首页    期刊浏览 2024年09月21日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Economic performance under labour.
  • 作者:Liadze, Iana ; Weale, Martin
  • 期刊名称:National Institute Economic Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0027-9501
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:April
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:National Institute of Economic and Social Research
  • 摘要:Keywords: Economic growth; national income; labour market; sustainability; recession JEL Classifications: E20; E32
  • 关键词:Economic growth;Labor market

Economic performance under labour.


Liadze, Iana ; Weale, Martin


This article compares the performance of the UK economy since 1997 with that between 1979 and 1997 and with the performance of the other G7 economies in both periods. It concludes that Britain has done relatively well in terms of productivity growth, economic growth and national income per head but not very well in terms of labour market performance. Savings rates were too low to deliver sustainable economic growth over the period 1979-97 and there has been very little improvement since then. The performance of the economy during the recession and its immediate aftermath has been disappointing relative to the other G7 economies.

Keywords: Economic growth; national income; labour market; sustainability; recession JEL Classifications: E20; E32

Introduction

A General Election is an obvious time to assess a government's economic record and in this commentary we present a summary of the performance of key aspects of the British economy since Labour came to power in 1997. We make comparisons both with Britain's performance under the earlier Conservative Government from 1979-97 and also with that of other countries. This survey provides the background for four articles describing aspects of that performance in more detail. Alan Budd provides an account of fiscal policy, identifying the factors which lay behind the deficit which has opened up in the past two years. Timothy Besley and Kevin Sheedy look at monetary policy. Paul Gregg and Jonathan Wadsworth look at the performance of labour market policy in the recent recession and Lorna Unwin at training policy. Thus these four articles provide an account of key aspects of both demand management and of supply-side policy.

Any assessment is overshadowed by the recession. The monthly profile of GDP points to a picture slightly worse than that of the early 1980s, although the calendar year of 2009 showed the largest contraction since 1921 and indeed the worst GDP performance of any year since 1870 with the exception of the three years after the end of the First World War. Nevertheless, the recession was an international phenomenon and, despite being more severe than that of the 1980s, the interval since the previous recession was longer. Although we obviously address the recession and its consequences, we aim to provide a perspective broader than that which would be obtained by looking at the recession alone.

The policy framework and Labour's performance

A key feature of the Labour Government and one of which it was proud for most of its tenure was the system of macroeconomic management. Labour formalised the arrangement which had gradually developed since Britain had left the ERM in 1992 that the interest rate should be set to deliver an inflation target and devolved the responsibility to the monetary policy of the Bank of England (Besley and Sheedy, 2010). Fiscal policy was given the twin goals of keeping the government current account in balance or in surplus over the economic cycle and keeping government net debt at no more than 40 per cent of GDP (Budd, 2010). These policies were set out in the belief, which proved to be quite mistaken, that they would make the economy more stable than it had been in the past.

The flaws to the policy are, by now, all too apparent. Since in purely arithmetic terms, the Government assumed, despite a past history of forecasting errors, that there was no possibility of a recession, it set its budget on the assumption that there was no risk of large recession-related deficits, (1) This meant that, when the true nature of the business cycle emerged, it was impossible to deliver the target of balancing the government current account over the cycle, with the consequence that the national debt is set to rise sharply. There is now some doubt whether it is politically possible to reduce the national debt sharply enough in time for the next recession or whether a permanently higher level of debt means that the economic cost of the recent recession and crisis is to be spread across all future generations.

A second failure has been that, although inflation has been kept close to target, and in that sense monetary policy has been a success, the fiscal/monetary combination has allowed imbalances to build up in the private sector which at the very least have left households in a position which makes it difficult for them to manage the effects of the recession and which may have the effect of slowing the recovery as they seek to reduce their indebtedness.

The generic flaw of the policy was the underlying pre-Keynesian assumption that the Government did not need to concern itself with developments elsewhere in the economy. It maintained this position despite evidence that overall saving levels were very low and household debt was rising in a way which was unsustainable. Had the Government shown any interest in any of (i) private debt levels, (ii) private sector saving or (iii) overall national saving, the recession would not have been avoided but the private sector would have been in a better position to cope with it; it is possible that it would have been less acute and the prospects for recovery would be better.

A further and related failing of at least as much importance was that the Government did not recognise any macroeconomic role for financial regulation. This meant that when interest rates were set, while the Monetary Policy Committee might have felt unhappy about developments in credit and asset markets, neither it nor anyone else had any means of addressing these except as they were thought to affect the risk of inflation. As we now know, this meant that instability built tip in the banking system with consequences which we now recognise. This shortcoming has been generally recognised ex post. However the regulatory framework needed is still to be developed and the role of macro prudential regulation is under discussion (Bank of England, 2009).

It is often snggested that the economy needs to move to a structure which is export-led rather than consumption-led and that saving matters. It is also understood that an additional policy instrument, over and above fiscal and monetary policy, is needed. At present the preferred approach seems to be one of regulating financial institutions. This, while important in its own right, rather loses sight of the possibility that the problems arising from low saving and high debt may be a consequence of poor decision-making by households and non-financial businesses or a rational response to fiscal and legal incentives to borrow (such as tax relief on debt interest and the incentives created by limited liability). Insofar as one is concerned about debt because of the burden it imposes on future generations, it is important to remember that government debt is only one mechanism for transferring resources from the future to the present and that policy-makers concerned about this issue also need to look at the transfers associated with (i) the system of state transfers and benefits and (ii) the effects of movements of land prices (Barren and Weale, 2010).

Monetary and fiscal policy were only two arms of the policy framework. The third was supply-side policy. This in turn has two key aims. The first is to promote a high level of labour supply, in terms of both numbers of people working and hours worked, and the second is to ensure that when people are working, their labour is as productive as possible. Thus an exploration of Labour's record has to examine these issues as well.

A basis for comparison

We focus our assessment on the major macroeconomic indicators--growth rates of GDP and national income, the performance of labour productivity, labour market indicators, inflation, unemployment and the sustainability indicators of saving and the fiscal position.

Any comparison of the economic performance of two different countries, or of the same country in two different periods, can be distorted by the fact that many of the economic indicators of interest follow the economic cycle. A comparison of one country or time period enjoying a boom with another experiencing a recession will inevitably flatter the former; the explanation of the better performance of the first is simply the cyclical nature of the economy.

An international assessment of the United Kingdom's performance obviously also depends on the countries with which it is compared. We have made our comparison with the other countries of the G7, with the data for Germany relating to West Germany before unification.

Dealing with cycles poses obvious problems with the sort of comparisons that we want to carry out, and no resolution of them is completely satisfactory. HM Treasury has identified a cyclical peak in 1997 (although Besley and Sheedy--2010, figures 2 and 9--suggest it lay between two peaks). The period of the Conservative Government, from 1979 to 1997, then covers two complete economic cycles with a separate cyclical peak in 1990. The recent recession started in early 2008, but on annual data output was slightly higher in 2008 than in 2007 and it is reasonable to put the recent peak in 2007, with 2008 being, by any measure except annual GDP growth, a recessionary year.

Our main aim is to present the records of the two Governments, and we therefore focus on the period 1979-97 and 1997 or 1998 to 2009, depending on the variable in question. However, where relevant, we also h)ok at 1997 or 1998 to 2007 so as to give some indication of the performance of the economy over a complete, if weak, economic cycle. Of course these comparisons are still subject to the problem that, while 1997 was a weak cyclical peak in the UK, it was not so in all the other countries of the G7.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

GDP and national income

Figure 1 summarises the growth rate of the UK economy since the Conservatives came to power in 1979. As table 1 sbows, the growth rate improved sharply from 2.2 per cent per annum to 2.9 per cent per annum during the 1997-2007 cycle as compared to growth tinder the Conservatives. However, if we look at the picture tip to 2009 the record is, not surprisingly, worse, with average growth of 2.0 per cent. Of equal interest is the fact that, despite the performance of the economy during the recession, the UK improved its ranking among the G7 countries slightly under Labour as compared to that under the previous Government.

However, GDP growth on its own does not deliver improvements to welfare. GDP per capita is much more important since this reflects the implications of population change. We see from this, in table 2, that adjustment for population growth improves the United Kingdom's relative position, putting it top of the G7 for the period 1997-2007 and second for the longer period 1997-2009.

Growth in GDP offers a robust measure of the expansion of the economy. Nevertheless comparisons of GDP between countries can be misleading. GDP is gross of depreciation, which merely makes tip for resources used up in the production process. And it does not take any account of net property income from abroad. Net national income is computed after these adjustments. When computed at current prices and compared between countries at current purchasing power parities it offers a better snapshot view than does GDP compared on the same basis, but with the drawback that it does not allow a helpful interpretation of growth rates.

We therefore show, in table 3, per capita net national income of the G7 countries measured relative to the United States. This indicator of the position, at points in time rather than the growth rate over intervals, shows the effects of the country's good growth performance with a rise up the scale under both Conservatives and Labour. The gap relative to the United States remains, nevertheless, substantial.

Productivity

The broad measures discussed above serve to indicate the performance of the economy from the perspective of residents, but they do not indicate effectively its performance as a productive unit. The latter depends on the proportion of residents of working age, the proportion of those of working age who do actually work (and also the proportion of those older than the conventional retirement age who work), the average number of hours of work by people who work and the productivity of the economy--the amount of output generated per hour worked. The age structure of the population is obviously exogenous to an analysis of economic performance, but the other variables are all relevant to an analysis of performance. We discuss in the section on labour market performance the movement in employment and hours worked and focus here on output per hour worked or labour productivity.

This, shown in table 4, grew at 1.7 per cent per annum between 1997 and 2009. Over the period 1979 to 1997 on a comparable basis productivity per person hour grew at 2.2 per cent per annum. However, from 1997 to 2007 the growth rate of labour productivity was the same as it had been under the Conservative Government. Since, internationally, there was a general deterioration of productivity growth, this resulted in the UK being the top performer during the period 1997-2007. Looking at the period 1997-2009, performance was worse only than the United States.

The drivers of labour productivity are growth in the capital stock per person employed and a residual, known as growth of total factor (capital deepening) productivity. The evidence is that the UK's performance is explained by both capital deepening and faster growth in total factor productivity. This is shown in table 5.

An important factor behind Britain's above average performance in total factor productivity growth has probably been the continuing expansion of tertiary education. The proportion of 25-64 year olds with tertiary education has risen from 23 per cent in 1997 to 32 per cent by 2007. This improvement was faster than in the other European G7 countries and the United States, but slower than in Canada and Japan. Of course it reflects not only the policies that the Labour Government has followed m encourage participation in tertiary education but also those of its Conservative predecessor. It is not possible to regard this as a solely Labour achievement. As Unwin (2010) points out, this good record with tertiary education is not matched at lower educational and skill levels.

As with GDP per capita an alternative measure of performance is delivered by comparing the level of productivity in the United Kingdom with that of the other G7 countries. This is done in table 6. These data are computed at 2005 purchasing power parities. The good record in productivity growth results in an improved ranking of the UK's relative level of productivity but, as the table shows, the level of productivity remains substantially lower than that of France and Germany as well as that of the United States.

Inflation

While economists have only limited explanations of how inflation affects people's welfare, there is no doubt that low inflation is regarded as an important policy target. Indeed the Government has made a great deal of the success that it claims has flowed from making the Bank of England independent a few days after coming to power in 1997. Inflation is very obviously lower than it was under the Conservative Government; the average rate from 1979 to 1997 was 5.8 per cent per annum measured by the consumer expenditure deflator, while from 1997 to 2009 it has been 2.0 per cent per annum. The reduction in inflation has, of course, been fairly general. A comparison of the G7 country ranking of average inflation for 1979-97 and 1997-2009 is shown in table 7. Although inflation was lower after 1997 than before, the reduction in the inflation rate between the late 1970s and 1997 was extremely substantial. It is an open question whether this was a greater or lesser achievement than delivering low inflation from 1997 onwards.

Labour market performance

Another important feature of the British economy has been its improved unemployment performance. The unemployment rate reached a peak of l1.8 per cent in [984 and, despite the severity of the recent recession, has stayed well below this, reaching 8 per cent in early 2010. Gregg and Wadsworth (2010) discuss, later in this Review, some of the factors behind this good performance. Average unemployment rates in the period since 1997 have been 5.6 per cent, whereas between 1979 and 1997 they were 9.2 per cent. Nevertheless, if we look at an international comparison of unemployment rates in the years 1979, 1997 and 2009, we see no movement in the country's position.

We now turn to broader indicators of supply conditions in the labour market, having noted that aggregate GDP depends, in part, on how many people work and how many hours they put in. In table 9 we show the activity rate. This measures total employment (including self-employment) as a proportion of the population aged 15-64. Since employed people of all ages, including those aged 65 and over, appear in the numerator, this indicator reflects the outcome of policies which extend working lives beyond conventional retirement as well as those which encourage economic activity by people of working age. We note, however, that policies which promote post-compulsory full-time education depress the ratio.

The table shows that the UK's activity rate has improved since 1997, with an important factor behind the improvement being increased labour force participation by people older than 50. It is also noteworthy that this improvement has taken place despite 2009 being a year of deep depression. Nevertheless the improvement is less than in other countries; we note, in particular, that Germany's position reflects the part-time working schemes it has had in place during the recession.

Table 10 shows average annual hours worked per worker. These data show a general downward drift, as people have made use of rising living standards to reduce their work effort. It is also worth pointing out that these data are in some sense a counterpart of those in table 9. Italy shows a low activity rate and high hours per worker because people who do not work in Italy might be working part-time if they lived in say Germany. Perhaps a greater surprise is that the data for the United Kingdom do not provide any evidence of a long hours culture. A possible reason for this is that they average over full-time and part-time working; full-time workers in the United Kingdom could be working long hours with the total nevertheless depressed more here than in some other countries by part-time working. It should also be noted that this finding is not a consequence of the recession; the rankings are little different if one looks at 2007 rather than 2009.

The general conclusion of this picture of the labour market is that, although, seen in terms of activity rates, things have improved since 1997, and in terms of unemployment they are not much worse despite the recession, nevertheless in international terms Britain's performance has not been very impressive and there must surely be scope for a new government to develop measures to raise Britain's labour supply further.

Sustainability

An underlying concern about the British economy is that the balance between consumption and saving is inappropriate. Low saving means that, even if GDP performs adequately, consumption and living standards are likely to disappoint. If saving levels are low, then the capital stock has to be financed by borrowing from abroad, or by foreign businesses investing in Britain. A consequence of this is that an increasing proportion of profits is paid abroad as a return on that foreign investment. As a result the nation's income falls below the national product; the high levels of consumption made possible by low levels of saving are not sustainable, or at least do not grow in a way which is likely to match people's aspirations.

An initial summary indicator of whether the economy has been managed in a sustainable way is provided by the ratio of produced capital to GDP. Produced capital is capital accumulated by saving; it includes produced physical assets, but not land, intangible assets such as computer programmes, stocks and work in progress and also net foreign assets. Seen from this perspective, the position has improved under Labour. In 1997 the ratio of produced capital to annual GDP was 2.5. At the end of 2008, the last year for which data are available, it had risen to 2.7.

However, the increase is entirely attributable to capital gains made on Britain's net foreign asset position as a result of the decline in sterling and the financial crisis. At the end of 2006 Britain's net foreign liabilities amounted to 352bn [pounds sterling]. By the end of 2008, the 2009 Blue Book shows this had been transformed into assets of 92bn [pounds sterling] despite the fact that the country had run a balance of payments deficit throughout the period. The improvement is equal to just over 30 per cent of one year's GDE

It is not easy to produce similar data for other countries, because national capital stock data are not as well developed as national accounts. However, an alternative perspective is offered by national saving. Table 11 shows net national saving (the sum of private sector and government net saving) for the G7 economies, with 2009 data not yet available. Looking at the United Kingdom on this basis, we can see that it and the United States compete for the bottom position.

The UK savings rate was higher tinder Labour than it had been under the Conservatives. However, if the economy maintains a growth rate of 2 1/4 per cent per annum with this savings rate, the ratio of produced wealth to annual GDP will eventually settle at 1.9. Thus, Labour was not running the economy in a way which could sustain the ratio of produced wealth to income that it inherited from the Conservatives.

A low level of saving and a reduced ratio of wealth to GDP might be justified if there were reasons for thinking that initial levels of wealth were too high. However there are two related reasons for doubting that this is the case. First of all there is widespread concern about the adequacy of pension arrangements; since pensions are financed by saving, this suggests that saving is thought to be too low. Secondly, the peak of the baby boom was reached in 1965. One might therefore expect that, if baby boomers were saving properly for their old age, the saving rate would be large enough to be associated with rising rather than falling wealth. Khoman and Weale (2008) present a full analysis which suggests that ahead of the recession in 2005, the country's consumption level was up to 9 per cent higher than is sustainable, depending on how much and when working lives increase. This analysis assumed that people, when old, want living standards which rise in line with those of younger people and that people do not rely on their children to provide financial support.

National saving and produced national wealth are much the most important indicators of sustainability. However, greater public attention focuses on the fiscal position, and we therefore also explore Britain's fiscal performance tinder this Government and its predecessor. The Government's fiscal targets are defined in terms of net government debt (which is nevertheless gross of some financial holdings such as those in banks). However an international comparison can be made only on the basis of gross debt and we therefore present data for gross debt and gross borrowing as a proportion of GDP (tables 12-13).

These data suggest a better than average international performance and certainly provide no rational background for the suggestion that the United Kingdom, which has never defaulted on its domestic debt, (2) might now consider such a move. Only if the 2009-10 current deficit continued unchecked would a situation arise where it could become very difficult for the Government to collect the taxes needed for debt service. On the other hand, given the effects of the recession on the fiscal position, which we discuss subsequently, and the fiscal prospects, no one could suggest either that fiscal policy has been a success or that it has been managed better than in the previous period.

Economic performance in the recession

Normally a discussion of economic performance over a number of years provides a better indication of the underlying position than does a focus on the short term. But, given that the past two years have seen the worst recession since the early 1930s, an assessment of Britain's economic performance has to take into account the country's experience of the recession.

Table 14 shows the profile of the recession itself, indicating the change in output relative to the first quarter of 2008. Canada, France and the United States have performed markedly better than the other G7 countries, and the United Kingdom's relative position has slipped during the early recovery phase.

Two other important indicators also suggest that the United Kingdom has performed relatively poorly during the recession. Table 15 shows that it has the second-largest increase in unemployment of the G7 countries, with only the United States showing a larger increase. Thus, although, as Gregg and Wadsworth (2010) indicate, unemployment has risen less during the current recession than might have been expected from past experience, an international comparison nevertheless points to a relatively poor performance. The figures of course reflect the special measures that the different countries have taken to limit the rise in unemployment during the depression and are not necessarily indicative of the labour market more broadly.

Table 16 shows the deterioration in the budgetary position between 2007 and 2009 with the United Kingdom as the worst performing of the G7 economics. With both unemployment and the budgetary position past experience of recessions would suggest that 2010 may be worse than was 2009, even though output is now generally rising. Moving to the current recession, there is, however, increasing evidence that unemployment has now stopped rising in some countries; this is less likely to be true of the budget deficits.

In the early phase of the recession to Q1 2009, country differences in output change could be explained by the size of the external deficit/surplus and the growth of government consumption (Weale, 2009). In the later phase the pattern seems to have changed, and the UK has performed poorly. While it is too early to be able to give a clear account of the factors which account for this, there are a number of possible influences. First of all the good GDP performance of Canada and the United States is probably explained by different facts. Canada kept its banking system well regulated and did not experience a banking crisis. It was affected only by the spillover from the crisis elsewhere. The United States has been helped for two reasons. First the fiscal stimulus was larger than m the United Kingdom and secondly a policy of credit easing was pursued. Unlike the Bank of England's interventions in money markets, those in the United States included as an important component the purchase of corporate loan stock and other forms of direct lending to businesses. For all its shortcomings, and the problems which can arise with such interventions, this has provided some relief from credit shortages which has been absent in the United Kingdom. Henriot (2010) suggests that France's relatively good performance is attributable to its industrial structure and its large public sector.

New Labour's legacy: the cost of the crisis

The analysis above, which suggests some relative improvement in Britain's economic performance, fails to indicate the magnitude of the problems that the new government will inherit. Our monthly estimates of GDP suggest that the recession which began in March of 2008 ended in September of 2009. Nevertheless, two years after the start of the recession, output is 5.4 per cent below its level of March 2008. Given that the underlying rate of growth of productive potential is probably around 2 1/2 per cent per annum, the cumulated output shortfall is now around 10 per cent. As Haldane (2010) points out, the long-term cost of the crisis depends much more on the permanent output loss than on the short-term movements. If one assumes that the permanent output loss is one quarter of the current shortfall, and that future output is discounted at 5 per cent per annum, then the total loss of output is equal to one year's GDP or a bout 1400bn [pounds sterling].

The magnitude of the shortfall depends, however, on two factors: (i) how far output was above long-run productive potential before the crisis and (ii) how far and how fast the current shortfall will be made good. Estimation of the permanent component of the output loss cannot be made with any degree of precision. The importance of this depends upon the context in which we see it. If we are considering the longer-term prospects for the public finances, then the change in perception of potential output between 2007 and 2009 must be fully taken account of in our plans. However, some of the perception of what was potential output in 2007 may have been mistaken and its loss does not therefore count as a cost of the crisis. We have, in the past, argued that there are three components.

1. The cost of capital is likely to be higher in the future than it was in the period before the crisis, depressing capital accumulation. It is not immediately clear how far the change between the period before and after the crisis is a consequence of the user cost of capital being abnormally low before the crisis rather than abnormally high afterwards. If risk were underpriced before the crisis, output was too high to be sustainable in the long run, even if we did not realise that in making our plans. If risk has been repriced because nobody had assumed such an event as we have seen could ever happen, but they now realise it can, then the user cost will be higher than previously in a different way, and there will be a permanent loss of potential output. We have previously argued that the rise in risk premia we are likely to see between the pre- and post-crisis period might reduce long-run sustainable output by around 3 per cent (see Barrell, 2009), as compared to pre-2007 projections.

2. The relative scale of the crisis in the UK as compared to migrant source countries is likely to reduce net inward migration to the UK. The UK has been a major destination for New Member States migrants in the past five years, mainly because it did not put up barriers whilst some other EU countries did. Although the factors driving migrants to move are hard to assess, they clearly include relative income levels, and many recent source countries, such as Poland, have fared much better in this crisis than the UK and may not suffer a permanent loss of output--indeed they may be seen as relatively less risky places to invest. In addition, more traditional large-scale source countries such as India and Australia have also suffered less than the UK and hence net inward migration is likely to fall. Barrell et al. (2009) suggested that these changes in the population could take up to 1 per cent off potential output (but not output per person) in the long run.

3. The financial services sector had expanded rapidly in the period 2000-2007, from 5.2 per cent to 8.3 per cent of GDP. Value added per person employed in the sector is roughly twice what it is in the rest of the economy and the volume of output of the sector is computed, in large part, by means of business income deflated by wage rates. The aftermath of the crisis is likely to lead to the sector shrinking again and one might suppose that it will shrink towards its relative size in 2000. If wage rates fall in line with shrinking income but employment remains constant, then there will be no impact on the volume of GDP. By contrast, if a shrinking income results in fewer people being employed in the sector and those being released finding jobs elsewhere at the average value added per person in the rest of the economy there will be a fall in reported GDP approximately equal to the shrinkage in the size of the sector. However, it is possible that the people associated with high value added are more able than the rest of the population. Hence if labour is reallocated, and to the extent that the skills and talents are transferable, those who move will continue to be associated with high value added elsewhere. It is difficult to balance these factors, but it might be reasonable to assume that output will be 1 per cent lower permanently if this sector shrinks towards its relative size in 2000.

The OECD (2009) have argued that there is a third influence to be taken into account--that the rise in unemployment and non-employment during the recession is likely to be associated with a semi-permanent rise in long-run unemployment. We are less concerned about this than these authors, because a number of successful programmes have been developed to prevent this happening. Their estimate of the permanent loss of output from the crisis is lower than ours, at about 31/2 per cent, with I per cent of this coming from labour market effects. Indeed one should be cautious about estimates of the cost of the crisis. Cecchetti, Kohler and Upper (2009) suggest that only about one in four systemic crises have permanent significant negative effects, whilst about one m eight might have positive effects. Barrell et al. (2010) also suggest that only one in four crises have a permanent effect. However, it would be surprising if the most recent crisis were not one of these one in four.

Just like any individual, the country can adjust to reduced circumstances. As we argued in the section on sustainability, it in fact needs to do more than that. As part of this adjustment one might expect the public sector to reduce its expenditure on a broad front, an obvious reference point would be a uniform squeeze on public spending.

But the public sector faces a more difficult adjustment process for three reasons. First of all, public sector plans have been made on the assumption that the pre-2007 trajectory would continue. As we noted, the change relative to this is almost certainly larger than the change relative to underlying pre-2007 output. Secondly, the crisis has exposed weaknesses in the tax base. Reliance on revenue from the financial sector and housing transactions has meant that revenues have fallen more than in proportion to GDP. And thirdly politicians have announced that substantial parts of current expenditure will be ring-fenced at a level based on pre-2007 estimates of GDP and the tax base. This means that some combination of large cuts to other areas and tax increases is needed to restore budget balance. The treatment of the health service provides a good example of the folly of this approach. Most studies suggest that spending on health rises more than in proportion to income (e.g. Beth et al., 2010), and this is probably a reasonable estimate of underlying social preferences. It follows that if GDP falls semi-permanently, health spending should be reduced at least in proportion, and not ring-fenced.

Resolution of the fiscal legacy will be one of the major problems to be resolved by the Government elected on 6 May. It is important to realise that achieving Labour's target of halving the deficit by 2013-14 does not mean the problem is solved. The budget needs to be in balance or in surplus so as to ensure (i) that the costs of the current crisis are not spread on to future generations and (ii) future crises and recessions can be managed with ever-rising debt.

Conclusions

Labour came to power claiming it would transform the performance of the British economy. During the course of the Government it claimed that its policies had done this. For example, in the 2006 Budget, Brown (2006) stated:

"The test of our monetary policy is that we are achieving sustained stability and growth, not just for a year or two but for the long term.

And the test of our fiscal policy is that we match a commitment to balance the current budget over the economic cycle with an ability to make the necessary long-term investments."

On the basis of these two tests, Labour's policies have been an obvious failure. If we compare economic growth from 1997 to 2009 with that of the previous Government from 1979 to 1997 Labour comes off badly. However this is a consequence of the fact that 2009 marked the trough of a depression while 1979 was a cyclical peak and 1997, if not a peak was at least a year of stable economic activity.

A more nuanced assessment is achieved by comparing Britain with the other G7 countries. On this basis we can see that, in terms of variables like GDP per capita, net national income per capita and labour productivity, Britain has improved its relative position; the key to note is that this is true despite the trough of the economic cycle falling in 2009. Thus, although Britain has performed relatively badly during the recession, a poor performance since 2007 has not been enough to offset the good performance between 1997 and 2007. However, labour market performance has been disappointing.

The recession is likely to have permanent costs. There is a wide variety of different estimates because there is no precise basis for estimating this; we expect the output loss to be around 5 per cent, with the impact on per capital GDP lower because the aftermath of the crisis is likely to result in less immigration than there had been up to 2007.

It is probably too early to say whether Britain is more affected by the long-term consequences of the recession than are the other advanced economies. Everyone suffered, to some extent, from a belief that a cyclical boom was a permanent improvement. But, given that even including 2009 Labour's record on productivity, growth and income per head is good relative to the other G7 countries, this assessment will change only if Britain suffers more than the other G7 countries from the aftermath of the recession. Being realistic, it is unlikely that this issue could ever be resolved with the required precision.

But it does seem that the degree of illusion suffered in the UK with regard to the public finances was greater than in most other countries. Indeed this is both the one area where, despite a reasonable performance in the period before the recession, the United Kingdom has performed worse than every other major country. Unless, which we do not expect, revenues revive sharply during the recovery, resolution of this problem is one of the biggest economic problems that the country faces. The process of fiscal stabilisation is likely to take up most of the current decade and, once debt levels have been stabilised, the Government elected on 6 May, or its successor, will have to address the problem of reducing debt levels to the point where the country can afford the budgetary costs of the next recession. This is bound to come in the end and the most important lesson for policymakers of the recent crisis is that macroeconomic policy should never be run on the assumption that recessions cannot happen again.

The particular problem to be faced in sorting out the public finances and reviving the economy is that the mechanisms which have supported growth in the past, rising land prices and buoyant public or private consumption, cannot be used if, at the same time, the saving rate is to be raised to a sustainable level. Of course, if the economy is competitive enough, demand can be provided from overseas and the combination of buoyant exports and restrained consumption results in higher saving. But it is quite possible that further depreciation of the exchange rate will be needed to deliver this.

doi: 10.1177/0027950110372731

REFERENCES

Bank of England (2009), 'The role of macro-prudential regulation', http://www.bankofengtand.co.uk/publications/other/ financialstability/roleofmacroprudentialpolicy091121.pdf.

Barrell R. (2009), 'Long-term scarring from the financial crisis', National Institute Economic Review, October, pp. 36-8.

Barrell R., Davis, E.P., Karim, D. and Liadze, I. (2010), 'The effects of the banking crisis on potential output in OECD countries', NIESR mimeo.

Barrell, R., Gottschalk, S., Kirby, S. and Orazgani, A. (2009), 'Projections of migration inflows under alternative scenarios for the World Economy', Department of Communities and Local Government economics paper No. 3.

Barrell, R. and Weale, M.R. (2010), 'Fiscal policy, fairness between generations and national saving', Oxford Review of Economic Policy (forthcoming).

Bech, M., Christiansen, T., Khoman, E., Davidson, J. and Weale, M.R. (2009), 'Ageing and aggregate health care expenditure in Europe', National Institute mimeo.

Besley, T. and Sheedy, K. (2010), 'Monetary policy under Labour', National Institute Economic Review, 212, April, pp. R 15-R33.

Brown, G. (2006), Budget Speech, available at http://www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/bud_budget06 speech.htm.

Budd, A. (2010), 'Fiscal policy under Labour', National Institute Economic Review, 212, April, pp. R34-R48.

Cecchetti, S., Kohler, M. and Upper, C. (2009), 'Financial crises and economic activity', NBER working paper 15379.

Gregg, P. and Wadsworth, J. (2010), 'The UK labour market and the 2008-9 Recession', National Institute Economic Review, 212, April, pp. R61-R72.

Haldane, A. (2010), 'The $100 billion question', Speech at the Institute of Regulation and Risk, Hong Kong, http:// www.ban kofengland.co.uk/publications/speeches/2010/ speech433.pdf.

Henriot, A. (2010), 'France: economic outlook', presented in Kiel, March 2010, available at http://www.coe-rexecode.fr/ public/Rencontres-et-debats/Communications-exterieures/ New-patterns-in-world-trade-modest-upturn-in-France.

Khoman, E. and Weale, M.R. (2008), 'Are we living beyond our means? A comparison of France, Italy, Spain and the United Kingdom', National Institute Discussion Paper No. 311, available at http://www.niesr.ac.uk/pdf/100408_94720.pdf.

Miller, A.C. (1890), 'The conversion of the English debt', Quarterly Journal af Economics, 4. pp. 437-48.

OECD (2009), 'The impact of the economic crisis on potential output', Working Party No. I on Macroeconomic and Structural Policy Analysis ECO/CPE/WPI (2010)3.

Reinhart, C.M. and Rogoff, K.S. (2009), This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Policy, Princeton University Press.

Unwin, L. (2010), 'Learning and working from the MSC to New Labour: young people, skills and employment', National Institute Economic Review, 212, April, pp. R49-R60.

Weale, M.R. (2009), 'International recession and recovery', National Institute Economic Review, 209, pp. 4-7.

NOTES

(1) Even the sharpest critics of the Government's fiscal management, like the National Institute, did not advocate the sort of fiscal surpluses which governments need to run in normal times so as to manage the possible costs of recessions. But there is no reason to believe that, had such suggestions been made, their authors would have been taken seriously by policymakers, politicians or by the media.

(2) Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) suggest that the various debt conversions of the 19th century and the War Loan conversion of 1932 were partial defaults because the interest rate payable on the debt was reduced. In fact they were nothing of the kind. The prospectuses of the securities in question allowed the Government to redeem them at short notice. At the time of these conversions it was in the taxpayers' interest to convert the debt because the coupon on the debt was higher than the market rate. Miller (1890) provides an informed account of Goschen's conversion.

Iana Liadze and Martin Weale *

* We are particularly grateful to Ray Barrell for considerable help, to Simon Kirby for providing figure I and also to other members of the National Institute's Editorial Board for their comments.
Table 1. Growth rates (per cent per annum)

                 Growth Rate               Rank

             1979   1997    1997    1979   1997    1997
             -97    -2007   -2009   -97    -2007   -2009

Canada       2.5     3.3     2.5     3       1       1
France       1.9     2.4     1.8     7       4       4
Germany      2.1     1.6     1.0     5       5       5
Italy        2.0     1.4     0.7     6       6       6
Japan        3.0     1.2     0.5     1       7       7
UK           2.2     2.9     2.0     4       3       3
US           2.9     3.0     2.3     2       2       2

Source: OECD and NIESR.

Table 2. Growth of GDP per capita (per cent per annum)

              Growth Rate               Rank

          1979   1997    1997    1979   1997    1997
          -97    -2007   -2009   -97    -2007   -2009

Canada    1.3     2.3     1.5     7       2       1
France    1.4     1.7     1.2     6       4       4
Germany   1.9     1.6     1.0     4       5       5
Italy     2.0     1.0     0.2     2       7       7
Japan     2.5     1.0     0.4     1       6       6
UK        2.0     2.4     1.5     3       1       2
US        1.8     2.0     1.3     5       3       3

Source: OECD and NIESR.

Table 3. Net national income per capita at current
purchasing power parities (US = 100)

                 US = 100                Rank

           1979    1997    2009   1979   1997   2009

Canada     86.4    75.5    80.8    2      2      2
France     76.4    70.9    69.8    4      6      5
Germany    78.0    73.4    73.2    3      3      4
Italy      71.8    70.7    60.5    5      7      7
Japan      69.8    73.1    65.8    6      4      6
UK         68.3    72.9    76.6    7      5      3
US        100.0   100.0   100.0    1      1      1

Source: OECD and NIESR. 2009 figures are calcualted by adjusting
OECD 2008 figures for the change in real GDP per capita between
2008 and 2009.

Table 4. Labour productivity growth rates (per cent per
annum)

              Growth Rate               Rank

          1979   1997    1997    1979   1997    1997
          -97    -2007   -2009   -97    -2007   -2009

Canada    1.2     1.4     1.0     7       6       6
France    2.2     1.9     1.4     2       3       4
Germany   2.0     1.5     1.1     4       5       5
Italy     1.9     0.3    -0.2     5       7       7
Japan     2.3     1.8     1.5     1       4       3
UK        2.2     2.2     1.7     3       1       2
US        1.6     2.0     2.0     6       2       1

Source: NIESR.

Table 5. Contributions of capital deepening and total factor
productivity growth to labour productivity growth (per  cent per
annum)

           Capital deepening           Rank

          1979-97   1997-2009   1979-97   1997-2009

Canada      0.5        0.6         5          5
France      1.0        0.9         1          1
Germany     0.6        0.7         4          4
Italy       0.8        0.5         2          7
Japan       0.5        0.6         6          6
UK          0.6        0.8         3          3
US          0.4        0.9         7          2

             Total factor              Rank
             productivity
                growth

          1979-97   1997-2009   1979-97   1997-2009

Canada      0.7        0.4         7          5
France      1.2        0.5         4          4
Germany     1.4        0.4         3          6
Italy       1.0       -0.7         6          7
Japan       1.8        0.9         1          2
UK          1.6        0.9         2          3
US          1.2        1.2         5          1

Source: NIESR.

Table 6. Labour productivity (US= 100) at 2005
purchasing power parities

           Output per hour
           worked US = 100            Rank

          1979   1997   2009   1979   1997   2009

Canada    83.5   81.5   73.8    2      5      5
France    76.5   93.1   88.8    5      2      2
Germany   77.9   92.0   81.6    4      3      3
Italy     80.0   89.9   71.1    3      4      6
Japan     48.8   66.6   63.9    7      7      7
UK        66.8   76.9   75.5    6      6      4
US         100    100    100    1      1      1

Source: OECD and NIESR.

Table 7. Inflation rates (per cent per annum)

            Inflation rate            Rank

          979-97   1997-2009   1979-97   1997-2009

Canada     4.6        1.6         4          4
France     4.9        1.4         5          3
Germany    2.8        1.2         2          2
Italy      8.7        2.3         7          7
Japan      1.8       -0.8         1          1
UK         5.8        2.0         6          5
US         4.0        2.1         3          6

Source: NIESR.

Table 8. Unemployment rates (per cent of labour force)

           Unemployment rate           Rank

           1979   1997   2009   1979   1997   2009

Canada      7.5    9.1    8.3    6      4      5
France      5.4   11.0    9.5    4      6      7
Germany     3.2    9.9    7.5    2      5      2
Italy       7.8   11.8    7.7    7      7      4
Japan       2.1    3.4    5.1    1      1      1
UK          4.7    7.1    7.6    3      3      3
US          5.8    4.9    9.3    5      2      6

Source: OECD and national sources.

Table 9. Activity rates (per cent)

          Activity rate (a)           Rank

          1979   1997   2009   1979   1997   2009

Canada    65.8   67.9   72.3    5      4      2
France    64.7   60.8   64.2    6      6      6
Germany   66.2   64.5   71.3    4      5      3
Italy     55.6   52.5   59.0    7      7      7
Japan     70.1   75.3   76.9    2      1      1
UK        70.8   69.5   70.9    1      3      4
Us        67.6   73.0   68.6    3      2      5

Source: OECD and NIESR.

Note: Per cent of population aged 15-64.

Table 10. Average annual hours worked per worker

               Annual hours
            worked per worker          Rank

           1979   1997   2009   1979   1997   2009

Canada     1825   1767   1725    5      4      3
France     1868   1649   1541    2      6      6
Germany    1770   1509   1392    7      7      7
Italy      1859   1863   1798    3      2      1
Japan      2126   1865   1713    1      1      4
UK         1819   1741   1632    6      5      5
US         1828   1846   1767    4      3      2

Source: OECD and NIESR.

Table 11. Net saving rates (per cent of GDP)

           Net national saving          Rank

           1979-97   1998-2008   1979-97   1998-2008

Canada       6.6        9.4         5          1
France       6.9        7.2         4          2
Germany      8.3        7.0         2          3
Italy        7.3        5.0         3          5
Japan       12.4        5.1         1          4
UK           3.4        4.1         7          6
US           5.3        3.6         6          7

Source: ONS and NIESR.

Note: The second figure for Japan covers 1998-2007.

Table 12. Gross public debt (per cent of GDP)

               Gross debt               Rank

          1979    1997    2009   1979   1997   2009

Canada    44.1    96.0    79.9    5      5      4
France    30.1    68.8    83.3    2      4      5
Germany   25.4    58.3    68.8    1      1      1
Italy     84.1   127.8   120.8    7      7      6
Japan     42.4    97.2   188.8    4      6      7
UK        58.2    58.3    73.9    6      2      2
US        39.6    66.5    79.0    3      3      3

Source: NIESR.

Table 13. Gross budget deficit (per cent of GDP)

             Gross budget
               deficit                 Rank

          1979-97   1997-2009   1979-97   1997-2009

Canada      5.8       -0.5         6          1
France      3.0        3.1         3          6
Germany     2.4        2.0         2          2
Italy       8.3        2.9         7          4
Japan       2.2        6.3         1          7
UK          3.5        2.5         4          3
US          3.9        3.1         5          5

Source: NIESR.

Table 14. The profile of the recession in the G7 countries

           Q2-2008   Q3-2008   Q4-2008   Q1-2009

Change in output since Q1-2008 (per cent)

Canada       0.1       0.2      -0.8      -2.5
France      -0.4      -0.7      -2.1      -3.4
Germany     -0.6      -0.9      -3.3      -6.7
Italy       -0.6      -1.5      -3.6      -6.2
Japan       -1.1      -2.4      -5.0      -8.4
UK          -0.1      -1.0      -2.8      -5.3
US           0.4      -0.3      -1.7      -3.3

Ranking

Canada        2         1         1         1
France        4         3         3         3
Germany       5         4         5         6
Italy         6         6         6         5
Japan         7         7         7         7
UK            3         5         4         4
US            1         2         2         2

           Q2-2009   Q3-2009   Q4-2009

Change in output since Q1-2008 (per cent)

Canada      -3.4      -3.2      -2.0
France      -3.2      -3.0      -2.4
Germany     -6.3      -5.6      -5.6
Italy       -6.7      -6.2      -6.5
Japan       -7.0      -7.2      -6.3
UK          -6.0      -6.2      -5.8
US          -3.5      -2.9      -1.6

Ranking

Canada        2         3         2
France        1         2         3
Germany       5         4         4
Italy         6         5         7
Japan         7         7         6
UK            4         6         5
US            3         1         1

Source: OECD.

Table 15. Unemployment in the recession (per cent)

           Jan. 2008   Feb. 2010   Increase   Rank

Canada        5.9         8.2         2.3      4
France        7.7        10.1         2.4      5
Germany       7.8         7.5        -0.3      1
Italy         6.7         8.5         1.8      3
Japan         3.9         4.9         1.0      2
UK            5.1         8.0         2.9      6
Us            5.0         9.7         4.7      7

Source: OECD. UK February 2010 figures estimated.

Note: OECD standardised unemployment.

Table 16. Budget balances in the recession (per cent of
GDP)

           2007    2009   Change   Rank

Canada      1.6    -5.1    -6.7     5
France     -2.7    -7.9    -5.2     3
Germany     0.2    -3.1    -3.3     1
Italy      -1.5    -5.3    -3.8     2
Japan      -2.5    -8.0    -5.5     4
UK         -2.6   -11.2    -8.6     7
US         -2.8   -11.1    -8.3     6

Source: NIESR.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有