The euro: past successes and new challenges.
Buti, Marco ; van den Noord, Paul
The successes of the first decade of European Economic and Monetary
Union are impressive, but it is fair to stress these were achieved in a
relatively benign economic environment characterised by steady global
growth, supportive financial conditions and fiscal windfalls associated
with booms in asset markets. Although all this has come to an abrupt end
with the financial crisis, there is a silver lining of fiscal stimulus
being more effective in EMU than without the single currency, with
offsetting exchange rate responses absent, trade multipliers stronger
and the fiscal framework credible. But the financial crisis also clearly
demonstrated the need for stronger coordination of national policy
actions to internalise crossborder spillovers. Meanwhile, the European
Commission has a major role to play in striking the right balance
between short-term emergency measures and longer-term priorities.
Against this backdrop, this article sheds light on the longer-run
challenges and the policy agenda for meeting them.
Keywords: Monetary union; economic governance; European Union
JEL Classifications: E60; F50; H00
Introduction
We are living in challenging times. The subprime crisis in the
United States developed into a full-blown global financial crisis and
what may well be the worst global downturn since the 1930s. World trade,
stock markets and confidence have fallen at an unprecedented pace.
Banking systems are under extreme stress and calls for capital
injections and guarantees from governments are the order of the day.
Fiscal stimulus, state aid for ailing industries and plummeting tax
revenues hit public finances. It is not easy a task to take a
longer-term view on European and Monetary Union (EMU). Yet this is what
we have been asked to do.
This crisis may be seen as the acid test of EMU, but, if so, in a
rather unexpected way. From the outset sceptics and critics have been
wondering if and how the Euro Area would survive recurrent
'asymmetric shocks' affecting individual countries amid a
'one-size-fits-all' monetary policy and exchange rate. But now
we are in a very different situation: a massive common shock that is
hitting all member countries of the Euro Area simultaneously, albeit
with a differentiated impact dependent on countries' initial
conditions. We are entering uncharted territory.
The Commission's Communication and staff report 'EMU@10,
Successes and Challenges After 10 Years of Economic and Monetary
Union' (European Commission, 2008a) released in May 2008, on which
we will draw extensively in this article, predicted such a shock to be
the archetypical one in the second decade of the Euro Area. The drafters
had obviously no clue that the subprime crisis would develop into
one--and that soon. Yet many of the policy recommendations in the Report
were based on such a predicted change in the 'typology of
shocks' and therefore, in our view, are more relevant than ever.
In section 2 of this article we shall look back to the first ten
years of EMU, or more precisely, the first nine years and three
quarters, which started with the launch of the European single currency
on 1 January 1999 and ended in September 2008 with the default of the
investment bank Lehman Brothers. In section 3 we will look ahead,
starting from the current crisis and then looking beyond the crisis to
consider the longer-term challenges and priorities. Section 4 lays out
the policy agenda for the second decade and section 5 concludes.
2. The first decade in restrospect
On 1 January 1999 the euro became the currency of 300 million
people in eleven EU Member States--Belgium, Germany, Spain, France,
Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Austria, Portugal and
Finland. This move established the second largest currency area in the
world (after the United States), producing roughly one fifth of the
world's GDP. Five other EU Member States have joined the Euro Area
since its inception: Greece in 2001, Slovenia in 2007, Cyprus and Malta
in 2008 and this year Slovakia, the first member of the former Soviet
bloc to adopt the single currency.
2.1 A historic move
The creation of the euro--and the European Central Bank--was a
defining moment in European postwar history. Although the origins of the
single currency go back to the 1970s, the process accelerated in the
early 1990s when the lifting of the Iron Curtain and the ensuing
political uncertainties prompted the perception that stronger common
goal setting in Europe was needed. Among the related political events of
the early 1990s was the reunification of Germany, which had serious
macroeconomic ramifications and contributed to tensions and turbulence
in the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM). This eventually led to
the go-ahead for monetary union in Europe, as laid down in the
Maastricht Treaty signed in 1992.
With EMU a unique stability-oriented policy framework was created.
It comprises a single monetary policy in combination with fiscal
policies conducted at national level --albeit subject to rules and
coordination--by its participating Member States. This is unlike federal
monetary unions, like the United States, where a federal government is
endowed with sovereignty to tax and to provide common public goods.
Aside from the political motivations for the creation of a single
currency for Europe, the euro was intended to serve several economic
goals:
* Macroeconomic stability. As noted, the single currency was a
response to the episode of financial turbulence in the early 1990s. The
use of the exchange rate and monetary policy instruments had lost much
of their efficacy, especially in smaller countries, after the removal of
capital controls.
* Growth and jobs. The single currency was seen as a decisive move
to complement the completion of the European single market in 1992. The
associated reduction in transaction costs and risk premia were expected
to boost intra-area trade and finance, competition and efficiency.
* Cohesion and convergence. It was hoped that by fostering
integration real economic convergence towards the best-performers would
receive a boost. Moreover, as economies would become more similar,
policies would become easier to co-ordinate as the importance of
national desiderata diminished.
2.2 Initial expectations
Before it was created there was a lively academic and political
debate on the viability or desirability of a monetary union for Europe.
There was a very broad spectrum of views on the subject: some predicted
a bumpy start or even collapse, while others were more sanguine (Buti
and Sapir, 1998 and 2002). However, many tended towards a pessimistic
view and this may have adversely affected perceptions of the euro
area's performance in its early years.
But even its fiercest proponents saw the creation and management of
a single currency in Europe as a major challenge for several reasons:
* With the loss of the exchange rate mechanism other channels would
have to take over responsibility for adjustment in case of
country-specific disturbances. However, without a 'federal
budget' it would be impossible to direct fiscal transfers from
booming to slumping states. Moreover, labour mobility within and across
borders was deemed to be low and prices and wages weakly responsive to
the local business cycle. Further, it was feared that real interest
rates might behave pro-cyclically at the country level, going down as
inflation rose in upturns and vice versa (the so-called 'Walters
critique').
* The use of fiscal policies to stabilise the national economies
was seen as possible to some extent, but the experience of previous
decades had given rise to scepticism. Countries would be tempted to
'free ride' in the absence of the disciplining effect of
exchange-rate risk, by running budget deficits. The adverse effects of
fiscal profligacy risked spilling over to other participating countries.
It would also result in an unbalanced policy mix, with monetary policy
tighter to offset aggregate fiscal ease.
These concerns led to the convergence criteria for inflation,
exchange rate stability, interest rates and public deficits and debt
enshrined in the 1992 Maastricht Treaty, and which countries must comply
with to qualify for Euro Area accession. It also led to the adoption of
the Stability and Growth Pact in 1997 which fixed rules for fiscal
policy and penalties if those rules were breached. (1) This led sceptics
to point to a risk of pro-cyclical fiscal policies, as participating
countries would be forced to tighten their budgets in a downturn while
feeling little urge for fiscal restraint in good times.
The concerns over the weak adjustment capacity of the countries
participating in the Euro Area gave impetus to the EU's Lisbon
Strategy, which was adopted in 2000 to steer structural reform in
product, labour and financial markets. While the Strategy was designed
to boost growth and jobs over the longer haul in the whole EU, evidence
has been mounting that structural policies also have favourable knock-on
effects on the economic adjustment capacity of countries. In addition,
the integration and development of financial markets can be seen to
create opportunities for risk sharing and consumption smoothing, thus
easing the stabilisation role of macroeconomic policies.
2.3 A success story overall
Inflation banished
The inflation performance of the Euro Area has improved decisively
in comparison with previous decades. Inflation rates came down
substantially and so did the volatility of price changes (figure 1). The
bulk of the disinflation in the Euro Area occurred in the 1990s as a
result of the efforts to meet the Maastricht inflation criteria. Since
then, on average inflation has been broadly on a par with the ECB's
benchmark of price stability of close to but below 2 per cent. Even
though inflation exceeded this mark during most of 2008 due to increases
in energy and food prices, long-term inflation expectations remained
consistent with the price stability goal, suggesting that this goal is
well anchored and credible.
Admittedly, a long-term decline in inflation has also been observed
in other developed countries. But it is fair to say that without the
institutional changes that accompanied the creation of the single
currency--notably the establishment of an independent central bank with
a clear price stability mandate--this would have been much more
difficult to achieve in the Euro Area. The public perceptions of the
euro in many participating countries are still unfavourable, but this is
probably attributable to radical shifts in relative prices, with, in
particular, prices of frequent expenses (food and energy) having risen
while those of less frequently purchased items steeply fell (see Box).
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Extraordinarily job-rich growth
Another tangible economic achievement in the first ten years of the
Euro Area has been the massive growth in employment--with the creation
of 16 million jobs and the unemployment rate plummeting from 9 per cent
in 1999 to 7 per cent in 2008. This has occurred in spite of growing
numbers of people retiring, as labour market participation has risen
sharply. It would be inappropriate to attribute this achievement solely
to the single currency, and there is indeed evidence that labour market
reforms in the 1990s have facilitated the labour market participation of
'marginal' workers (e.g. with low skills or limited job
histories). We would judge that it is unlikely that job gains would have
been as impressive under the more volatile monetary conditions and
fiscal instability that used to prevail under the previous system.
As a counterpart there has been a significant productivity
slowdown, with growth in output per worker halving from 1 1/2 per cent
in the period 1989-98 to an estimated 3/4 per cent in 1999-2008 (table
1). This is in sharp contrast to the rapid pace of productivity growth
observed in the United States over the same period, which is
attributable to a large extent to a major differential in productivity
growth in the services sector (Havik et al., 2008). It largely explains
why the Euro Area has seen its growth rate stalling at around 2 per cent
per annum, the same as in the preceding decade--despite a much faster
growth in labour utilisation. On a per capita basis, output growth has
matched the US performances, but this means that the Euro Area continued
to lag behind US living standards, with per capita income having settled
at slightly over 70 per cent of the US level.
Obviously it is tempting to assume the recent jobs
'miracle' itself has caused the productivity slowdown. A
trade-off between more jobs and productivity may indeed emerge if faster
employment growth leads to lower capital use per worker and if greater
numbers of low-skilled workers are employed. But this combined effect is
found to be small, indeed tiny in comparison with the impact of the slow
development and diffusion of new technologies and best work practices
(European Commission, 2007a). A number of Euro Area countries are not
yet fully reaping the benefits of the information technology revolution
and the spurt in the global division of labour.
Even so, there is evidence to suggest that without the introduction
of the single currency labour productivity (and per capita income) would
have been weaker in the Euro Area than it has been (Baldwin et al., 2008
and Barrel et al., 2008). The euro has favoured productivity as it has
offered firms greater opportunities to trade, specialise and
invest--owing to economies of scale, stronger competition and lower cost
of capital. Growth performance may not have been brilliant, but without
the euro it would have been worse.
Integrating financial markets
The creation of the single currency has contributed to the
financial integration of Europe which has had many favourable effects on
the functioning of the Euro Area economy. Financial capital is easily
transferred from countries with an external surplus to those with a
deficit and there are more opportunities for international risk sharing.
The associated lower cost of capital, as noted, has contributed to
productivity and growth. It is obvious though that financial regulation
and supervision must keep pace with these developments, which it has not
done.
The most immediate impact of EMU on financial integration was felt
on the Euro Area markets for unsecured money and derivatives. Almost as
soon as EMU was launched, interest rates on inter-bank deposits and
derivative contracts across the Euro Area converged fully on the
benchmark Euribor and Eonia rates. EMU also had a very substantial
impact on the integration of the market for government bonds, which are
important not only as a source of government financing but also in
providing reference pricing for other financial instruments. Well ahead
of the launch of EMU, there was a process of sustained convergence in
yields on bonds issued by the Euro Area Member States (figure 2).
Although yield spreads have widened since the onset of the financial
crisis, this must be seen as reflecting exceptional circumstances.
Moreover, they are still considerably smaller than the huge spreads that
were common prior to the creation of the single currency. And in some
ways the persistent widening of yield spreads is a good sign: it shows
that financial markets price fiscal sustainability risk even in a
monetary union.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
There is evidence that the elimination of currency risk has spurred
corporate bond issuance while the integration of stock markets has
proceeded faster in the Euro Area than at the global level. Home bias in
stock markets has diminished and cross-border holdings of long-term debt
securities increased. Integration of financial market infrastructure has
also advanced. Progress has been made in cross-border wholesale
financial services, while the Single Euro Payments Area (SEPA) is set to
eliminate differences between national and cross-border retail payments.
However, financial integration remains work in progress. In
particular, cross-border provision of retail financial services is
lagging and regulatory and supervisory costs for financial
intermediaries operating in a multi-jurisdictional environment remain
high. And, more urgently, the cross-border cooperation in arrangements
for crisis prevention, management and resolution need to be stepped up.
The recently released de Larosiere report (de Larosiere Group, 2009) is
a welcome first step.
A balanced macroeconomic policy mix
The adoption of the single currency implied a radical change in the
macroeconomic policy framework. Monetary policy was centralised while
fiscal policy remained in the remit of the participating countries,
subject to rules, surveillance and co-ordination at the EU level. The
rules required the member states to create sufficient fiscal space to
let the automatic fiscal stabilisers work--which are deemed powerful in
the Euro Area owing to extensive public social safety nets and
progressive taxes--without breaching the 3 per cent of GDP reference
value for the fiscal deficit. The Stability and Growth Pact, which aims
at making fiscal discipline a permanent feature of EMU, encountered
difficulties with its enforcement and was eventually reformed in 2005.
The reform of the Pact, which emphasised structural adjustment and
sustainability, helped to strengthen its political ownership and
contributed to sizeable deficit reductions in the subsequent years.
As noted above, monetary policy in the Euro Area is fully credible,
with inflation expectations firmly anchored in the ECB's price
stability goal. And notwithstanding occasional difficulties in enforcing
the fiscal rules, budget deficits have declined significantly, averaging
0.6 per cent of GDP in 2007 (figure 3). Without these achievements,
joint monetary and fiscal stimulus to cushion a major economic downturn,
as presently engineered, would have been completely out of reach or
counterproductive.
A concern at the outset was that fiscal policies in the Euro Area
tend to be pro-cyclical, which adds to overheating in the upturn,
complicates fiscal management in the subsequent downturn and jeopardises
fiscal sustainability in the long run. While pro-cyclical behaviour
appears to have become less prominent with the adoption of the euro
(Turrini, 2008 and Von Hagen and Wyplosz, 2008), it has not been
entirely eradicated. Two episodes stand out in this regard. First,
fiscal policies were eased while the dotcom bubble was inflating in
1999-2000, based on (wrong) beliefs that the economy would slide in
recession in the wake of bursting of the bubble. In 2006-7, policymakers
failed to appreciate the extent of the financial and housing bubbles and
wrongly perceived the associated tax windfalls as
'structural'. While on conventional measures such windfalls
may be recorded as fiscal tightening, it de facto is not. (2) These
windfalls are now rapidly evaporating, with large deficits opening up in
Spain and Ireland where housing busts are particularly severe (figure
4).
The early debates also highlighted the risk of unbalanced policy
mixes, with fiscal policies working against, rather than supporting,
monetary policy. Euro sceptics have pointed out that in monetary union
the fiscal authorities will be inclined to run higher deficits, knowing
that they can 'share the bill' with the other members via an
increase in the area-wide interest and exchange rate. However, these
fears have proved to be unfounded. As shown in figure 5, fiscal and
monetary policies have consistently moved in the same direction--i.e.
supporting each other aside from short spells of procyclical fiscal
policies in the aforementioned periods 1999-2000 and, though not
captured by the conventional data, 2007-8. Perhaps even more
importantly, the rapid deterioration in public finances in some
countries recently has been reflected in widening yield spreads rather
than in a rise in the benchmark bond yield.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
It is evident from a comparison of figures 5 and 6 that in the
United States fiscal and monetary policies respond much more strongly to
the cycle than in the Euro Area. It should be recalled though that the
United States has much weaker automatic fiscal stabilisers (smaller
government, less elaborate social safety nets) than the Euro Area.
Moreover, the United States has been the epicentre of economic shocks
that have shaped recent cycles, so it is not surprising that policy
activism is most prominent there. Moreover, this greater policy
activism, notably the pronounced swings in the stance of monetary
policy, may well have fuelled recent boom-bust cycles in the United
States, if not their contagion to the rest of the global economy.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Converging or diverging?
From the outset it was clear that the business cycles of the
participant countries must be more or less in sync for the favourable
effects of monetary union to materialise. Otherwise, the
one-size-fits-all monetary policy would be too loose for buoyant
economies and too tight for the others. There is evidence that business
cycles have indeed become more synchronised between participating
countries since the mid-1990s--possibly driven by the establishment of
the Single Market in 1992 and the joint policy efforts in the run-up to
the euro (Gayer, 2007).
Even so, while high frequency fluctuations have become more
synchronised, there have been persistent differences in economic
performance between countries in a medium-term time frame. Specifically,
two of the three largest countries in the Euro Area (Germany and Italy)
have experienced considerably weaker growth than the average (figure 7).
Germany has been grappling with the consequences of unification in 1991,
which led to large losses in competitiveness and excessive construction
activity. Painful corrections on both fronts have persistently depressed
domestic demand. Italy's sluggish performance has been due to
continued losses in competitiveness associated with weak productivity
growth (figure 8) and an industrial structure that is particularly prone
to competition from emerging economies.
By contrast, most other Euro Area countries--notably those in the
area's 'periphery'--have seen comparatively robust
growth. Many of them have seized the opportunities stemming from
globalisation, reformed their economies and have seen sharp declines in
real interest rates thanks to the euro. Moreover, some of them had not
yet fully completed their catching-up towards EU average living
standards. Three of the four 'cohesion countries' (Spain,
Ireland and Greece) have shown a strong catch-up performance, while the
fourth (Portugal) has disappointed because of growth-unfriendly fiscal
management.
The counterpart of this has been, however, growing imbalances
within the Euro Area. Divergences in productivity growth and unit labour
cost developments have proved persistent, involving major shifts in
intra-Euro Area real effective exchange rates, which in some cases must
have gone beyond their longer-term equilibrium values (figures 8 and 9).
Moreover, several of the strong performers have been thriving on
construction booms, spurred by immigration and capital inflows
facilitated by the single currency and the integration of financial
markets. This squeezed exporting industries, cut into competitiveness
and led to persistent current account deficits (figure 10). In
particular, Spain and Ireland are now facing painful adjustments, with
house prices and construction activity rapidly declining (figures 11 and
12). While the financial crisis has accelerated these corrections, they
were already underway.
What happened to TINA?
From the debate of the 1990s two opposing views emerged regarding
the impact of the euro on participating countries' efforts to
reform their economies. According to the Alternative (TINA) hypothesis
(Bean, 1998), the single currency would spur governments to undertake
structural reform, as this was seen as the only way to strengthen
market-based adjustment so as to offset the loss of the exchange rate
instrument. Others, however, argued that the disappearance of the
exchange rate adjustment would rather lead to more protectionism and
hence weaken the incentives for structural reform (Calmfors, 2001).
The evidence so far is not very conclusive, although on balance the
single currency seems to have had little positive effect on structural
reform (Duval, 2005 and Duval and Elmeskov, 2006). Analysis reported in
European Commission (2008a) indicates that Euro Area countries have on
average been slower to implement the structural policy recommendations
under the Broad Economic Policy Guidelines (BEPGs)--a Treaty-based tool
for economic policy coordination--in the period 2000-2005.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 12 OMITTED]
Importantly, progress in the cross-border integration of services
has been more muted than expected. Price rigidities in this area are
particularly problematic since it impedes reallocation of resources from
non-tradeable to tradeable sectors in countries with unsustainable
current account deficits. This has led to intensified surveillance of
national structural policies in the Euro Area under the Lisbon Strategy
for Growth and Jobs when it was revamped in 2005.
A global role for the euro
It was clear from the outset that the euro would not quickly
overtake the US dollar's dominant position. Even so, the euro has
emerged as the second most important international currency alongside
the US dollar and continues to consolidate this position. The euro has
become a prominent currency of denomination in international debt
markets and its role as an invoicing and reserve currency has been
growing as well (figure 13). It has become a reference currency in the
managed exchange rate regimes of about 40 countries. Accordingly, the
euro serves as a stability anchor for many countries. However,
Europe's external representation in international fora-such as the
Bretton Woods institutions--has remained fragmented, reducing its
influence despite the large number of seats that EU (and Euro Area)
countries hold in them. While a problem in itself, it is also a symptom
of the recurrent political resistance against policy coordination at the
EU centre. This takes us to the issue of Euro Area governance.
Governance of the Euro Area
The economic governance of the Euro Area is anchored in the
principle of 'subsidiarity', which leaves policy
responsibilities to the participating countries wherever possible,
subject to coordination where needed. Softer forms of coordination are
employed in the Lisbon Strategy, whereas fiscal coordination is stricter
and rules-based. Although there have frequently been frictions, the
governance structure of the Euro Area has helped promote a common
understanding among Euro Area policymakers of the importance of sound
public finances and flexible product, labour and capital markets for a
smooth functioning of EMU.
Even so, EMU's governance has at times suffered from a deficit
of political and national ownership, with some Member States reluctant
to translate a common understanding of policy challenges into
policymaking at home. Decisive steps to improve this situation were
taken in 2005, when the Stability and Growth Pact was reformed. The
Lisbon Strategy for Growth and Jobs was equipped with a Euro Area
dimension, and the President of the Eurogroup--the informal gathering of
Euro Area Finance Ministers that traditionally precedes the meetings of
the Council of Economics and Finance Ministers (ECOFIN)--henceforth
appointed for a term of two years (as opposed to a biannual rotating
presidency).
The Stability and Growth Pact was designed to have a dissuasive effect on countries who would be tempted to run large fiscal deficits.
The Pact has a 'preventive arm', calling on countries to run
surpluses or balanced budgets in 'good times', and a
'corrective arm' that may result in penalties if countries
durably fail to respect the 3 per cent rule. But, as noted, underlying
budgetary imbalances were built up during good times even if not to the
same extent as previously. And there have been sizeable deviations from
agreed adjustment paths of the fiscal position (figure 14). Moreover,
attempts to comply with the 3 per cent of GDP reference value for budget
deficits in some cases led to only cosmetic improvements (Buti et al.,
2007, Koen and Van den Noord, 2006).
Since the adoption of a reform of the Pact in 2005, which
introduced inter alia provisions for country-specific circumstances such
as desirable--yet deficit-unfriendly-pension reforms, the enforcement of
the corrective arm has been running much more smoothly. (3) However,
further progress concerning the preventive arm would be warranted in
view of the impact of unsustainable asset booms on public finances.
As noted, structural reform has remained largely within the remit
of the Member States. The 'softer' form of coordination
employed here has its legal basis in Article 99 of the EC Treaty, which
requires all EU Member States to 'regard their economic policies as
a matter of common concern and shall coordinate them within the
Council'. The Broad Economic Policy Guidelines (BEPGs), to which
the Treaty has assigned a central role in the coordination of economic
policies, help to internalise Euro Area priorities such as the need for
flexible and effective adjustment of prices and wages in the absence of
internal exchange rates into Member States' reform priorities.
However, the potential benefits of structural policy coordination are
not yet being exploited to the full.
Another important area of EMU governance concerns the conduct of
exchange rate policy. Formal or informal agreements on exchange rates
with partners outside the Euro Area require a decision by the Council,
while the Eurosystem (the National Central Banks and the ECB) holds the
foreign exchange reserves of the Euro Area and has sole responsibility
for exchange rate intervention. In practice the conduct of exchange rate
policy has not encountered major problems, but inconsistencies in public
statements of Eurogroup members have occasionally occurred. With the
2005 decision to appoint the Eurogroup President for a term of two
years, the situation seems to have improved in this respect. However, as
noted, there is still an issue of international representation.
3. The second decade: new challenges ahead
The long-standing sceptics proved largely wrong about the Euro
Area. It did not fall apart (it expanded), monetary policy quickly
established a credible price stability anchor, fiscal and monetary
policies turned out to be mostly supportive of each other and the single
currency reinforced the European single market. Not all objectives were
achieved. Public perceptions of the euro remained muted at best, growth
disappointed despite a measurable positive impact of the euro on
activity, intra-area imbalances developed and need to be corrected, and
the governance of the Euro Area keeps calling for attention. But one is
left with a favourable picture of EMU's first decade overall.
However, the economic successes of EMU, laudable as they may be,
were achieved in a global economic environment that--with hindsight--can
only be qualified as exceptionally benign. The 'great
moderation' of output and inflation volatility in the world
facilitated macroeconomic policymaking in the Euro Area. New
technologies and globalisation created favourable supply conditions that
helped to keep inflation in check, despite soaring prices of raw
materials and energy associated with rapid growth in emerging economies.
Demand was buoyed by low interest rates and (perceived or genuine)
wealth gains. Fiscal windfalls enabled governments to expand their
budgets without immediately raising alarm bells. The tide suddenly
turned when the global financial system entered its most pervasive
crisis since the 1930s.
[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]
3. 1 First priority: resolving the financial crisis
In its initial stages the financial crisis led to severe and
persistent liquidity shortages and soaring risk premia on financial
products. With the default of the American investment bank Lehman
Brothers in September 2008 the crisis entered a second phase in which
liquidity almost completely dried up and a credit squeeze paralysed
economic activity. Consumer and producer confidence plummeted to
historic lows and global trade declined at a pace that dwarfs the
2001--3 downturn (figure 15). No Member State of the Euro Area, or of
the European Union as a whole, will escape a sharp contraction in
activity and a surge in unemployment.
The origin of the crisis resides in the period of historically low
global interest rates during the late 1990s and 2000s and lax regulation
and supervision that failed to keep pace with (often misguided)
innovation in financial markets. The crisis began in the United States,
but the mechanisms at work have been global. Bubbles inflated in many
markets, including in real estate markets, due to excessive leveraging.
Several emerging economies in Central and Eastern Europe, but also
several Euro Area countries with large current account deficits and
excessive leveraging, have been severely hit by capital flows now being
reversed.
To prevent a collapse of the global financial system, central banks
both in Europe and elsewhere have injected massive liquidity, eased
their collateral requirements and cut their policy rates. Governments
recapitalised financial institutions or guaranteed bad loans and other
'toxic' assets. Several have provided guarantees on new bank
lending and in some cases banks have been nationalised. Other measures
include the extension of deposit guarantees (in the EU based on a
coordinated initiative), limits on short selling and adjustment of
accounting rules with regard to mark-to-market valuation. Several EU
countries are now receiving emergency balance of payment support from
the International Monetary Fund and the European Union.
The European Union has initiated a coordinated fiscal stimulus
package in response to the crisis. The European Economic Recovery Plan
(European Commission, 2008b) was the centrepiece of the December 2008
European Council, at which an aggregate stimulus of 1.5 per cent of EU
GDP was agreed. Many third countries have also put national economic
recovery plans in place. At the international level, the EU is playing a
leading role in the G20 process, which has been the focus of efforts to
address the downturn in global economic confidence.
It should be emphasised that without the euro the handling of the
crisis would be a lot more difficult. The existence of a single central
bank has facilitated the implementation of liquidity injections and
transatlantic interventions in money markets. The effectiveness of
fiscal stimulus is stronger in the absence of offsetting exchange rate
movements and the incentives for co-ordination are stronger since each
country benefits from trade-spillover effects. The presence of the
EU-backed fiscal framework helps to contain 'non-Keyenesian'
responses to fiscal stimulus.
The main priority in the short term for the monetary and fiscal
authorities is to implement the necessary monetary and fiscal stimulus
without de-anchoring inflation expectations, jeopardising the
sustainability of public finances or aggravating intra-area imbalances.
This requires that simultaneously sound 'exit strategies' are
developed. It also requires that the fiscal stimulus is appropriately
dosed according to the fiscal space and the competitiveness situation of
each country. Fiscal stimulus may be counterproductive if it is not
credibly viewed as limited in time, conflicting with competitiveness
requirements or adding to already very high levels of public debt. It is
essential also that fiscal stimulus is coordinated so as to internalise
the cross-border spillover effects. The Commission's role is to
ensure a right balance is struck between short-term urgency and the
longer-term requirements.
3.2 Challenges and priorities for the longer run
The longer-term priorities for the Euro Area have not fundamentally
changed with the financial crisis, which are to safeguard macroeconomic
stability, foster economic growth and employment, enhance the quality
and sustainability of public finances, ensure a smooth enlargement of
the area and promote a more prominent role of the Euro Area in the
global arena. Moreover, well before the crisis erupted it was clear that
these priorities needed to be pursued in a world economy that continues
to globalise and become more dominated by emerging economies, while
aging population and environmental and energy constraints put a brake on
trend economic growth.
But obviously the crisis will leave its mark also in the longer
run. In particular, potential economic growth may be further weakened by
lower investment associated with surging capital cost and higher
structural unemployment due to industrial restructuring. This will bear
on public finances, but the crisis will also affect the longer-term
fiscal situation directly, via a legacy of banking rescues, fiscal
stimulus and higher bond yields in some Member States. Moreover, the
financial crisis has clearly demonstrated that global shocks, common to
all Euro Area countries and calling for coordinated responses, take
precedence over 'asymmetric' country-specific shocks. So the
longer-term policy agenda of EMU has become even more pertinent with the
financial crisis.
Globalisation and other secular trends
Globalisation has been progressing apace and the share of the
emerging economies in the global economy is set to rise progressively
(figure 16). Globalisation offers major opportunities for efficiency
gains and implies lower prices and bigger choice for consumers. But it
also makes a strong call on the adjustment capacity of the
industrialised countries, including in the Euro Area. Declining
industries will need to restructure and be replaced with new activities.
Research, innovation and human capital building will become ever more
important drivers of economic growth and dynamism.
[FIGURE 15 OMITTED]
But globalisation has also led to global imbalances building up.
Saving surpluses in the emerging economies in Asia have facilitated
excessive borrowing in economies with developed capital markets that
attracted foreign capital, notably the United States, where excessive
leveraging put the stability of the global economy at risk. The
financial crisis is a short-run manifestation of this risk, a release of
tension emanating from these tectonic shifts. Once the dust has settled,
the world economy will most likely not return to its pre-crisis state as
saving behaviour across the world must change fundamentally. The
external imbalances within the Euro Area in some ways replicate this
global 'model' and will have to go through a similar
adjustment--which has yet to begin.
One of the triggers of the financial crisis has been the surge in
energy and food prices in response to the rapid growth of the world
economy and changing consumption and production patterns. These price
increases may well resume once the global economy recovers. In addition,
with the integration of China's and India's labour force into
the global economy nearing its completion, global disinflation may have
run its course--and this is likely to present an increasingly stiff
challenge for monetary policy.
Adverse global 'supply' shocks--including those possibly
stemming from climate change--may be recurrent, and will be a common
concern for all Euro Area countries.
The rapid ageing of populations is bound to leave its mark on the
growth potential and public finances of the Euro Area economy. The ratio
between the number of people at retirement age and those at working age
is projected to double in the coming four decades. Under unchanged
policies trend economic growth in the Euro Area would gradually fall to
just over I per cent per annum (figure 17). This projection was made
prior to the economic crisis; if the crisis proves to be protracted (and
it most likely will), capital formation and productivity growth suffer
and lower trend growth may result. Ageing may also reduce the adjustment
capacity of the economy--particularly unwelcome if supply shocks become
more frequent.
Requirements for economic policy
The imminent increase in ageing-related public expenditure calls
for careful long-term fiscal planning so as to safeguard the
sustainability of public finances (figure 18). This was perceived as a
major challenge even before the financial crisis. Now there is no
escape; fiscal positions must move towards a sustainable path as quickly
as possible once the crisis is over. Moreover, as noted, official
long-term projections foresee potential growth of the Euro Area to be
slashed from 2 to i per cent per annum over the next decades. To reverse
this tendency, both productivity and labour force participation need to
be boosted, so as to strengthen competitiveness, maintain or improve
living standards and facilitate fiscal management.
In addition, the adjustment capacity of the Euro Area needs to be
bolstered. From the outset this was seen as a prerequisite for the
success of EMU. During the first decade of EMU the adjustment capacity
of Euro Area members has hardly been tested, owing to the benign
economic environment. The financial crisis and the ensuing deleveraging
process, along with the need for industrial restructuring (with the
construction, automotive and financial industries most affected), will
cater for such a test. It is essential that the necessary restructuring
is not hampered by keeping ailing industries alive at all costs. It is
therefore essential also that the achievements of the Internal Market
remain intact and that governments do not give in to protectionist sentiments.
The Euro Area is blessed with developed social security systems,
which underpin the automatic fiscal stabilisers and are welfare
enhancing, especially in times of crisis. The sustainable financing of
these systems is an important challenge. The projected low potential
growth and the aging of the population underline the need for timely
measures to avoid an explosive development of public debt, harmful cuts
in public infrastructure investment or distorting tax increases. Tax and
benefit systems must be shaped so as to minimise the disincentives to
work. Medium-term budgetary frameworks should be developed or improved.
Well functioning financial markets are a precondition for
macroeconomic stability and contribute to the growth potential and
adjustment capacity of market economies. They share risk and promote the
inter-temporal smoothing of consumption, and tend to increase the impact
of structural reform by ensuring that capital flows 'down
hill', i.e. to destination countries where the marginal return on
capital is highest. Well-functioning financial markets also heighten the
incentives for governments to embark on bold structural reform in labour
and capital markets (Buti et al. 2009).
[FIGURE 17 OMITTED]
However, financial integration cannot be left unattended, as it can
contribute--and the Euro Area has contributed-to unsustainable current
account imbalances, housing bubbles and financial contagion risks
(European Commission, 2007b). These risks, in turn, tend to be
exacerbated by market distortions and rigidities in the real economy.
The financial crisis strongly revealed these risks and has clearly
demonstrated that closer cross-border cooperation on crisis prevention
and resolution are a necessity along with regulatory and supervisory
arrangements in the EU that are consistent with the ongoing financial
integration. However, it is important to guard against excessive or
misguided re-regulation so as to not throw the baby away with the
bathwater. Eventually, most current EU members will join the Euro Area.
But also in this area the crisis is taking its toll. It has magnified
the perceived advantages of participating in a monetary union and
therefore, not surprisingly, aroused renewed interest of candidate
countries to join. Some of them have been running large external
deficits and accumulated large foreign liabilities, often denominated in
foreign currency. So it is not surprising they are seeking protection
against the financial crisis--to which they are especially
vulnerable--via adoption of the euro. However, candidate countries must
comply with the nominal convergence criteria enshrined in the Treaty,
even if this has become more demanding in the current environment.
4. A policy agenda for the next decade
The second decade of EMU will be more challenging than the first
one. Trend growth will be slower and the sustainability of
countries' welfare states at risk. The first priority now is to
manage the crisis and to implement a viable exit strategy. A balance has
to be struck between short-term emergency measures and longer-term
priorities. The EMU@10 report offers a policy agenda to meet these
longer-term priorities. It is built on three pillars: broader and deeper
policy coordination and surveillance, a stronger international role for
the Euro Area and more effective governance.
4.1 The domestic policy agenda: propping up coordination and
surveillance
Deepening and broadening of surveillance Countries which
accumulated large macroeconomic imbalances are those that are most
vulnerable to the current crisis. Unsustainable boom conditions put an
overly favourable gloss on their--now rapidly deteriorating-fiscal
positions while the financing of their typically large current account
deficits became problematic with the onset of the crisis.
[FIGURE 18 OMITTED]
Fiscal surveillance did not work properly in the 'good
times' that preceded the financial crisis. With the crisis
unfolding, deficits in Euro Area countries are now soaring, with four of
them exceeding the 3 per cent of GDP mark by large margins--and more
trouble ahead. Fiscal surveillance must be improved, with the fiscal
impact of asset cycles properly taken into account. Countries should
commit to realistic time paths for public expenditure for the medium run
and allow automatic stabilisers to operate around this central path
insofar as the Treaty deficit and debt rules permit this. Member States
should shape their expenditure and funding plans in ways that benefit
growth, competitiveness and employment.
The crisis has clearly exposed the harmful nature of divergent
external and competitiveness positions within the area. Surveillance
must be broadened to include competitiveness and balance of payment
issues. The new EU member states still outside the Euro Area should be
included in this regular surveillance. Due to the (in itself desirable)
large capital flows to them they have been susceptible to overheating
and the formation of bubbles--which now cause havoc as they burst. This
may affect their macroeconomic stability as well as their prospects of
Euro Area membership. Enhanced coordination and surveillance are
inevitable, and if the crisis is to trigger this, it has at least served
one purpose.
The proposals in EMU@10 do not require revisions of the Treaty.
Article 99 of the Treaty stipulates that "Member States shall
regard their economic policies as a matter of common concern" and
"shall coordinate them within the Council", so the principle
of broad and deep policy coordination and surveillance has a firm legal
anchor. A first step towards implementing the proposals was taken by the
Council last autumn, when it mandated the Eurogroup to review the
competitiveness position of the Euro Area member states on a regular
basis.
Integrating structural, financial and macro surveillance The crisis
has demonstrated the importance of spotting macro-financial risks early
and heightened the need for reforms in labour and product markets to
boost potential growth and the adjustment capacity of Euro Area Members.
Structural policy was seen as essential for a well functioning Euro
Area from the outset. It supports growth and smoothes adjustment to
external shocks. Moreover, in a monetary union the multiplier effects of
structural reform tend to be larger since the reformers will more easily
attract foreign capital, not hampered by exchange risk. The Lisbon
Strategy is thus of particular importance for the Euro Area. In
particular, the competition in services markets needs to be
strengthened, the functioning of the labour market improved and
innovation promoted. Against this backdrop the surveillance of
structural and macroeconomic policies in the Euro Area must be
integrated. Lisbon and Maastricht are not that far apart. In fact, they
have come even closer with the financial crisis.
If there is anything the financial crisis has demonstrated it is
that close cooperation of EU Member States is crucial for financial
stability. Of course there is no point in restricting this to the Euro
Area--not least since the EU's largest financial centre (London) is
located outside the Euro Area. But the Euro Area should play a leading
role because of the particular importance of a well-functioning
financial system for the single currency. Euro Area members have been
reluctant to play this role until recently, but the acute financial
stability risks in the autumn of 2008 drove Euro Area Heads of State and
Government together for the first time in history. This precedent should
clear the way for macro-prudential surveillance at the centre.
4.2 The external agenda: a global role for the Euro Area
The crisis has clearly shown that there is a need for stronger
global governance. Being the second largest currency union in the world,
the Euro Area is naturally disposed to be a major contributor in this
regard.
The single currency put the Euro Area on the map as a global
financial player. Governments in the Euro Area draw financial benefits
from the use of the euro as an international reserve currency, and not
only eliminated Member States' intra-area exchange rate risk but
also reduced their global exchange rate risk because international
transactions are increasingly invoiced and settled in euro. Conversely,
with massive amounts of financial assets denominated in euro
circulating, Euro Area monetary policy decisions are felt all across the
globe. Even the smallest Euro Area countries play, at least indirectly,
a role in the international economic and financial power play.
It is thus essential that Euro Area countries work together towards
a common strategy that reflects the economic weight of the area in the
pursuit of stronger global governance. This should of course be embedded
in an overarching strategy for the European Union as a whole-there is no
point in creating division. But as a minimum the Euro Area should speak
with one voice in the international dialogue, for example on issues like
exchange rate policies and the surveillance of the global financial
system. This is, unfortunately, not yet the case--with the exception of
recent dialogues with China.
As part of this strategy the Euro Area could start streamlining its
representation in the international institutions that together govern
the financial system in the world. European countries are often blamed
for being overrepresented in institutions like the International
Monetary Fund, but in practice Europe does not draw any benefit from
this at all since its negotiation position is often undermined by
recurrent internal disputes. Europe may be better off with less seats
and a more effective coordination of positions. That would also
strengthen the international dialogue by creating room at the table for
the emerging countries.
4.3 A better governance of the Euro Area
The financial crisis has made it clear that coordination of
economic policies at the Euro Area level is indispensible. Economic
governance in the Euro Area is guided by the EU principle of
'subsidiarity'; government action should take place at the
lowest possible level. However, cross-border spillovers of policy action
call for coordination and this requirement has become more pertinent
with the current policy response to the crisis.
As recent events have illustrated, the ECOFIN Council remains at
the core of the governance of the Euro Area. This is where policy
decisions are formally taken and where the views not only of the Euro
Area countries but also of their EU peers outside the Euro Area (who are
prospective Euro Area members in most cases) are represented. It also
covers a broader set of policy areas-ranging from financial markets to
taxation--than the Eurogroup does and is therefore best positioned to
oversee the necessary tradeoffs across policy areas.
The Eurogroup should serve as a platform for deepening and
broadening of coordination and surveillance in the Euro Area--a role
which it is progressively assuming. It should focus on the prevention of
pro-cyclical or unsustainable fiscal policies ex ante and reinforce the
'preventive arm' of the Stability and Growth Pact to help
countries to prepare for fiscal stress associated with aging populations
and also the unwinding of a presumably huge legacy of implicit
liabilities--if not outright debt- after the financial crisis is over.
To rein in or prevent the recurrence of intra-area balance of payments
problems, the Eurogroup should develop guidelines on policies that
affect competitiveness.
The Commission should assume a strong supportive role and better
integrate EMU-related concerns in the whole range of its policy
proposals. It should enhance its fiscal and macroeconomic surveillance
and reinforce its role in fostering economic and financial
integration--sorely needed in an environment where protectionist
instincts risk resuscitating. It should play an active role in improving
the cyclical adjustment of fiscal positions in cooperation with the
Member States. Considering the external policy agenda, the Commission
should strengthen its role in the international dialogues and fora
alongside the Member States and take an intellectual lead in debates on
global institutional reforms.
An effective governance of the Euro Area is also an important
precondition for a smooth enlargement of the Euro Area. The second
decade will undoubtedly see the adoption of the euro in most EU Member
States, notwithstanding (or perhaps because of) the financial crisis.
The accession criteria are enshrined in the Treaty, so Euro Area
accession countries will need to respect these. The Commission will
continue to provide an honest assessment of countries' readiness to
join on the basis of the criteria while the Eurogroup and ECOFIN Council
will continue to issue policy advice in the pursuit of a smooth
accession of these countries, several of which are suffering more than
average from the consequences of the crisis.
5. Conclusions
Economic and Monetary Union emerged from the currency crises in the
early-1990s and the ensuing breakdown of ERM mark 1. Although it met a
lukewarm reception; it represented a leap forward in European monetary,
economic and political integration. The transition to a monetary union
in 1999 went smoothly, the euro instantly became the world's second
international currency, the ECB achieved a strong reputation and several
new EU members in the East have gained membership of the Euro Area.
With hindsight the first decade of EMU may not have been
particularly challenging and economic conditions are now deteriorating
very rapidly. With countries facing very different exposures to the
crisis the risk of conflict is real. But speculation that this could
lead to a break-up of the Euro Area is ill-founded. Europe's
post-war history is one of progress and compromises, and this is likely
to continue, not least since the euro proves an invaluable asset from
which each country derives major benefits.
It is useful to recall that in its initial stages the US federal
system allocated very limited powers to the centre, with the system
evolving towards more federalism with each major crisis (Bordo and
James, 2008). This may also be Europe's future. The coordinated
policy responses to the crisis may well portend another leap forward in
the integration of the Euro Area and, ultimately, the European Union as
a whole.
REFERENCES
Baldwin, R, DiNino, V., Fontagne, L., De Santis, R.A. and Taglioni,
D. (2008), 'Study on the impact of the euro on trade and foreign
direct investment', European Economy--Economic Papers, 321,
European Commission.
Barrell, R., Gottschalk, S., Holland, D., Khoman, E., Liadze, I.
and Pomerantz, O. (2008), 'The impact of EMU on growth and
employment', European Economy--Economic Papers, 318, European
Commission.
Bean, C. (1998), 'The interaction of aggregate-demand policies
and labour market reform', Swedish Economic Policy Review, 5, pp.
353-82.
Bordo, M. and James, H. (2008), 'A long-term perspective on
the euro', European Economy--Economic Papers, 307, European
Commission.
Buti, M., Nogueira Martins and Turrini, A. (2007), 'From
deficits to debt and back: political incentives under numerical fiscal
rules', CESifo Economic Studies, 53, pp. 1125-52.
Buti, M. and Sapir, A. (eds) (1998), Economic Policy in EMU--A
Study by the Commission Services, Oxford University Press.
--(2002), EMU and Economic Policy in Europe--The Challenge of the
Early Years, Edward Elgar.
Buti, M., Turrini, A., van den Noord, P. and Biroli, P. (2009),
'Defying the 'Juncker Curse': can reformist governments
be re-elected?', Empirica, 36(1), pp. 65-100.
Calmfors, L. (2001), 'Unemployment, labour market reform and
monetary union', Journal of Labor Economics, 19(2), pp. 26589.
De Larosiere Group (2009), Report of the High-Level Group on
Financial Supervision in the EU, Brussels.
Duval, R. (2005), 'Fiscal positions, fiscal adjustment and
structural reforms in labour and product markets', in Deroose, S.,
Flores, E. and Turrini, A. (eds) (2005), Budgetary implications of
structural reforms, European Economy--Economic Papers, no. 248, European
Commission.
Duval, R. and Elmeskov, J. (2006), 'The effects of EMU on
structural reforms in labour and product markets', ECB Working
Paper Series, 596, European Central Bank.
European Commission (2007a), 'The EU economy: 2007
review-moving Europe's productivity frontier', European
Economy, 8/ 2007.
--(2007b), 'EU financial integration and Euro Area
adjustment', Quarterly Report on the Euro Area, 6(2), pp. 43-42.
--(2008b), 'EMU@10, successes and challenges after ten years
of economic and monetary union', European Economy, 2/2008.
--(2008b), A European Economic Recovery Plan, COM (2008) 800.
Gayer, C. (2007), 'A fresh look at business cycle
synchronisation in the Euro Area', European Economy--Economic
Papers, 287, European Commission.
Havik, K., McMorrow, K., Roger, W. and Turrini, A. (2008),
'EUUS productivity differences: a macro, sectoral and industry
level perspective', European Economy--Economic Papers, 339,
European Commission.
Koen, V. and van den Noord, P. (2006), 'Fiscal gimmickry in
Europe: one-off measures and creative accounting', in Wierts, P. et
al. (eds), Fiscal policy surveillance in Europe, Palgrave Macmillan.
Turrini, A. (2008), 'Fiscal policy and the cycle in the Euro
Area: the role of government revenue and expenditure', European
Economy--Economic Papers, 323, European Commission.
Von Hagen, J. and Wyplosz, C. (2008), 'EMU's
decentralized system of fiscal policy', European Economy--Economic
Papers, 306, European Commission.
The public's perception of the euro
Since the introduction of the cash euro, the European Commission
has conducted regular opinion polls to monitor citizens' attitudes
towards the single currency (Eurobarometer). According to these polls
people are aware of the microeconomic benefits of the euro, such as the
reduction of transaction costs, the ease of travel and the increase in
price transparency. But they remain more sceptical about the euro's
macroeconomic benefits such as price stability and stronger growth.
Moreover, while around two-thirds of respondents consider the euro to be
"a good thing for Europe"; less than half consider it to be a
"good thing for their country". Men, younger people and
citizens with higher education or higher incomes generally judge the
euro more favourably than women, older people and citizens with lower
education or income. (a)
Research suggests that popular support for the euro is correlated
with inflation perceptions. Inflation perceptions, as measured by the
European Commission's Consumer Surveys, increased significantly
with the euro cash changeover in 2002. A number of factors have been
identified which could explain this phenomenon. These include the
relative price increases for frequently purchased goods (food, energy),
the steep increase in house prices in many countries, low increases in
disposable income and various psychological factors.(b) It is notable
that respondents show little awareness of the actual inflation rate
though; two-thirds either have a too high estimate of the actual
inflation rate or admit not to know it.
Notes: (a) Dohring, B. and Moronu, A. (2007), 'What drives
inflation perceptions? A dynamic panel analysis', European
Economy--Economic Papers, 284. (b) Jonung, L. and Conflitti, C. (2008),
'Is the euro advantageous? Does it foster European feelings?
Europeans on the euro after five years', European Economy--Economic
Papers, 313.
NOTES
(1) Concretely, countries are required to move towards and sustain
a fiscal position 'close to balance or in surplus' over the
medium term and will be subject to corrective measures if the fiscal
deficit exceeds 3 per cent of GDP and/or if public debt fails to
converge towards or below 60 per cent of GDP, unless 'special
circumstances' can be demonstrated. Participating countries submit
annually a Stability Programme which contains a record of current and
expected fiscal outcomes and on which the assessment of compliance by
the European Commission and the European Council is based.
(2) According to conventional methodologies to cyclically adjust
fiscal positions, only the impact of the GDP cycle is considered while
the fiscal impact of asset cycles is assessed at best in qualitative
terms.
(3) In March 2005 a reform of the Stability and Growth Pact was
adopted by the ECOFIN Council. The 'preventive arm' of the
Pact henceforth focused on structural balances and allowed the
possibility of adopting medium-term budgetary objectives that were
better tailored to a country's specific circumstances, while
permitting some flexibility in the pace at which this objective should
be achieved, depending on a country's structural reform efforts
(notably pension reform). In the 'corrective arm', the
economic circumstances that could lead to a waiver of the excessive
deficit procedure were reinterpreted and clarified. In addition, some
flexibility was also introduced regarding the length of the adjustment
period, inter alia to take into account possible adverse economic events
with major unfavourable consequences for government finances.
Marco Buti and Paul van den Noord, Directorate General for Economic
and Financial Affairs, European Commission. e-mail:
Paul.VANDENNOORD@ec.europa.eu and Marco.Buti@ec.europa.eu. The authors
have written this article in a personal capacity. The views expressed
are not necessarily those of the European Commission.
Table I. Growth and employment, average rate of change
per annum, per cent
1989-1998 1999-2008
Euro Area
Real GDP 2.2 2.1
Real GDP per capita 1.9 1.6
Level of real GDP (US=100) 73 72
Employment 0.6 1.3
Labour productivity 1.6 0.8
United States
Real GDP 3.0 2.6
Real GDP per capita 1.8 1.6
Employment 1.5 1.0
Labour productivity 1.5 1.6
Source: European Commission, OECD.
Figure 13. Currency shares in foreign exchange reserves
1999 2007
USD 71% 65%
EUR 18% 26%
JPY 6% 3%
GBP 3% 5%
Other 2% 2%
Source: European Commission.
Note: Table made from pie chart.
Figure 16. Geographical composition of world GDP in 2005 and 2050
2005 2050
Europe 26% 18%
Other, 12% 9%
China, 10% 22%
North America, 35% 37%
Japan, 14% 8%
India, 3% 6%
Source: European Commission.
Note: Table made from bar graph.