 and 1.3 per cent respectively this year and next, owing to a decline in domestic demand, tight austerity measures and the deterioration of the external environment. Business and consumer confidence collapsed as a result of ongoing sovereign issues in the Euro Area and the weakening global economy, particularly as Europe is the biggest export market for Spanish goods and services.

The labour market crisis is expected to worsen, with over one in four workers being unemployed next year. It will be further exacerbated by government plans to reduce public sector employees as part of its austerity measures. A reduction in public sector workers could be politically sensitive, with trade unions battling against cuts and weakening public support for the current government. According to a poll reported in the media, government popularity has fallen by a third.

[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]

Furthermore, the government has also introduced labour market reforms to ease hiring and firing, reformed the unemployment benefit system, increased the retirement age, and linked wages to productivity rather than inflation. As unemployment continues to rise, wages are expected to decline further and intensify the internal devaluation. In consequence, household income will be depressed and consumer spending is expected to continue to decline through 2014.

The probability of missing this year's fiscal target has increased. Additional consolidation measures were introduced in September but, given the severe impairment of the banking system, the negative impact on growth will offset much of the budgetary improvement. The bulk of the fiscal adjustment falls on autonomous regions. Local and regional elections are due in the next few weeks, making regional expenditure more inelastic. However, the recent OMT programme announced by the ECB has alleviated the situation in the short terra and reduced sovereign bond yields allowing the government to raise money at a lower cost.

Non-performing loans continue to rise as house prices adjust. This will put further pressure on banks' balance sheets. M2, a measure of private sector deposits in the banking sector, continues to decline with large capital flight out of the banking system. This is despite the recent recapitalisation and falling credit risk in the banking sector. As a result, there is less money available to lend to the real economy, leading to a contraction in private investment and consumption. Figure 14 shows lending to both businesses and households in nominal terms is contracting at an increasing rate.

Further capital flight is a major risk as international investors continue to reduce their exposure to Spanish assets. The feedback loop between falling asset prices leading to capital flight, which reduces credit availability even further, must be halted. We expect the government to seek a further bailout sooner rather than later.

Greece

As the economy continues to contract, soaring unemployment and repeated breaches of the conditions set by the Troika make it harder for the new government to start a process of renegotiation. A voluntary withdrawal from EMU is unlikely given the preference of the populus, confirmed in the recent election. However, more achievable conditions set by the Troika, including for instance the official sector's involvement in writing off part of their debt and extending the time given to implement the programme, are likely to be necessary if Greece is to prevent the rising tide of discontent becoming even more serious.

We expect a deep contraction in output in 2012-14, with an increasing likelihood of recession continuing into 2015. This makes it almost impossible for the government to achieve the Troika's targets. Greece requires cash within a month to meet its obligations towards public sector employees and pensioners, or face bankruptcy. All components of domestic demand are contracting, whilst the external sector continues to contribute to growth despite slowing global demand (see figure 15). We expect the current account to be in balance in the next two years, which will provide some support to domestic capital markets. Unemployment is expected to be around 24 per cent this year and about 26 per cent next year, with more than hall of 15-24 year-olds out of work.

[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]

New Member States

Economic growth in Central and Eastern Europe is expected to decelerate following the major weakening of the global economy. The scale of the slowdown will vary across individual economies, reflecting their idiosyncratic structural features. The cross-border integration trend in the banking sector has reversed; risks of withdrawal of capital from Central and Eastern European banking systems remain.

This year will see a dip in economic activity in Central Europe. Three countries--Slovenia, Hungary and the Czech Republic--are forecast to record recessions. The highest growth rates are expected to materialise in the Baltic countries, however, the pace of growth will remain well below its potential. A moderate recovery is expected to materialise throughout the region next year. The scale of the slowdown and the speed of the successive adjustment process in individual economies will depend on the level of their openness, the sensitivity of their labour markets and the scale of resilience of their banking systems.

Recent quarters have seen a reversal of cross-border integration trends in banking across Europe. While the large European banks had significantly increased their EU and global operations before the crisis, increasing the integration of the European banking market, this trend reversed after the crisis. Initiatives such as the II Vienna Initiative (see the July Review) have been designed to prevent an abrupt withdrawal of capital by Western European banks from banking systems in Central and Eastern Europe. However, risks of further national fragmentation of banking markets remain. Some banks may pull out from foreign markets and aim to achieve a greater matching of assets and liabilities on a country-by-country basis. This process may have negative repercussions for Central and Eastern European economies. The loan to deposit ratio of many cross-border groups present in the region is high, which reflects the use of wholesale funding raised by the parent entity to finance business in host countries. The degree of cross-border bank penetration differs across countries--see table 4. The share of assets of non-domestic banks is much larger in the Central and Eastern European countries as compared to the larger economies of Western Europe. In some cases the share of non-domestic banks is about 80-90 per cent of total bank sector assets. This applies to the Baltic countries, Estonia and Lithuania, as well as the Czech Republic, Slovakia and Romania. On the other hand, the large share of foreign assets in the banking sectors implies that potential losses are absorbed abroad and not in the corresponding governments' balance sheets (unlike, for example, in Ireland).

Appendix A: Summary of key forecast assumptions

The forecasts for the world and the UK economy reported in this Review are produced using NIESR's model, NiGEM. The NiGEM model has been in use at the National Institute for forecasting and policy analysis since 1987, and is also used by a group of about 50 model subscribers, mainly in the policy community. Most countries in the OECD are modelled separately, and there are also separate models of China, India, Russia, Hong Kong, Taiwan, Brazil, South Africa, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovenia, Romania and Bulgaria. The rest of the world is modelled through regional blocks so that the model is global in scope. Ali models contain the determinants of domestic demand, export and import volumes, prices, current accounts and net assets. Output is tied down in the long run by factor inputs and technical progress interacting through production functions, but is driven by demand in the short to medium term. Economies are linked through trade, competitiveness and financial markets and are fully simultaneous. Further details on the NiGEM model are available on http://nimodel.niesr.ac.uk/.

There are a number of key assumptions underlying our current forecast. The interest rates and exchange rate assumptions are shown in tables A1-A2. Our short-term interest rate assumptions are generally based on current financial market expectations, as implied by the rates of return on treasury bills of different maturities. Long-term interest rate assumptions are consistent with forward estimates of short-term interest rates, allowing for a country-specific terra premium in the Euro Area.

In this context, we note the latest ECB Governing Council's decision to maintain key interest rates at the record low of 0.75 per cent. This decision comes in response to weak growth expectations and high uncertainty in financial markets, whilst medium-term inflation expectations for the Euro Area remain in line with the 2 per cent target. Meanwhile, the Bank of England maintains its interest rate at its record low 0.5 per cent and expanded its programme of asset purchase by a further 50 billion [pounds sterling] in July. Asset purchases have reached a total of 375 billion [pounds sterling] to date. The Bank of Japan also maintained its current essentially 0 rate unchanged in the short term in order to support economic growth. In the US, the Federal Reserve aggressively eased monetary policy in September 2012, announcing that interest rates will remain exceptionally low until at least mid-2015, extended the Maturity Extension Programme (MEP) to the end of the year, and introduced a third, and open-ended, round of quantitative easing (QE3), purchasing agency mortgage-backed securities at a rate of $40 billion per month. The US will maintain a highly accommodative stance for a considerable period after economic recovery strengthens. Canada maintained the target for the overnight rate at 1 per cent, anticipating sluggish global growth in the medium terra, whilst inflationary pressures have softened.

Monetary policy in many emerging economies has softened recently, as global inflationary pressures appear to ease and activity is slowing down. The People's Bank of China lowered benchmark rates by a further 31 basis points to 6 per cent in July, whilst the main policy rates in Korea were recently reduced by 25 basis points to 2.75 per cent. The South African Reserve Bank cut interest rates for the first time since September 2010 by 50 basis points, down to 5 per cent. In Brazil, the central bank continues to loosen its monetary policy as a response to lower growth expectations with 10 consecutive interest rate cuts since August 2011, which now stands at a record low of 7.25 per cent.

[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]

Figure A1 illustrates our projections for real long-term interest rates in the US, Euro Area, Japan and Canada. Long real rates have followed nominal rates in a sharp drop since the second quarter of 2011. Announced policies indicate that the monetary stance should remain highly expansionary until the end of 2014. Real interest tares in North America are expected to stabilise close to historical levels by 2017-18, while they are expected to 'normalise' earlier in the Euro Area, due to the high risk premium on borrowing in some Euro Area economies. We see real interest rates in Japan stabilising around a level rather below international rates of return.

Figure A2 depicts the spread between 10-year government bond yields of Spain, Italy, Portugal and Greece over German yields, regarded as a safe haven in the Euro Area. Sovereign risks in the Euro Area have been a major macroeconomic issue for the global economy and financial markets over the past two years. The final agreement on the Private Sector Involvement in the Greek default in January 2012, and more recently the Outright Money Transactions (OMT) introduced by the ECB in September 2012, have brought some relief to bond yields in the vulnerable economies. In our forecast, we have assumed spreads remain at current levels until the end of 2014, and start to recede in 2015.

[FIGURE A2 OMITTED]

Nominal exchange rates against the US dollar are assumed to remain constant at the prevailing rate in the first week of October 2012 until March 2014. After that, they follow a backward-looking uncovered-interest parity condition, based on interest rate differentials relative to the US. Figure A3 illustrates the effective exchange rate projections for the US, Euro Area, Japan, Canada and the UK. The Euro Area effective exchange rate depreciated steadily from early 2011 to mid-2012, amid growing concerns about growth and financial markets, but has seen a modest recovery in the final quarter of the year. This may be more of a reflection of the ultra-loose monetary stance in the US than a decline in the Euro Area risk premium. Meanwhile, Japanese interventions to bring their currency down against the dollar brought some relief in the first half of the year. However, the Yen effective exchange rate started to appreciate again in the second half of the year, and stands roughly 40 per cent above its level at the beginning of 2008. Sterling lost nearly 20 per cent of its value between the end of 2007 and the end of 2009, but has strengthened by 6 1/2 per cent in effective terms since mid-2011.

Our oil price assumptions for the short term are based on those of the US Energy Information Administration, who use information from forward markets as well as an evaluation of supply conditions. In the longer term, we assume that real oil prices will rise in line with the real interest rate. The oil price assumptions underlying our current forecast are reported in figure A4 and in table 1 at the beginning of this chapter. Annual average oil prices, based on the average of Brent and Dubai spot prices, rose by almost 40 per cent between 2010 and 2011. Tight demand and supply balances and the Libyan crisis triggered this rise. Prices increased by about 9 per cent in the first quarter of this year in response to the stand-off over Iran's nuclear plans, but have reverted back since April amid growing concerns about global economic activity. In our forecast, we assume that oil prices will average $110.7 per barrel this year, up by about $4.6 per barrel compared to our July 2012 baseline assumptions.

[FIGURE A3 OMITTED]

Our equity price assumptions for the US reflect the return on capital. Other equity markets are assumed to move in line with the US market, but are adjusted for different exchange rate movements and shifts in country-specific equity risk premia. Figure A5 illustrates the key equity price assumptions underlying our current forecast. Global share prices dropped sharply in mid-2011 in response to the deepening of the Euro Area debt crisis and the downgrade of US government debt. However, we have seen a rebound in most of the largest economies over the past year. Within Europe, share price developments have diverged sharply, with a rise in prices in Germany, the UK and a few others, such as Ireland, while share prices have continued to deteriorate in Greece, Spain, Portugal and others. In Japan, share prices have recovered none of the losses suffered at the height of the financial crisis, and stand 55 per cent below their average level in 2007.

[FIGURE A4 OMITTED]

Fiscal policy assumptions for 2012-14 follow announced policies. Average personal sector tax rates and effective corporate tax rate assumptions underlying the projections are reported in table A3. Government revenue as a share of GDP reported in the table reflects these tax rate assumptions and our forecast projections for income and profits, as well as our projections for consumption tax revenue. Government spending is expected to decline as a share of GDP in most countries reported in the table, with the exceptions of Germany and Finland. We expect little relief in the burden of government interest payments in the vulnerable Euro Area economies of Ireland, Spain, Greece, Portugal and Italy.

[FIGURE A5 OMITTED]
Table A1. Interest rates

Per cent per annum

                   Central bank intervention rates

              US     Canada    Japan    Euro Area     UK

2010         0.25     0.59      0.10       1.00      0.50
2011         0.25     1.00      0.10       1.25      0.50
2012         0.25     1.00      0.10       0.88      0.50
2013         0.25     1.00      0.10       0.75      0.50
2014         0.62     1.18      0.10       0.75      0.50
2015         1.17     1.41      0.10       1.04      0.84
2016-2020    1.96     2.07      0.52       2.17      1.71

2012   Q1    0.25     1.00      0.10       1.00      0.50
2012   Q2    0.25     1.00      0.10       1.00      0.50
2012   Q3    0.25     1.00      0.10       0.78      0.50
2012   Q4    0.25     1.00      0.10       0.75      0.50
2013   Q1    0.25     1.00      0.10       0.75      0.50
2013   Q2    0.25     1.00      0.10       0.75      0.50
2013   Q3    0.25     1.00      0.10       0.75      0.50
2013   Q4    0.25     1.00      0.10       0.75      0.50
2014   Q1    0.49     1.00      0.10       0.75      0.50
2014   Q2    0.50     1.23      0.10       0.75      0.50
2014   Q3    0.70     1.25      0.10       0.75      0.50
2014   Q4    0.80     1.25      0.10       0.75      0.50
2015   Q1    1.00     1.25      0.10       0.98      0.61
2015   Q2    1.10     1.41      0.10       1.00      0.80
2015   Q3    1.25     1.50      0.10       1.00      0.90
2015   Q4    1.35     1.50      0.10       1.18      1.05

                     10-year government bond yields

              US     Canada    Japan    Euro Area     UK

2010          3.2      3.2      1.2        3.3        3.6
2011          2.8      2.8      I.I        3.9        3.1
2012          1.8      1.9      0.9        3.3        1.8
2013          1.8      1.9      0.8        3.2        1.7
2014          2.1      2.2      0.9        3.6        1.9
2015          2.4      2.4      I.0        3.7        2.2
2016-2020     3.1      3.1      1.4        3.9        2.9

2012   Q1     2.0      2.0      1.0        3.5        2.1
2012   Q2     1.8      1.9      0.9        3.4        1.8
2012   Q3     1.6      1.8      0.8        3.2        1.5
2012   Q4     1.6      1.7      0.8        3.0        1.5
2013   Q1     1.7      1.8      0.8        3.1        1.6
2013   Q2     1.8      1.9      0.8        3.2        1.6
2013   Q3     1.9      1.9      0.8        3.3        1.7
2013   Q4     1.9      2.0      0.8        3.4        1.8
2014   Q1     2.0      2.1      0.8        3.5        1.8
2014   Q2     2.1      2.1      0.8        3.6        1.9
2014   Q3     2.2      2.2      0.9        3.7        1.9
2014   Q4     2.2      2.3      0.9        3.8        2.0
2015   Q1     2.3      2.3      0.9        3.8        2.1
2015   Q2     2.3      2.4      0.9        3.7        2.1
2015   Q3     2.4      2.5      I.0        3.7        2.2
2015   Q4     2.5      2.5      I.0        3.7        2.3

Table A2. Nominal exchange rates

                      Percentage change in effective rate

              US     Canada    Japan   Euro    Germany   France
                                       Area

2010          -3.1       9.5     4.6    -6.1      -3.6      -2.8
2011          -3.0       2.1     7.2     2.3       0.7      I.I
2012           3.5       0.7     3.4    -3.5      -1.9      -1.9
2013          -0.8       1.4     0.2     0.2       0.0       0.2
2014           0.6      -0.5    -0.6     0.3       0.1       0.2
2015           0.5      -0.3    -0.2     0.6       0.2       0.3
2012   Q1     -0.4       3.2    -2.4    -2.8      -1.5      -1.2
2012   Q2      2.1      -2.8     0.1   -I.I       -0.5      -0.5
2012   Q3     -0.1       3.4     2.6    -1.7      -0.9      -0.8
2012   Q4     -1.7       0.7    -0.9     1.9       0.9       0.9
2013   Q1     -0.1       0.0    -0.1    -0.1       0.0       0.0
2013   Q2     -0.1       0.0    -0.1    -0.1       0.0       0.0
2013   Q3      0.2      -0.1    -0.2     0.1       0.0       0.0
2013   Q4      0.2      -0.1    -0.2     0.1       0.0       0.0
2014   Q1      0.2      -0.1    -0.2     0.1       0.0       0.0
2014   Q2      0.1      -0.1    -0.1     0.1       0.0       0.1
2014   Q3      0.2      -0.1    -0.1     0.1       0.0       0.1
2014   Q4      0.1      -0.1    -0.1     0.1       0.1       0.1
2015   Q1      0.1      -0.1    -0.1     0.2       0.1       0.1
2015   Q2      0.1       0.0     0.0     0.1       0.1       0.1
2015   Q3      0.1       0.0     0.0     0.2       0.1       0.1
2015   Q4      0.1       0.0     0.0     0.2       0.1       0.1

         Percentage             Bilateral rate per US $
          change in
       effective rate

        Italy     UK     Canadian     Yen     Euro    Sterling
                             $

2010      -3.3    -0.2       1.026    87.8    0.755       0.647
2011       1.4     0.0       0.995    79.8    0.719       0.624
2012      -1.7     4.6       1.000    79.1    0.779       0.630
2013       0.3     1.2       0.984    78.5    0.773       0.620
2014       0.3     0.4       0.991    79.2    0.776       0.620
2015       0.5     0.6       0.995    79.5    0.776       0.619
2012      -1.4     1.3       0.994    79.3    0.763       0.636
2012      -0.5     2.6       1.027    80.1    0.780       0.632
2012      -0.6     1.2       0.996    78.6    0.800       0.633
2012      I.0     -0.1       0.983    78.3    0.772       0.619
2013       0.0     0.0       0.983    78.3    0.772       0.619
2013       0.0     0.0       0.983    78.3    0.772       0.619
2013       0.1     0.1       0.985    78.5    0.773       0.620
2013       0.1     0.1       0.987    78.7    0.774       0.620
2014       0.1     0.1       0.988    78.9    0.775       0.621
2014       0.1     0.1       0.990    79.1    0.776       0.621
2014       0.1     0.1       0.992    79.3    0.776       0.621
2014       0.1     0.1       0.993    79.4    0.776       0.620
2015       0.1     0.2       0.994    79.5    0.776       0.620
2015       0.1     0.2       0.995    79.5    0.776       0.619
2015       0.1     0.1       0.995    79.6    0.776       0.619
2015       0.1     0.1       0.996    79.6    0.775       0.618

Table A3. Government revenue assumptions

                     Average income       Effective corporate
                       tax rate               tax rate
                     (per cent) (a)          (per cent)

                2012    2013    2014    2012    2013    2014

Australia       14.5    14.6    14.5    25.7    25.7    25.7
Austria         31.7    31.7    31.4    19.9    19.9    19.9
Belgium         33.0    33.2    33.3    16.7    16.7    16.7
Canada          21.9    22.0    22.0    20.0    20.6    21.4
Denmark         38.0    38.0    38.1    18.1    18.1    18.1
Finland         31.5    31.6    31.6    22.8    23.3    23.3
France          28.9    29.2    29.2    17.6    22.8    22.8
Germany         27.8    27.8    27.8    16.8    16.8    16.8
Greece          17.6    17.6    17.5    13.5    13.5    13.5
Ireland         22.5    22.5    22.8     8.0     8.0     8.0
Italy           29.5    29.4    28.9    28.6    28.6    28.6
Japan           22.8    22.8    23.0    29.3    29.6    29.8
Netherlands     34.0    34.0    34.0     8.0     8.0     8.0
Portugal        21.0    21.3    20.7    18.6    18.6    18.6
Spain           24.9    24.8    24.9    25.2    25.2    25.2
Sweden          29.8    29.8    29.4    30.4    30.4    30.4
UK              23.4    23.8    24.2    17.6    16.3    15.3
US              17.3    17.7    18.2    28.5    28.6    28.9

                     Gov't revenue
                    (% of GDP) (b)

                2012    2013    2014

Australia       32.6    33.6    33.7
Austria         38.5    37.5    37.1
Belgium         44.2    43.3    43.1
Canada          35.8    35.9    36.2
Denmark         45.9    45.9    45.7
Finland         45.9    46.0    45.7
France          45.9    46.6    46.7
Germany         45.2    45.4    45.7
Greece          43.7    44.8    45.6
Ireland         29.5    28.5    27.4
Italy           45.6    46.7    46.4
Japan           31.6    31.6    32.1
Netherlands     41.5    40.9    40.2
Portugal        37.9    38.0    37.3
Spain           35.8    36.9    37.4
Sweden          44.5    43.7    42.9
UK              37.3    37.3    37.7
US              27.8    28.0    28.4

Notes: (a) The average income tax rate is calculated as
total income tax plus both employee and employer social
security contributions as a share of  personal income. (b)
Revenue shares reflect NiGEM aggregates, which may differ
from official government figures.

Table A4. Government spending assumptions(a)

                                                         Deficit
                  Gov't spending        Gov't interest  projected
                     excluding             payments      to fall
                interest payments         (% of GDP)      below
                                                           3%
              2012   2013   2014   2012   2013   2014   of GDP(b)

Australia     33.8   33.3   32.5    1.8    1.7    1.5     2013
Austria       38.8   37.6   36.9    2.5    2.3    2.2     2011
Belgium       43.5   42.6   42.2    3.5    3.2    2.9     2012
Canada        35.7   35.8   35.5    3.5    3.2    3.0     2014
Denmark       48.1   47.4   46.6    1.7    1.6    1.5     2014
Finland       45.0   45.2   45.0    1.4    1.2    1.1       --
France        47.7   47.5   47.1    2.7    2.7    2.5     2015
Germany       44.1   44.4   44.8    2.1    1.8    1.5     2011
Greece        44.4   44.6   43.9    6.7    6.5    6.7     2017
Ireland       33.5   32.0   30.6    4.1    4.3    4.5     2019
Italy         43.0   42.8   41.8    5.3    5.6    5.6     2012
Japan         39.6   39.4   38.5    2.1    1.9    1.7       --
Netherlands   43.3   42.0   40.9    1.9    1.8    1.7     2013
Portugal      39.0   38.2   36.0    4.2    4.4    4.4     2015
Spain         39.6   38.7   37.8    3.2    3.9    4.2     2016
Sweden        43.7   43.1   42.1    1.1    0.9    0.8       --
UK            40.2   39.4   38.5    3.1    3.3    3.2     2017
US            33.5   32.9   32.3    2.9    2.7    2.6     2019

Notes: (a) Expenditure shares reflect NiGEM aggregates,
which may differ from official government figures. (b) The
deficit in Denmark, Finland and  Sweden has not exceeded 3
per cent of GDP in recent history. In Japan and the US,
deficits are not expected to fall below 3 per cent of GDP
within our forecast horizon.


Appendix B: Forecast detail

[FIGURE B1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE B2 OMITTED]

[FIGURE B3 OMITTED]

[FIGURE B4 OMITTED]

Appendix B: Forecast detail
Table B1. Real GDP growth and inflation

                               Real GDP growth (per cent)

                   2010    2011    2012    2013    2014   2015-19

Australia           2.5     2.1     3.3     2.4     3.3       3.4
Austria (a)         2.2     2.7     0.7     1.4     1.8       2.0
Belgium (a)         2.4     1.8    -0.2     0.5     1.1       1.8
Bulgaria (a)        0.5     1.8     0.8     1.8     3.0       2.8
Brazil              7.5     2.7     1.3     3.2     3.5       4.2
China              10.4     9.3     7.6     7.6     7.5       7.1
Canada              3.2     2.4     2.1     1.7     2.0       2.3
Czech Rep.          2.6     1.7    -0.3     1.1     2.0       1.6
Denmark (a)         1.3     0.8     0.4     1.5     1.3       1.8
Estonia (a)         3.3     8.3     2.5     3.7     2.9       2.0
Finland (a)         3.3     2.7       1     1.7     1.9       2.1
France (a)          1.6     1.7     0.2     0.2     1.1       1.6
Germany (a)         4.0     3.1     0.7     1.1     1.5       1.2
Greece (a)         -3.4    -7.0    -6.1    -3.2    -0.4       2.0
Hong Kong           6.8     4.9     1.4     3.9     4.3       3.3
Hungary (a)         1.2     1.7    -0.6     0.7     1.7       3.8
India              10.3     7.0     5.2     5.4     6.6       6.9
Ireland (a)        -0.8     1.4     0.2     0.9     2.6       2.8
Italy (a)           1.8     0.5    -2.3    -0.7     0.7       1.7
Japan               4.6    -0.7     2.2     0.9     1.4       1.4
Lithuania (a)       1.4     6.0     2.5     2.8     4.3       3.8
Latvia (a)         -1.4     5.2     4.3     3.3     3.2       2.5
Mexico              5.5     3.9     4.0     3.3     3.7       3.5
Netherlands (a)     1.6     1.1    -0.2     1.0     1.2       1.5
New Zealand         0.9     0.5     2.0     2.7     2.2       2.1
Norway              0.6     1.5     3.3     2.1     2.9       2.5
Poland (-)          3.9     4.3     2.1     2.8     3.9       3.0
Portugal (a)        1.4    -1.7    -3.0    -1.6     0.7       2.7
Romania (a)        -1.7     2.5       1     3.1     2.8       3.5
Russia              4.3     4.4     3.5     3.1     3.5       3.3
South Africa        2.9     3.1     2.8     3.6     4.5       3.1
S. Korea            6.3     3.6     2.6     2.9     3.4       3.6
Slovakia (a)        4.2     3.3     2.7     2.9     3.4       3.0
Slovenia (a)        1.1       1    -1.3     0.6     1.3       3.2
Spain (a)          -0.3     0.4    -1.8    -1.3     1.2       2.1
Sweden (a)          6.3     3.9     1.3     1.7     2.3       2.5
Switzerland         3.0     1.9     0.9     1.2     1.2       1.7
Taiwan             10.7     4.0       1     3.1     3.3       3.3
UK (a)              1.8     0.9    -0.1     1.1     1.7       2.3
US                  2.4     1.8     2.0     2.0     2.4       2.8
Euro Area (a)       1.9     1.5    -0.5     0.2     1.2       1.6
EU-27 (a)           2.0     1.6    -0.2     0.6     1.5       1.9
OECD                3.0     1.8     1.3     1.4     2.1       2.4
World               5.3     3.9     3.1     3.4     3.9       4.1

                          Annual inflation (a) (per cent)

                   2010    2011    2012    2013    2014   2015-19

Australia           2.8     2.6     1.6     2.5     3.0       3.3
Austria (a)         1.7     3.6     2.4     1.7     1.9       2.4
Belgium (a)         2.3     3.5     2.5     1.5     2.2       2.2
Bulgaria (a)        3.0     3.4     2.4     2.7     3.2       1.9
Brazil              5.1     6.6     5.1     6.7     2.7       5.2
China               3.3     5.4     2.5     2.3     2.7       1.6
Canada              1.3     2.0     1.4     1.3     1.8       2.3
Czech Rep.          1.2     2.1     3.5     2.3     2.4       1.9
Denmark (a)         2.2     2.7     2.4     2.0     2.7       2.2
Estonia (a)         2.7     5.1     4.5     2.6     3.8       3.8
Finland (a)         1.7     3.3     3.1     2.1     1.9       1.3
France (a)          1.7     2.3     2.3     1.8     2.1       1.7
Germany (a)         1.2     2.5     2.1     1.8     1.9       1.3
Greece (a)          4.7     3.1     1.1     1.5     2.5       3.6
Hong Kong           1.4     4.0     3.0     2.9     3.6       2.8
Hungary (a)         4.7     3.9     5.6     4.2     3.4       2.5
India              12.0     8.8     9.2     7.1     6.1       4.1
Ireland (a)        -1.6     1.2     2.2     2.0     1.8       1.8
Italy (a)           1.6     2.9     3.1     1.3     2.0       2.3
Japan              -1.7    -1.1    -0.7    -1.1     0.3       0.6
Lithuania (a)       1.2     4.1     3.2     2.9     2.9       4.1
Latvia (a)         -1.2     4.2     2.6     4.0     3.5       2.5
Mexico              4.2     3.4     4.1     3.6     3.6       2.3
Netherlands (a)     0.9     2.5     3.0     3.0     2.4       2.3
New Zealand         1.7     3.4     1.4     1.2     2.5       2.9
Norway              2.2     1.3     1.0     1.2     2.2       2.4
Poland (-)          2.7     3.9     3.8     2.6     2.6       2.1
Portugal (a)        1.4     3.6     2.8     1.0     1.7       2.5
Romania (a)         6.1     5.8     3.0     2.9     2.6       2.8
Russia              6.9     8.4     5.6     6.4     4.6       4.2
South Africa        4.0     5.0     5.3     4.6     6.2       5.5
S. Korea            2.9     4.0     2.2     1.9     2.7       2.6
Slovakia (a)        0.7     4.1     3.7     2.8     1.9       3.7
Slovenia (a)        2.1     2.1     2.2     2.3     3.2       2.0
Spain (a)           2.0     3.1     2.3     2.0     2.3       2.3
Sweden (a)          1.9     1.4     1.1     1.2     1.7       1.8
Switzerland         0.9     0.1     0.2     0.9     1.7       2.3
Taiwan              0.6     0.8     1.6     2.0     2.0       2.2
UK (a)              3.3     4.5     2.7     2.0     1.6       1.8
US                  1.9     2.4     1.6     1.8     1.9       2.4
Euro Area (a)       1.6     2.7     2.5     1.8     2.1       2.0
EU-27 (a)           2.1     3.1     2.6     1.9     2.1       2.0
OECD                1.7     2.3     1.8     1.7     1.9       2.1
World               4.1     5.2     4.3     3.8     3.2       2.9

Notes: (a) Harmonised consumer price inflation in the EU economies
and inflation measured by the consumer expenditure deflator in the
rest of the world.

Table B2. Fiscal balance and government debt

                           Fiscal balance (per cent of GDP)(a)

                    2010     2011     2012    2013    2014    2019

Australia           -4.7     -3.9     -3.0    -1.4    -0.3    -0.9
Austria (a)         -4.5     -2.6     -2.8    -2.4    -2.0    -1.5
Belgium (a)         -3.9     -3.9     -2.8    -2.5    -2.1    -1.6
Bulgaria            -3.1     -2.1     -1.5    -0.5    -0.4    -0.9
Canada              -5.5     -4.4     -3.4    -3.1    -2.3    -1.6
Czech Rep.          -4.8     -3.1     -3.2    -3.6    -3.2    -2.6
Denmark (a)         -2.5     -1.8     -3.9    -3.2    -2.4    -1.6
Estonia              0.2      1.0     -2.1    -1.2    -0.2    -1.2
Finland (a)         -2.9     -0.9     -0.5    -0.3    -0.4    -1.1
France (a)          -7.1     -5.2     -4.5    -3.6    -3.0    -2.2
Germany (a)         -4.3     -1.0     -1.0    -0.8    -0.7    -1.3
Greece (a)         -10.5     -9.1     -7.5    -6.3    -5.0    -1.6
Hungary             -4.3      4.2     -3.2    -2.7    -2.1    -1.2
Ireland (a)        -31.2    -13.0     -8.1    -7.8    -7.7    -2.6
Italy (a)           -4.6     -3.9     -2.7    -1.7    -1.0    -0.8
Japan               -8.4     -9.5    -10.1    -9.6    -8.0    -5.5
Lithuania           -7.2     -5.5     -4.0    -3.4    -2.6    -1.5
Latvia              -8.2     -3.5     -2.3    -2.4    -2.3    -1.1
Netherlands (a)     -5.0     -4.6     -3.7    -2.9    -2.3    -1.9
Poland              -7.8     -5.1     -3.5    -3.0    -2.3    -1.7
Portugal (a)        -9.8     -4.2     -5.2    -4.6    -3.0    -1.5
Romania             -6.8     -5.2     -3.3    -2.4    -2.0    -1.7
Slovakia            -7.7     -4.8     -3.4    -2.4    -1.5     0.0
Slovenia            -6.0     -6.4     -5.6    -4.6    -3.7    -0.7
Spain (a)           -9.4     -8.6     -7.0    -5.7    -4.6    -1.1
Sweden (a)           0.3      0.3     -0.3    -0.3    -0.1    -0.7
U K (a)            -10.2     -7.8     -7.0    -8.1    -6.6    -1.1
US                 -11.4    -10.2     -8.6    -7.7    -6.4    -2.9

                       Government debt (per cent of GDP, end year)(b)

                   2010    2011    2012    2013    2014    2019

Australia          27.9    30.6    32.4    32.0    30.5    23.5
Austria (a)        71.8    72.2    73.5    72.0    70.0    61.4
Belgium (a)        96.0    98.1   102.4    99.3    96.4    86.4
Bulgaria             --      --      --      --      --      --
Canada             82.1    82.1    82.8    82.8    81.6    71.0
Czech Rep.         38.1    41.2    46.4    48.6    49.8    54.3
Denmark (a)        42.9    46.5    47.4    48.8    48.8    50.0
Estonia              --      --      --      --      --      --
Finland (a)        48.4    48.6    49.3    49.9    50.5    55.9
France (a)         82.7    86.2    91.3    92.3    92.4    89.3
Germany (a)        83.0    81.2    81.1    79.6    78.4    76.9
Greece (a)        145.0   165.4   132.3   142.0   144.0   120.7
Hungary            81.4    80.6    73.4    68.5    65.9    49.1
Ireland (a)        92.5   108.2   113.6   117.6   118.4   114.1
Italy (a)         118.7   120.0   126.8   126.2   122.9   101.9
Japan             193.0   205.0   213.8   221.4   223.4   229.7
Lithuania            --      --      --      --      --      --
Latvia               --      --      --      --      --      --
Netherlands (a)    62.9    65.1    69.8    69.2    68.4    65.1
Poland             54.8    56.3    55.8    54.3    54.2    51.0
Portugal (a)       93.4   107.8   118.1   121.8   121.3   102.8
Romania              --      --      --      --      --      --
Slovakia             --      --      --      --      --      --
Slovenia             --      --      --      --      --      --
Spain (a)          61.2    68.5    83.0    88.8    90.7    82.1
Sweden (a)         39.4    38.4    37.0    36.2    34.8    29.9
U K (a)            79.4    85.0    89.8    94.3    97.5    90.7
US                 96.9   101.2   108.0   110.7   112.4   103.4

Notes: (a) General government financial balance; Maastricht
definition for EU countries. (b) Maastricht definition for
EU countries. (c) The deficit for  Ireland in 2010 includes
outlay on bank recapitalisation amounting to 20 per cent of
GDP. The outlays are in the form of promissory notes and do
not require upfront financing.

Table B3. Unemployment and current account balance

                       Standardised unemployment rate

               2010    2011    2012    2013    2014   2015-19

Australia       5.2     5.1     5.3     5.3     4.8       4.2
Austria         4.4     4.2     4.3     3.8     3.3       3.4
Belgium         8.3     7.2     7.5     7.0     6.7       7.1
Bulgaria       10.2    11.3    12.4    12.2    10.1       7.1
Canada          8.0     7.5     7.3     7.0     7.2       6.3
China           --      --      --      --      --        --
Czech Rep.      7.3     6.7     6.9     7.2     7.4       6.6
Denmark         7.4     7.6     7.9     7.8     6.7       6.7
Estonia        16.9    12.4    10.3     9.7     9.7       9.6
Finland         8.4     7.8     7.7     7.6     7.4       7.5
France          9.8     9.7    10.4   1 1.0    10.4      10.0
Germany         7.1     5.9     5.5     5.5     5.5       5.8
Greece         12.6    17.7    23.6    25.9    25.3      21.9
Hungary        11.2    10.9    11.0    11.0     9.9       6.8
Ireland        13.7    14.5    14.9    15.2    14.5      12.9
Italy           8.4     8.4    10.6    11.4    10.7       9.9
Japan           5.1     4.6     4.4     4.9     4.7       4.5
Lithuania      17.8    15.4    13.2    14.2    14.3      14.0
Latvia         19.8    16.3    15.5    14.3    13.7      12.4
Netherlands     4.5     4.4     5.2     4.9     4.1       4.8
Poland          9.6     9.7    10.1     9.6     8.8       7.7
Portugal       12.1    12.9    15.7    15.8    11.2       7.7
Romania         7.3     7.4     7.2     6.7     6.4       6.2
Slovakia       14.5    13.6    13.7    12.5    11.7      10.6
Slovenia        7.3     8.2     8.3     8.0     7.7       7.5
Spain          20.1    21.7    24.9    26.7    25.6      19.9
Sweden          8.4     7.5     7.6     7.3     6.6       6.7
UK              7.9     8.1     8.1     8.2     8.0       6.8
US              9.6     8.9     8.1     7.7     7.1       5.9

                   Current account balance (per cent of GDP)

               2010    2011    2012    2013    2014   2015-19

Australia      -2.9    -2.3    -4.5    -5.1    -4.6      -4.4
Austria         3.1     1.9     2.1     3.7     5.1       7.0
Belgium         1.4    -1.0    -1.4     1.7     3.2       4.4
Bulgaria       -1.1     1.2    -7.8   -10.1    -8.9      -5.6
Canada         -3.1    -2.8    -2.8    -2.0    -1.6      -2.0
China           4.4     3.1     3.4     5.5     4.6       2.0
Czech Rep.     -3.9    -2.9     1.8    -1.6    -2.9      -2.6
Denmark         5.5     6.5     4.3     1.2     0.9      -0.6
Estonia         3.0     2.2    -2.4    -3.0    -3.3      -3.2
Finland         1.4    -0.7    -2.1    -1.9    -1.8      -1.1
France         -1.6    -2.0    -3.2    -2.9    -2.5      -2.2
Germany         5.9     5.7     6.7     7.3     7.1       5.1
Greece        -10.1    -9.8    -4.8    -1.1     0.0      -0.4
Hungary         1.2     1.4    -2.0     0.4     0.0      -0.7
Ireland         0.5     0.1     2.3     3.8     1.4       1.3
Italy          -3.5    -3.3    -2.1    -1.0    -0.9       0.3
Japan           3.7     2.0     0.7     0.4     0.5       0.7
Lithuania       1.5    -1.5    -3.6    -3.8     0.0       2.9
Latvia          3.3    -2.6    -4.1    -5.4    -7.1      -8.8
Netherlands     7.0     8.5    12.4    12.0    12.1      13.4
Poland         -4.7    -4.3    -4.2    -0.6     0.4      -2.4
Portugal      -10.0    -6.5    -2.0     0.1     1.2       1.0
Romania        -6.3    -6.4    -5.5    -4.9    -4.5      -6.4
Slovakia       -3.1     0.0     2.7    -0.5    -1.4      -1.8
Slovenia       -0.6     0.0     1.2     3.6     4.2      -0.2
Spain          -4.5    -3.6    -1.9    -1.0    -0.9      -1.4
Sweden          6.6     6.9     6.7     6.2     6.5       7.8
UK             -2.5    -1.9    -3.4    -1.2    -0.9      -1.0
US             -3.0    -3.1    -3.2    -3.1    -2.8      -2.3

Table B4. United States

                                 Percentage change

                           2009    2010    2011    2012

GDP                        -3.1     2.4     1.8     2.0
Consumption                -1.9     1.8     2.5     1.8
Investment : housing      -22.4    -3.7    -1.4     9.7
             business     -18.1     0.7     8.6     8.0
Government: consumption     4.3     0.9    -2.3    -1.2
            investment      0.6    -0.6    -7.2    -3.7
Stockbuilding (a)          -0.8     1.5    -0.2     0.0
Total domestic demand      -4.2     2.8     1.8     2.0
Export volumes             -9.1     1.1     6.7     3.8
Import volumes            -13.5    12.5     4.8     2.9
Average earnings            2.6     2.0     2.3     1.8
Private consumption
  deflator                  0.1     1.9     2.4     1.6
RPDI                       -2.6     2.2     1.6     1.6
Unemployment, %             9.3     9.6     8.9     8.1
General Govt.
  balance as % of GDP     -11.9   -11.4   -10.2    -8.6
General Govt. debt
  as % of GDP (b)          88.4    96.9   101.2   108.0
Current account
  as % of GDP              -2.7    -3.0    -3.1    -3.2

                             Percentage change

                                          Average
                           2013    2014   2015-19

GDP                         2.0     2.4     2.8
Consumption                 1.7     1.6     1.8
Investment : housing        4.9     6.9     9.4
             business       5.0     6.4     6.9
Government: consumption     0.4     0.8     1.8
            investment      0.9     1.2     2.1
Stockbuilding (a)           0.1     0.0     0.0
Total domestic demand       2.0     2.1     2.6
Export volumes              3.6     6.6     5.1
Import volumes              3.2     4.2     4.2
Average earnings            2.0     1.7     3.3
Private consumption
  deflator                  1.8     1.9     2.4
RPDI                        1.4     1.1     1.8
Unemployment, %             7.7     7.1     5.9
General Govt.
  balance as % of GDP      -7.7    -6.4    -4.1
General Govt. debt
  as % of GDP (b)         110.7   112.4   108.7
Current account
  as % of GDP              -3.1    -2.8    -2.3

Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis.

Table B5. Canada Percentage change

                           2009   2010      2011   2012

GDP                        -2.8    3.2       2.4    2.1
Consumption                 0.4    3.3       2.4    1.6
Investment : housing       -8.0   10.2       2.3    5.9
             business     -20.5    8.5      12.9    4.9
Government: consumption     3.6    2.4       0.8   -0.5
          : investment      8.8   17.9      -3.1   -7.9
Stockbuilding (a)          -0.8    0.7       0.3    0.0
Total domestic demand      -2.9    5.3       3.4    1.5
Export volumes            -13.8    6.4       4.6    5.5
Import volumes            -13.4   13.1       7.0    4.2
Average earnings            2.1    2.6       2.9    2.1
Private consumption
  deflator                  0.5    1.3       2.0    1.4
RPDI                        0.9    3.5       1.2    1.8
Unemployment, %             8.3    8.0       7.5    7.3
General Govt.
  balance as % of GDP      -4.9   -5.5      -4.4   -3.4
General Govt. debt
  as % of GDP (b)          80.5   82.1      82.1   82.8
Current account
  as % of GDP              -3.0   -3.1      -2.8   -2.8

                                         Average
                           2013   2014   2015-19

GDP                         1.7    2.0       2.3
Consumption                 2.2    2.7       2.7
Investment : housing        3.9    5.3       6.7
             business       3.8    3.8       3.8
Government: consumption    -0.8   -0.8       1.6
          : investment      0.0    0.5       2.0
Stockbuilding (a)           0.1    0.0       0.0
Total domestic demand       1.9    2.3       2.9
Export volumes              3.1    4.2       3.3
Import volumes              3.4    4.2       4.3
Average earnings            2.3    3.3       4.4
Private consumption
  deflator                  1.3    1.8       2.3
RPDI                        2.8    2.4       3.0
Unemployment, %             7.0    7.2       6.3
General Govt.
  balance as % of GDP      -3.1   -2.3      -1.5
General Govt. debt
  as % of GDP (b)          82.8   81.6      75.0
Current account
  as % of GDP              -2.0   -1.6      -2.0

Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis.

Table B6. Japan Percentage change

                            2009    2010    2011    2012

GDP                         -5.5     4.6    -0.7     2.2
Consumption                 -0.7     2.6     0.1     1.6
Investment : housing       -16.3    -4.5     5.7     1.3
           : business      -14.3     1.1     1.2     4.0
Government : consumption     2.3     2.2     2.0     2.0
           : investment      7.8     0.4    -2.8     6.0
Stockbuilding (a)           -1.5     0.7    -0.4     0.4
Total domestic demand       -3.8     2.8     0.2     2.7
Export volumes             -24.4    24.5    -0.1     4.0
Import volumes             -15.8    11.2     6.3     6.8
Average earnings            -0.4    -1.2     0.5    -2.3
Private consumption
  deflator                  -2.4    -1.7    -1.1    -0.7
RPD1                         1.4     2.1     0.8     0.7
Unemployment, %              5.1     5.1     4.6     4.4
Govt. balance
  as % of GDP               -8.8    -8.4    -9.5   -10.1
Govt. debt
  as % of GDP(b)           187.4   193.0   205.0   213.8
Current account
  as % of GDP                2.9     3.7     2.0     0.7

                                           Average
                            2013    2014   2015-19

GDP                          0.9     1.4     1.4
Consumption                  0.7     0.9     0.3
Investment : housing         3.5     4.0     3.5
           : business        5.1     6.7     4.1
Government : consumption     0.1    -0.3     0.6
           : investment     -5.9    -3.0     0.7
Stockbuilding (a)            0.4     0.0     0.0
Total domestic demand        1.3     1.4     1.0
Export volumes               2.4     5.6     5.6
Import volumes               5.9     6.0     4.2
Average earnings            -0.9    -0.5     1.2
Private consumption
  deflator                  -1.1     0.3     0.6
RPD1                         0.2    -0.3     0.1
Unemployment, %              4.9     4.7     4.5
Govt. balance
  as % of GDP               -9.6    -8.0    -6.1
Govt. debt
  as % of GDP(b)           221.4   223.4   227.8
Current account
  as % of GDP                0.4     0.5     0.7

Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP. (b) End-of-year basis.

Table B7. Euro Area Percentage change

                               2009    2010   2011   2012

GDP                            -4.3     1.9    1.5   -0.5
Consumption                    -0.9     0.9    0.1   -0.9
Private investment            -14.6     0.3    2.2   -3.5
Government: consumption         2.6     0.7   -0.1   -0.6
investment                      0.8    -3.9   -2.7   -4.4
Stockbuilding (a)              -0.8     0.7    0.1   -0.5
Total domestic demand          -3.6     1.3    0.5   -1.8
Export volumes                -12.4     1.0    6.4    3.0
Import volumes                -11.0     9.4    4.2   -0.1
Average earnings                3.1     0.9    1.8    1.6
Harmonised consumer prices      0.3     1.6    2.7    2.5
RPDI                            0.5     0.1   -0.7   -1.3
Unemployment, %                 9.6    10.1   10.1   11.3
Govt. balance as % of GDP      -6.4    -6.2   -4.1   -3.4
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)     79.9    85.3   87.2   91.7
Current account as % of GDP    -0.2    -0.1    0.0    0.9

                                              Average
                               2013    2014   2015-19

GDP                             0.2     1.2    1.6
Consumption                     0.0     0.5    1.0
Private investment              0.0     2.5    4.0
Government: consumption        -1.5     0.4    1.2
investment                     -1.4     2.6    2.1
Stockbuilding (a)               0.0     0.0    0.0
Total domestic demand          -0.4     0.9    1.6
Export volumes                  3.4     3.9    4.0
Import volumes                  2.3     3.6    4.3
Average earnings                1.3     1.4    2.5
Harmonised consumer prices      1.8     2.1    2.0
RPDI                           -0.5     0.4    1.3
Unemployment, %                11.9    11.2   10.1
Govt. balance as % of GDP      -2.7    -2.1   -1.7
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)     91.4    90.6   86.8
Current account as % of GDP     2.1     2.3    2.0

Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.

Table B8. Germany Percentage change

                               2009   2010   2011   2012

GDP                            -5.1    4.0    3.1    0.7
Consumption                     0.3    0.8    1.7    0.9
Investment : housing           -2.5    4.4    6.5    2.8
           : business         -17.1    7.1    7.4   -0.6
Government : consumption        3.0    1.7    1.0    1.0
           : investment         4.7   -0.9   -1.5   -5.1
Stockbuilding(a)               -0.9    0.7    0.3   -0.5
Total domestic demand          -2.4    2.6    2.7    0.3
Export volumes                -12.8   13.4    7.9    4.9
Import volumes                 -8.0   10.9    7.5    4.6
Average earnings                2.9    0.8    2.9    2.3
Harmonised consumer prices      0.2    1.2    2.5    2.1
RPDI                           -0.5    0.9    1.2    1.6
Unemployment, %                 7.8    7.1    5.9    5.5
Govt. balance as % of GDP      -3.2   -4.3     -1     -1
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)     74.4   83.0   81.2   81.1
Current account as % of GDP     5.9    5.9    5.7    6.7

                                             Average
                               2013   2014   2015-19

GDP                             1.1    1.5    1.2
Consumption                     1.5    1.4    1.7
Investment : housing            3.9    1.9    2.7
           : business           1.6    2.4    1.7
Government : consumption        1.5    1.8    1.1
           : investment         4.0    2.6    1.9
Stockbuilding (a)               0.0    0.0    0.0
Total domestic demand           1.6    1.7    1.6
Export volumes                  4.8    3.8    4.1
Import volumes                  6.3    4.3    5.3
Average earnings                2.6    2.3    2.3
Harmonised consumer prices      1.8    1.9    1.3
RPDI                            1.0    0.8    1.3
Unemployment, %                 5.5    5.5    5.8
Govt. balance as % of GDP      -0.8   -0.7     -1
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)     79.6   78.4   77.3
Current account as % of GDP     7.3    7.1    5.1

Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.

Table B9. France Percentage change

                                2009     2010     2011     2012

GDP                             -3.1      1.6      1.7      0.2
Consumption                      0.2      1.4      0.2      0.2
Investment : housing           -12.1     -0.3      3.2      1.0
           : business          -12.9      4.4      5.1      0.3
Government : consumption         2.6      1.7      0.2      0.9
           : investment          2.5     -8.2     -1.8      1.4
Stockbuilding (a)               -1.2      0.5      0.9     -0.5
Total domestic demand           -2.6      1.9      1.7      0.0
Export volumes                 -11.8      9.2      5.5      2.1
Import volumes                  -9.5      8.4      5.2      1.0
Average earnings                 2.9      1.6      3.0      1.8
Harmonised consumer prices       0.1      1.7      2.3      2.3
RPDI                             1.8      1.3     -0.3     -0.1
Unemployment, %                  9.5      9.8      9.7     10.4
Govt. balance as % of GDP       -7.5     -7.1     -5.2     -4.5
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)      79.3     82.7     86.2     91.3
Current account as % of GDP     -1.3     -1.6     -2.0     -3.2

                                                Average
                                2013     2014   2015-19

GDP                              0.2      1.1      1.6
Consumption                      0.6      0.9      0.9
Investment : housing             0.1      0.9      4.5
           : business            0.7        1      2.2
Government : consumption        -1.9      0.2      1.5
           : investment         -2.3      0.7      1.9
Stockbuilding (a)                0.0      0.0      0.0
Total domestic demand           -0.1      0.7      1.4
Export volumes                   2.0      5.3      4.7
Import volumes                   1.0      3.7      4.0
Average earnings                 1.9      2.1      2.7
Harmonised consumer prices       1.8      2.1      1.7
RPDI                            -0.1      0.8      1.1
Unemployment, %                 11.0     10.4     10.0
Govt. balance as % of GDP       -3.6     -3.0     -2.5
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)      92.3     92.4     90.8
Current account as % of GDP     -2.9     -2.5     -2.2

Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.

Table B10. Italy Percentage change

                               2009    2010    2011    2012

GDP                            -5.5     1.8     0.5    -2.3
Consumption                    -1.6     1.2     0.2    -3.4
Investment : housing           -8.4    -2.1    -2.3    -7.2
           : business         -15.3     5.1    -0.6   -10.5
Government : consumption        0.8    -0.6    -0.9    -1.0
           : investment        -3.3    -5.9    -5.1   -14.0
Stockbuilding (a)              -1.3     1.3    -0.6    -1.1
Total domestic demand          -4.4     2.2    -0.8    -5.1
Export volumes                -17.7    11.4     6.3     1.6
Import volumes                -13.6    12.4     1.0    -7.8
Average earnings                1.7     1.8     1.2     1.1
Harmonised consumer prices      0.8     1.6     2.9     3.1
RPDI                           -3.0    -0.8    -0.5    -3.8
Unemployment, %                 7.8     8.4     8.4    10.6
Govt. balance as % of GDP      -5.4    -4.6    -3.9    -2.7
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)    116.0   118.7   120.0   126.8
Current account as % of GDP    -2.0    -3.5    -3.3    -2.1

                                              Average
                               2013    2014   2015-19

GDP                            -0.7     0.7     1.7
Consumption                    -1.7    -0.1     0.6
Investment : housing           -4.6    -1.0     3.5
           : business          -0.4     4.9     6.1
Government : consumption       -1.0    -0.3     0.7
           : investment        -4.6    14.4     3.9
Stockbuilding (a)               0.0     0.0     0.0
Total domestic demand          -1.8     0.6     1.5
Export volumes                  3.7     3.7     3.8
Import volumes                 -0.1     3.9     3.5
Average earnings               -0.4    -0.4     2.0
Harmonised consumer prices      1.3     2.0     2.3
RPDI                           -1.7    -0.2     1.1
Unemployment, %                11.4    10.7     9.9
Govt. balance as % of GDP      -1.7    -1.0    -1.1
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)    126.2   122.9   111.1
Current account as % of GDP    -1.0    -0.9     0.3

Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP.
(b) End-of-year basis; Maastricht definition.

Table B11. Spain Percentage change

                               2009    2010      2011    2012

GDP                            -3.7    -0.3       0.4    -1.8
Consumption                    -3.8     0.7      -1.0    -1.5
Investment : housing          -23.1   -10.1      -6.7    -9.3
           : business         -16.7    -3.7      -5.7   -14.8
Government : consumption        3.7     1.5      -0.5    -6.8
           : investment         0.3     0.0       0.0    -0.2
Stockbuilding (a)               0.0     0.1      -0.1    -0.1
Total domestic demand          -6.3    -0.7      -1.9    -4.5
Export volumes                -10.0    11.3       7.6     1.5
Import volumes                -17.2     9.2      -0.9    -7.2
Average earnings                4.2    -0.1       0.1     0.5
Harmonised consumer prices     -0.2     2.0       3.1     2.3
RPDI                            3.8    -1.0      -3.1    -6.1
Unemployment, %                18.0    20.1      21.7    24.9
Govt. balance as % of GDP     -11.2    -9.4      -8.6    -7.0
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)     53.9    61.2      68.5    83.0
Current account as % of GDP    -4.8    -4.5      -3.6    -1.9

                                              Average
                               2013    2014   2015-19

GDP                            -1.3     1.2       2.1
Consumption                    -0.8    -0.9       0.5
Investment : housing           -9.5     3.7       5.9
           : business          -4.1     7.9       9.4
Government : consumption       -7.6     0.1       2.9
           : investment        -1.2    -0.9       2.6
Stockbuilding (a)              -0.1     0.0       0.0
Total domestic demand          -3.3     0.4       2.4
Export volumes                  4.5     7.0       3.5
Import volumes                 -2.0     5.0       4.5
Average earnings                0.1    -0.3       1.9
Harmonised consumer prices      2.0     2.3       2.3
RPDI                           -2.8    -1.0       1.8
Unemployment, %                26.7    25.6      19.9
Govt. balance as % of GDP      -5.7    -4.6      -2.3
Govt. debt as % of GDP (b)     88.8    90.7      87.4
Current account as % of GDP    -1.0    -0.9      -1.4

Note: (a) Change as a percentage of GDP. (b) End-of-year
basis; Maastricht definition.


ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

We would like to thank E. Philip Davis, Simon Kirby and Jonathan Portes for helpful comments.

This forecast was completed on 25 October, 2012.

Exchange rate, interest rates and equity price assumptions are based on information available to 10 October 2012. Unless otherwise specified, the source of all data reported in tables and figures is the NiGEM database and NIESR forecast baseline.

REFERENCES

Armstrong, A. (2012a), 'The government's response to the Independent Commission on Banking', National Institute Economic Review, 219, F64-9.

--(2012b), 'Restoring trust in banking', National Institute Economic Review, 221, F4-10.

Blanchard, O. (2011), 'Blanchard on 2011's four hard truths', www. voxeu.org.

BaFin (Federal Financial Supervisory Authority) (2012), 'German banks successfully complete EU-wide recapitalisation exercise', Press release.

Diamond, D. and Dybvig, P. (1983), 'Bank runs, deposit insurance and liquidity', Journal of Political Economy, 91 (3).

EBA (2012), Final Report on the implementation of Capital Plans following the EBA's 2011 Recommendation on the creation of temporary capital buffers to restore market confidence.

HM Treasury (2009), Risk Reward and Perfomance, HMSO.

Holland, D. and Portes, J. (2012), 'Self-defeating austerity', National Institute Economic Review, 222, October, F4-10.

International Monetary Fund, (2012a), World Economic Outlook, IMF.

--(2012b), Global Financiai Stability Report, IMF.

Liikanen Report, The (2012), High Level Export Group on Reforming the Structure of the EU Banking Sector.

Obstfeld, M. (2012), 'Does the current account still matter?', American Economic Review, 102(3).

Schinasi, G.J. and Todd Smith, R. (2000), 'Portfolio diversification, leverage, and financial contagion', IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 47.

Shin, H. (2011), 'Global banking glut and loan risk premium', Mundell-Fleming Lecture, presented at the IMF Annual Research Conference.

Solow, R. (2011), 'IMF talk', presented at Macro anal Growth Policies in the Wake of the Crisis, IMF Conference.

Stiglitz, J.E. and Greenwald, B. (2003), Towards a New Paradigm in Monetary Economics, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

NOTES

(1) Blanchard (2011).

(2) This is very similar to the flow of losses from finance companies (non-banks) to the banks in Asia to the balance sheets of international banks. VAR models required banks to reduce their exposure to the next largest emerging market creditor which was Brazil.

(3) For example, a credit loss on an asset in simple bank VAR model triggers an income and substitution effect away from similar assets. See Schinasi and Todd (2000).

(4) This has been the case for banks in emerging market countries and advanced economies such as Continental Illinois Bank. In the immediate aftermath of Northern Rock commentators all stressed that the bank's assets were sound only to later discover a portfolio of very high loan to value mortgages.

(5) Solow (2011).

(6) Why the multiplier is likely to be larger during this exceptional period was explained by Prof. Robert Solow at an IMF conference at the start of last year.

(7) See Stiglitz and Greenwald (2003) part II.

(8) IMF(2012b),p27.

(9) Some of these policies, such as what are know as the Bush Tax cuts, have been in place since 2001, and so to describe them as temporary may be misleading.

(10) As of the first quarter of 2012.

(11) World Economic Outlook, October 2012, IMF.
Table 1. Forecast summary Percentage change

                                  Real GDP (a)

             World   OECD    China   EU-27   Euro     USA    Japan
                                     Area

2009          -0.6    -3.6     9.0    -4.3    -4.3    -3.1    -5.5
2010           5.3     3.0    10.4     2.0     1.9     2.4     4.6
2011           3.9     1.8     9.3     1.6     1.5     1.8    -0.7
2012           3.1     1.3     7.6    -0.2    -0.5     2.0     2.2
2013           3.4     1.4     7.6     0.6     0.2     2.0     0.9
2014           3.9     2.1     7.5     1.5     1.2     2.4     1.4
2003-2008      4.4     2.3    11.0     2.1     1.9     2.2     1.4
2015-2019      4.1     2.4     7.1     1.9     1.6     2.8     1.4

                            Real GDP (a)                   World
                                                         trade (b)
             Germany   France   Italy    UK    Canada

2009            -5.1     -3.1    -5.5   -4.0      -2.8     -10.4
2010             4.0      1.6     1.8    1.8       3.2      12.5
2011             3.1      1.7     0.5    0.9       2.4       5.7
2012             0.7      0.2    -2.3   -0.1       2.1       3.7
2013             1.1      0.2    -0.7    1.1       1.7       4.9
2014             1.5      1.1     0.7    1.7       2.0       6.0
2003-2008        1.5      1.6     0.9    2.5       2.3       7.7
2015-2019        1.2      1.6     1.7    2.3       2.3       5.5

              Private consumption deflator Interest rates (c) Oil

                    Euro
             OECD   Area   USA    Japan   Germany   France   Italy

2009          0.2   -0.5    0.1    -2.4       0.0     -0.7    -0.1
2010          1.7    1.7    1.9    -1.7       2.0      1.1     1.5
2011          2.3    2.5    2.4    -1.1       2.0      2.1     2.7
2012          1.8    2.2    1.6    -0.7       1.8      2.1     2.7
2013          1.7    2.1    1.8    -1.1       2.1      2.2     2.0
2014          1.9    2.1    1.9     0.3       1.9      2.1     2.0
2003-2008     2.2    2.2    2.7    -0.5       1.4      2.1     2.6
2015-2019     2.1    2.0    2.4     0.6       1.3      1.7     2.3

                 Private consumption deflator
                   Interest rates (c) Oil
                                                   ($ ner
                                            Euro   barrel)
              UK    Canada   USA    Japan   Area     (d)

2009         1.4     0.5     0.3     0.1    1.3       61.8
2010         3.7     1.3     0.3     0.1    1.0       78.8
2011         4.7     2.0     0.3     0.1    1.2      108.5
2012         2.6     1.4     0.3     0.1    0.9      110.7
2013         1.8     1.3     0.3     0.1    0.8      105.7
2014         1.6     1.8     0.6     0.1    0.8      107.5
2003-2008    2.5     1.6     3.0     0.3    2.8       57.5
2015-2019    1.8     2.3     1.7     0.4    1.8      119.1

Notes: Forecast produced using the NiGEM model. (a) GDP growth at
market prices. Regional aggregates are based on PPP shares. (b) Trade
in goods  and services. (c) Central bank intervention rate, period
average. (d) Average of Dubai and Brent spot prices.

Table 2. The largest banks in Europe

Bank                    Country          Total       Total      Total
                                        assets      assets/    assets/
                                                    national   EU GDP
                                      (bn [euro])   GDP (%)      (%)

Deutsche Bank           Germany              2164       84.8      17.4
HSBC                    UK                   1967      119.8      15.8
BNP Paribas             France               1965       99.8      15.8
Credit Agricole Group   France               1879       95.4      15.1
Barclays                UK                   1871      113.9      15.0
RBS                     UK                   1803      109.8      14.5
Santander               Spain                1251      118.2      10.1
Societe Generale        France               1181       60.0       9.5
Lloyds Banking Group    UK                   1161       70.7       9.3
Groupe BPCE             France               1138       57.8       9.1
ING                     Netherlands           961      161.5       7.7
Unicredit               Italy                 926       59.4       7.4
Rabobank Group          Netherlands           731      122.9       5.9
Nordea                  Sweden                716      197.4       5.8
Commerzbank             Germany               661       25.9       5.3
Intesa                  Italy                 639       41.0       5.1
BBVA                    Spain                 597       56.5       4.8
Standard Chartered      UK                    461       28.1       3.7
Danske Bank             Denmark               460      193.7       3.7

Source: Liikanen Report, 2012

Table 3. Recapitalisation exercise results

Bank                          Core Tier I Ratio   Core Tier I Ratio
                                 30.09.2011          30.06.2012

Bayerische Landesbank               10.0                10.3
Commerzbank AG                       8.8                12.2
DekaBank Deutsche
Girozentrale                         9.6                11.7
Deutsche Bank AG                     8.3                10.2
DZ Bank AG                           9.2                11.6
HSH Nordbank AG                      9.6                10.0
Hypo Real Estate Holding AG         27.9                21.6
Landesbank
Baden-Wurttemberg                    9.1                 9.9
Landesbank Berlin AG                13.8                12.7
Landesbank Hessen-Thuringen          6.3                 9.8
Norddeutsche Landesbank              6.0                 9.5
WGZ Bank AG                         10.2                10.4

Source: BaFin, 2012.

Table 4. Total assets of domestic credit institutions vs
foreign subsidiaries in Western and Central and Eastern
Europe

                         Total assets   % domestic   % foreign
                         (bn [euro])

Western Europe
Austria                          1166      74.9        25.1
Belgium                          1147      48.5        51.5
Germany                          7996      94.8         5.2
Denmark                           920      87.7        12.3
Spain                            3915      92.1         7.9
Finland                           634      22.1        77.9
France                           6674      96.7         3.3
Greece                            425      80.8        19.2
Ireland                          1193      32.0        68.0
Italy                            2794      91.5         8.5
Netherlands                      2832      88.8        11.2
Portugal                          513      77.8        22.2
Sweden                           1618      99.6         0.4
UK                              11143      69.0        31.0

Central Eastern Europe
Bulgaria                           39      23.5        76.5
Czech Republic                    168       5.1        94.9
Estonia                            20       5.7        94.3
Hungary                           110      39.1        60.9
Lithuania                          24       9.9        90.1
Latvia                             26      37.7        62.3
Poland                            297      36.2        63.8
Romania                            84      16.7        83.3
Slovenia                           53      72.6        27.4
Slovakia                           55      11.0        89.0
Total EU                        44818      80.1        19.9

Source: The Liikanen Report, 2012.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有