首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月06日 星期三
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Up and down the generational income ladder in Britain: past changes and future prospects.
  • 作者:Blanden, Jo ; Machin, Stephen
  • 期刊名称:National Institute Economic Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0027-9501
  • 出版年度:2008
  • 期号:July
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:National Institute of Economic and Social Research
  • 关键词:Personal income

Up and down the generational income ladder in Britain: past changes and future prospects.


Blanden, Jo ; Machin, Stephen


This article seeks evidence on trends in intergenerational income for cohorts born after 1970. As many of these cohorts have not yet joined the labour market, we must look at relationships between intermediate outcomes (degree attainment, test scores and non-cognitive abilities) and parental income to forecast forward from these to estimates of intergenerational earnings correlations. We find no evidence that the relationship between these intermediate outcomes and parental income have changed for more recent cohorts. Evidence from the earlier 1958 and 1970 cohorts shows that as mobility declined in the past the relationship between intermediate outcomes and parental income strengthened. We therefore conclude that, under realistic assumptions and in the absence of any significant unanticipated changes, the decline in intergenerational mobility that occurred between 1958 and 1970 birth cohorts is unlikely to continue for cohorts born from 1970 to 2000. Mobility is therefore likely to remain at or near the relatively low level observed for the 1970 birth cohort.

Keywords: Intergenerational mobility; children

I. Introduction

Social mobility has become one of the high profile public policy issues of modern society. However, much of the evidence currently discussed is backward looking, owing to the very demanding data requirements and modelling issues needed to estimate changes in mobility over time. Measuring income mobility, the extent to which people move up and down the generational ladder, requires data on incomes of people and their parents which, by necessity, means they need to be old enough to earn an income. (1) This creates a problem for policy which needs to look forward and try to appraise how much (or how little) social mobility there is likely to be for people not yet old enough to participate in the labour market.

Amongst people of labour market age, Blanden et al. (2004) identified a fall in intergenerational income mobility in a comparison of a birth cohort born in 1970 compared to one born in 1958. More specifically, adult earnings of the second cohort were more closely linked to their parental income when they were aged 16 as teenagers than was the case for the first cohort. (2) However, these results relate to individuals growing up in Britain in the 1970s and 1980s. In fact the 1958 cohort is, at the time of writing, aged almost 50 and the 1970 cohort nearing 40. Thus they tell us little (probably nothing) about children growing up in more recent policy environments. This is particularly the case if policy needs to be targeted towards early years as a number of influential authors have proposed (e.g. Carneiro and Heckman, 2003).

Seeking recent indicators of changes in social mobility for more recent cohorts (who may not be of labour market age) is of paramount importance in the light of the Government's concerted policy focus on social mobility and young people since 1997. The Government has directed additional funds into schools in inner-city areas through the Excellence in Cities Programme, provided pre-school services through Sure Start and has made substantial inroads into reducing child poverty. Last year the then Secretary of State for Education anticipated the positive impact that these policies would have on intergenerational mobility.

"The progress we have made since 1997--particularly at schools in deprived areas--means that there is every reason to expect that today's generation of poor children will have a much better chance to escape the limitations of their background."

Alan Johnson, Secretary of State for Education, 17 May 2007

In this paper we try to say something more about the likely mobility patterns for younger cohorts than has been said before. We do so by using a simple economic model which posits a link between a range of childhood outcomes and parental income which, under certain assumptions, provides a guide to subsequent levels of intergenerational income mobility. This is important, since it enables us to study more recent changes in social mobility for the younger cohorts yet to reach adulthood. These are the most important for thinking about in terms of public policy design and implementation.

Our results show that the fall in mobility experienced across the 1958 and 1970 cohorts appears to have been an episode caused by the particular circumstances of the time, such as the growth in income inequality and the uneven distribution of increased educational opportunities. Social mobility worsened and took a step change downwards, leaving the UK near the bottom of the intergenerational league table of mobility, and on a different trajectory relative to other countries in the world where there is less evidence of changes over time (Blanden, 2008). This fall in mobility was accompanied by strong increases in educational inequalities (e.g. a very sharp rise in the association between educational attainment and family income and stronger links between test scores and behavioural measures and family income).

Looking at the changing connection between these earlier age intervening factors (education attainment, test scores, behavioural measures) and family income for more recent cohorts we find no evidence of change; it appears that the decline in social mobility may well have flattened out. However, at the same time, they have not reversed nor started to improve and, under reasonable assumptions, social mobility appears unlikely to improve for the current set of children when they do become of labour market age.

In the next section we present our analytical framework and describe the data. Section 3 revisits the results of our intergenerational mobility analysis for the 1958 and 1970 cohorts, and links these results into our new framework. Section 4 reports estimates of models for more recent cohorts and considers the implications of our findings for the evolution of intergenerational mobility. Section 5 concludes.

2. Analytical framework and data

Conceptual framework

The extent of intergenerational income mobility is often measured by the following summary statistic, the coefficient [beta] in the following statistical regression:

In [Y.sub.t]children = [beta]In[Y.sub.]parents + [e.sub.i] (1)

where In [Y.sub.i]children is the log of some measure of earnings or income for children (when of adult age), and lnYiParents is the log of the same measure of earnings or income of their parents, i identifies the family to which parents and children belong and [e.sub.i] is an error term. [beta] is then the elasticity of children's income with respect to their parents' income and (1 - [beta]) defines the extent of intergenerational mobility.

We want to estimate [beta] consistently across time (over birth cohorts) to see if intergenerational mobility is getting better or worse. However, we cannot measure income for those cohorts not yet of labour market age, who are arguably the most important for considering policies to do with mobility.

We can, however, develop a model which studies earlier age outcomes and their relationship with parental income and examines how that maps into future intergenerational mobility. To see this, consider two life cycle stages, one which looks at how early age and childhood factors relate to parental income, and the other which looks at how income as an adult relates to these early age/childhood factors. In their simplest form, the two life cycle stages can he represented as:

Stage 1: The relationship between earlier age/childhood factors, Z, and family income:

[Z.sub.i] = [theta]In[Y.sub.i]parents + [u.sub.i] (2)

Stage 2: The relationship between child income (as an adult) and these earlier age factors

In[Y.sub.i]child = [lambda][Z.sub.i] + [v.sub.i] (3)

Here [theta] measures the sensitivity of the earlier age intervening factors Z to parental income and [lambda] the income 'returns' to Z, ( [u.sub.i] and [v.sub.i] are error terms). To be more concrete an obvious example would be if Z measures education, so that [theta] measures the sensitivity of education to parental income (stylistically 'how much more education children from rich backgrounds receive') and k the income returns to education ('how much more the highly qualified earn'). Of course, Z may be a whole range of factors that correlate with parental income and/or yield an income return as adults and we consider different possibilities below.

Putting the two together by substituting the first stage into the second stage gives the intergenerational function:

In[Y.sub.i]children = [lambda][theta]In[Y.sub.i]Parents + [lambda][u.sub.i] + [v.sub.i] (4)

Comparing equation (4) with the standard intergenerational mobility function in equation (1) shows that [beta] = [lambda] [theta]. However, it may be that [v.sub.i] is also related to In[Y.sub.i]parents so that [v.sub.i] = [alpha]In[Y.sub.i]parents + [w.sub.i]. Substituting this into (4) gives:

In[Y.sub.i]children = ([lambda][theta] + [alpha])In[Y.sub.i]Parents + [[epsilon].sub.i] (5)

where the error term [[epsilon].sub.i] = [lambda][u.sub.i] + [w.sub.i]. In a regression context it is evident that

[alpha] = cov([v.sub.i], In[Y.sup.parents.sub.i])/Var(In[Y.sup.parents.sub.i]), (6)

which is the direct influence of parental income on children's earnings that does not come through [Z.sub.i].

Implementation

In the above model the intergenerational parameter is [beta] = [lambda] [theta] + [alpha]. For cohorts in adulthood we can estimate [beta] and decompose the respective contributions of [theta], [lambda] and [alpha]. Importantly for our analysis we can study what happened to [theta], [lambda] and [alpha] in the period when [beta] rose (i.e. mobility fell). (3) For younger cohorts we can only estimate [theta] but we can, under certain assumptions about how [lambda] and [alpha] evolve over time, estimate [beta] even though the cohorts are too young yet to earn an income.

Our objective has similarities to the problem explored by Altonji, Bharadwaj and Lange (2008) in a recent paper. In their work Altonji et al. wish to compare the wage distribution for the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) 1979 cohort in their forties with the likely wage distribution for the NLSY 1997 cohort (which like our later cohorts has not yet entered the labour market) at the same age.

Altonji et al. observe w (wages) and z (characteristics correlated with wages) for the 1979 data but only z for the 1997 data. The wage distribution conditional on z for NLSY79 is estimated. This gives the relationship between z and w for the first cohort. By assuming that the conditional distribution of w given z does not change, the data can be reweighted (drawing on the approach of DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux, 1996) to replicate the distribution of z in the 1997 data and predict the future wage distribution for this cohort.

The two crucial assumptions implicit in Altonji et al.'s work are that the wage returns to z and the unmeasured influences on w do not change across cohorts. The parallel assumption in our own work would be to assume that [lambda] and [alpha] are unchanged. In our final section we experiment with these assumptions showing the impact on [beta] of [lambda] and [alpha] remaining constant and the effect of varying these parameters.

Data

In the first part of our empirical work we review the evidence on changes in [beta] and its components for older cohorts in the UK. In order to investigate intergenerational income mobility we need information on fathers' earnings or parental income as children are growing up and then information on the same children's earnings as adults. The 1958 (National Child Development Study or NCDS) and 1970 (British Cohort Study, or BCS) cohorts provide this information. These datasets selected all babies born in Britain in a single week in the springs of 1958 and 1970 respectively and rich information is obtained through childhood and into adult life. Data collection is continuing, and data collected in 2004 have recently been released.

For both cohorts parental income data are obtained at age 16. It is more common in the literature to estimate intergenerational mobility using earnings from both generations, but information on the components of income is not available for the second cohort. In addition, using parental income is more representative of the household's resources and better reflects the contribution of women working outside the home.

We use adult earnings information for age 33 for the 1958 cohort and age 34 for the 1970 cohort (i.e. in 1991 and 2004). Blanden et al. (2005) use earnings data for the BCS from age 30 but data from age 34 improve the comparability of data across the cohorts, and should lead to more accurate estimates of changes over time compared to previous work (see Haider and Solon, 2006, for a careful discussion of the possible impacts of lifecycle bias).

In order to compare the sensitivity of early age characteristics to parental income ([theta]) across the 1958 and 1970 cohorts and through to more recent data, we need measures of Z that are comparable across a number of our data sources. We use degree attainment, early age test scores and measures of externalising behaviour. In almost all of our datasets mothers are asked a number of items from the Rutter A scale (this is the version of the Rutter behaviour scale which is asked of parents, see Rutter et al. 1970). We combine selected items into an externalising behaviour measure by taking the first factor of a principal components analysis (as detailed in appendix tables la and b). A higher externalising score means children are more likely to 'act out' and misbehave. In the 1958 cohort we measure degree attainment at age 23, reading ability at age eleven and externalising behaviour at ages seven and eleven. In the 1970 cohort degree attainment is measured by age 23, reading at age ten and externalising behaviour at five and ten.

To investigate the likely level of mobility for more recent cohorts we study cohorts born between 1970 and 2000; again using degree attainment, early age test scores and mother's reports of behaviour as our Z variables. Our first source of information is the British Household Panel Survey. This survey began in 1991 and has collected evidence on 5000 households for all subsequent years. The longitudinal element of these data enables us to measure children's family income at age sixteen and then to observe their educational achievements; here we consider whether they obtain a degree by age 23. As there are now fourteen years' worth of 16-year olds available we split these into younger and older pseudo cohorts.

As discussed above, the 1958 and 1970 cohorts have made an important contribution to understanding mobility for those growing up in the 1970s and 1980s. The intergenerational story told by these data has been extended by collecting information on the children of the original cohort members. In 1991, data were collected about natural or adopted co-resident children for one third of the 1958 cohort members (those born in a week in 1958). Three thousand children were included aged between three and seventeen years old. Tests administered were the Peabody Individual Attainment test (for maths and reading) and the Peabody Picture Vocabulary test. The mother also answered a questionnaire providing more information on the behaviour and home environment of the children.

In 2004 a similar data collection exercise was conducted for the children of the 1970 cohort. In this case, data on children were collected for half of the cohort. Age-appropriate assessments of word and number skills from the British Ability Scales were carried out to gauge children's cognitive skills and attainment. Similar behavioural measures are taken from parents in both cohorts. Those that we use can be seen in appendix table lb.

Both datasets of the 'kids of' can be matched with information from the main surveys which provides details of parental education, family income and earnings, among numerous other characteristics. Information on family income is formed by adding together information on all of the cohort members' and their partners' sources of income (careful cleaning has been carried out here).

Another source of evidence which contains information on children's performance and their family background is the Millennium Cohort Study (MCS), which includes a large sample of children born in 2000 and 2001. The intention is to follow these children through life on a similar basis to the original cohorts. So far information is available at nine months, three years and five years. Cognitive test scores and behavioural reports are available at ages three and five.

We use percentiles of the vocabulary test at age five as our main measure. Once again questions are asked about the children's behaviour which are highly comparable with those available from the other data sources we use and can be used to create a behavioural index.

In order to compare results directly from the 'kids of' datasets and the MCS we must consider a number of issues about the selection of the samples and the variables used. Among the issues we confronted were the selection of age groups within the 'kids of' data, the construction of an MCS sample to mimic the 'kids of', the appropriate family income measure to use and the ethnic composition of the three datasets. There is more detail on these matters in the appendix.

It should be noted that the 'kids of' datasets were not designed to be representative samples of all children in the age group and while we have tried our best to adapt the data in our youngest cohorts to be comparable, the issue of representativeness introduces a caveat to our results. One useful aspect of the data we use is that the samples of the kids of BCS and the MCS were born only about one year apart. Therefore if we find similar results on these datasets we can be less worried about issues of comparability. The datasets we use in our comparative work are briefly summarised in the box above. The box emphasises why we need to look at earlier age intervening outcomes to say anything about more recent changes in social mobility. In almost all cases the N/A entries show that the most recent cohorts--the ones that are most relevant for contemporary policy debates--are characterised by missing information since these cohorts are simply not old enough to have got to these stages in the life cycle. (4) Our two-stage framework allows us to discuss likely social mobility for these more recent cohorts.
Dataset Year of birth In [[gamma].
 sub.i.sup.
 child]
 earnings
 observed

1958 Cohort 1958 1991
1970 Cohort 1970 2004
BHPS first
 pseudo cohort 1976 (average) N/A
BHPS second
 pseudo cohort 1980 (average) N/A
'Kids of 1958 cohort 1985 (average) N/A
'Kids of 1970 cohort 1999 (average) N/A
Millennium cohort 2000-2001 N/A

 Z

 Degree Tests
Dataset recorded taken

1958 Cohort 1981 1969
1970 Cohort 1993 1980
BHPS first
 pseudo cohort 1999 (average) N/A
BHPS second
 pseudo cohort 2002 (average) N/A
Kids of 1958 cohort N/A 1991
Kids of 1970 cohort N/A 2004
Millennium cohort N/A 2006

 Z

 Behavioural
 questions
Dataset answered

1958 Cohort 1965 and 1969
1970 Cohort 1975 and 1980
BHPS first
 pseudo cohort N/A
BHPS second
 pseudo cohort N/A
Kids of 1958 cohort 1991
Kids of 1970 cohort 2004
Millennium cohort 2006


Measurement issues

We take account of two important measurement issues in our estimations:

i) Changing income distributions:

Differences in the variance of InY between generations will distort estimates of [beta] which is why inequality adjusted parameters have to be considered throughout (Solon, 1992). This is in fact the partial correlation between parents' and children's status. This inequality adjusted measure of [beta] is obtained simply by scaling [beta] by the ratio of the standard deviation of parents' income to the standard deviation of sons' earnings. (5) An alternative way of obtaining the correlation is to standardise income and earnings before estimating the intergenerational mobility regression (both variables are scaled to have a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1). We therefore use standardised parental income to account for changing inequality in our estimates of the relationship between intermediate outcomes and parental income.

ii) Permanent versus transitory income

Ideally we would seek to measure parents' and children's status with a measure of permanent incomes. A common approach to approximate this is to use income averaged over a number of periods (Solon, 1989, Mazumder, 2005). In cases where averaged income is not available, we would be concerned that the measures of income available are not measured with equal accuracy over time. As shown by Solon (1992), and Zimmerman (1992), measurement error in parental income will lead to an attenuation of the estimated [beta] and lead to difficulties in making correct inferences about changes over time. To avoid this we adopt a two-stage procedure where we supplement our measures of parental income with predicted income from a regression of income on more permanent 'income proxy' characteristics such as education, employment and housing status.

We thus estimate predicted income as [[??].sup.parents.sub.i] = [??] Xi where the [??] are coefficients from a first stage equation that relates family income to a range of income proxies, [X.sub.i], so that the two stage [[beta].sub.2SLS] is estimated as

ln[Y.sup.children.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.2SLS] In[[??]sup.parents.sub.i] + [[omega].sub.i] (7)

This two-stage least squares (2SLS) approach has been shown to provide an estimate of [beta] which is biased upwards compared to its true value if the characteristics used to predict income have an independent influence on children's outcomes (Solon, 1992). In this case we can think of [beta] based on current income and [[beta].sub.2SLS] as providing lower and upper bounds on the true estimate.

3. Recap of existing evidence on changes in mobility for older cohorts Evidence on change mobility from the 1958 and 1970 cohorts

Tables la and lb report information on intergenerational mobility for these cohorts in the form of transition matrices. The tables show the proportion of sons in each parental income quartile that move into each quartile of their adult earnings distribution. We focus here on sons so that results are less directly influenced by women's labour market participation decisions. The extent of immobility can be summarised by an immobility index that computes the sum of the leading diagonal and its adjacent cells. The cells used to compute these are shaded in the tables and the resulting index reported at the bottom. These numbers can be interpreted relative to the immobility index in the case of perfect mobility. If all individuals had an equal chance of experiencing an adult income in each quartile, all cells would contain 0.25 and the immobility index (the sum of the diagonal band) would be 2.5.

The tables show a fall in intergenerational mobility across cohorts. In all cases there is a higher probability of sons remaining in the same quartile as their parents in the 1970 cohort compared with the 1958 cohort. For example, for sons in the bottom quartile the proportion remaining in the bottom quartile is 30 per cent for the 1958 cohort and 37 per cent in the 1970 cohort. Equally, there is a smaller chance of large movements in the second cohort with 18 per cent rising of those who start in the bottom quintile moving to the top quintile in the 1958 cohort and 13 per cent doing so in the 1970 cohort. The immobility indices reflect this fall in mobility, at 2.81 and 2.96 respectively.

In table 2 we provide estimates of average mobility for sons and daughters, again using earnings data at age 33 for the first cohort and at age 34 for the second. (6) The average measure of intergenerational mobility shows a sharp (and statistically significant) fall, with [beta] estimated as 0.21 for the 1958 cohort of sons and 0.33 for the 1970 cohort of sons. As shown in the second row, estimates of [[beta].sub.2SLS] are higher in both cohorts and also rise strongly across the cohorts. As discussed in Section 2, care must be taken in interpreting both [beta] and [[beta].sub.2SLS] when income inequality is changing. Columns 3 and 4 in each row show the partial correlation for each cohort with the final cohort showing the difference over time. This adjustment does not change our conclusion: the evidence indicates that intergenerational mobility has fallen across these cohorts for sons. In qualitative terms, panel B shows similar qualitative results for women, although the changes are slightly smaller in magnitude.

The influence of intervening factors

Table 3 summarises the association between family income at age sixteen and several intermediate outcomes for the original cohort members. This reveals a sharp rise in the association between family income and degree attainment with the linear probability coefficient on standardised income rising from 0.05 to 0.12. This rise in the inequality of access to higher education has been explored in detail elsewhere (Blanden and Machin, 2004) and shown to have a made a substantial contribution to the fall in intergenerational income mobility discussed above (Blanden, Gregg and Macmillan, 2007).

As shown in the second panel of table 3 there is also a statistically significant increase in the association between percentile in reading test and parental income. The Ordinary Least Squares specification shows that in the 1958 cohort a one standard deviation increase in income is associated with a 5.65 point increase in test score percentile, while in the 1970 cohort a one standard deviation increase in income leads to an 8.72 percentile increase. The third panel reveals the association between externalising behaviour, using tobit models to account for the clustering at the lowest level of behavioural problems. As we would expect, as a higher score indicates worse behaviour, there is a negative association between family income and the externalising score (scaled to have a mean of zero and standard deviation of one). At both younger and older ages the association between behaviour and parental income has grown significantly across the cohorts. We know these 'non-cognitive' traits tend to be related to later labour market outcomes (Heckman, Stixrud and Urzua, 2006) and if this association has not declined over cohorts then this rising association will contribute to the fall in intergenerational mobility.

As with the intergenerational income regressions in the previous section all our models are also estimated using the 2SLS framework. This confirms the findings of rising associations with income. It is reassuring that the findings are consistent across all the variables used.

The difficulty with comparisons based on reading scores in these datasets is that the tests used are not identical, so it might be that they are picking up different skills. In this case we use also two variables that we know are comparable across the cohorts (degree and externalising behaviour) meaning that it is not necessary to rely on test scores alone.

In our analysis of intergenerational income mobility in these two cohorts we explored both linear (regression) models and nonlinear (transition matrix) approaches. We can do the same for our intermediate outcomes. Table 4 presents the relationship between intermediate outcomes and age sixteen income in an alternative form, by showing the mean of the outcome within the top and bottom income quintiles and then the difference between these, which we describe as 'inequality'.

Once again, there is a clear expansion of inequality by parental income across the cohorts. For the poorest 20 per cent in terms of parental income, 5 per cent of the 1958 cohort achieved a degree; this compares with 20 per cent for the richest fifth. Comparable figures for the 1970 cohort are 7 per cent and 37 per cent. Inequality in degree attainment has therefore widened from 15 percentage points to 30 percentage points.

The second set of results provides test score percentiles by income group. The gap between the richest and poorest groups here is 16 percentiles for 11-year olds in the 1958 cohort and 25 percentiles for 10-year olds in the 1970 cohorts. Again we find a substantial (and statistically significant) expansion in inequality. This pattern is replicated in the results for externalising behaviour where inequality at both young ages (seven and five) and mid-childhood (eleven and ten) increases by about one fifth of a standard deviation between the cohorts.

4. Evidence for more recent cohorts

More recent evidence on cross-cohort changes in the relationship between Z and family income

Table 5 shows a similar analysis to the earlier table 3 for the more recent data. These estimates are based on the most comparable approaches to using the data for the 'kids of' and the MCS data. Estimations using alternative approaches are discussed in the appendix. (7)

The upper panel of the table reports coefficients on income from linear probability models of obtaining a degree by age 23. These are shown for the BCS data (those born in 1970) and then for those in the BHPS born on average in 1976 and 1980. Unlike the previous cross-cohort comparison of table 3, where the income coefficient rose steeply, there is no evidence of change for these cohorts.

The middle panel considers test scores. For the Ordinary Least Squares regression models there is no evidence that there has been a substantial change in the relationship between income and test scores, with a 1 standard deviation change in income leading to a 5-6 percentile change in reading/vocabulary score. (8,9) Notice that the estimates of the test-score income relationships in these recent cohorts around age five tends to be a little lower than for the 1970 cohort at age ten; this does not necessarily indicate that this relationship has declined, but more likely reflects the increasing influence of family background on attainment as children age (Feinstein, 2003 and Carneiro and Heckman, 2003). In the lower panel of table 5 we show the relationship between family income and behavioural measures at around age five, again there is no significant change.

More recent distributional analysis

A distributional analysis is given in table 6. There is much less evidence of a rise in the link between family income and degree attainment in more recent periods. The small increases in graduation rates that occurred for the (on average) 1975 cohorts compared with the 1970 group were evenly distributed across young people from different family income groups. Consequently, there was no evidence of a strong widening of educational inequality. Comparing across the two BHPS samples, there is a very slight widening of educational inequality with graduation rates among the poorest income groups dropping from 11 to 10 per cent and graduation rates among the richest 20 per cent growing by 4 per cent. However, the small samples in the BHPS mean that we cannot draw strong conclusions from these small changes; the summary should be thought of as 'no evidence of change'.

This is also the case for the results based on test scores and externalising behaviour; in the original cohorts test score inequality grew by 9 percentage points from 1969 to 1980, from 1991 to 2006 the change was around 1 percentage point and not statistically significant. There was no change in the inequality of behaviour scores by parental income from 1991 to 2006.

Taking the linear and nonlinear results together, it seems that all the large increases in educational inequality occurred between the 1958 and 1970 cohorts at the same time as the changes in intergenerational mobility. Unless changes in intergenerational mobility have been driven by very different forces in more recent years, these results suggest that we might expect to observe little change in intergenerational income mobility for the cohorts born from around 197010 onwards.

Simulations to predict changes in [beta] across more recent cohorts

In Section 2 we reviewed the relationship between [theta], the sensitivity of Z to parental income, and [beta], the intergenerational parameter of real interest. In discussing our results so far we have assumed that future patterns in [beta] for recent cohorts will mirror observed changes in [theta]. As noted in Section 2, this carries the implicit assumption that the returns to Z ([lambda]) and the direct effect of parental income on earnings ([alpha]) will remain unchanged for our more recent cohorts.

The first panel of table 7A lays out explicitly the relationship between inequality adjusted [beta], [theta], [lambda] and [alpha] for test scores for the older cohorts for whom all four parameters are observable. As noted in earlier results the substantial rise in [beta] was accompanied by an increase in the sensitivity of test scores to parental income, [theta]. It is also clear that the direct relationship between parental income and sons' earnings ([alpha]) increased over this period. This is to be expected; it means that the relationship with parental income is rising with unmeasured attributes at the same time as it is rising with measured attributes (in this case test scores).

The second panel predicts the change in [beta] between cohorts born around 1985 (the kids of the NCDS) and those born in 2000 (the MCS) using estimated [theta]s and assuming that [lamda] and ix remain at the same level as they were for the BCS. Exactly as we would expect, under these assumptions no increase in persistence is predicted, with [beta] falling slightly from 0.31 to 0.29.

In the third and fourth panels we explore the changes in [lambda] and [alpha] that would be necessary for there to be the same (annualised) change in adjusted [beta] between 1985 and 2000/2001 as there was between the 1958 and 1970 cohorts. As the gap between these cohorts is a little larger, so is the equivalent change, at 0.17. For this change to be generated entirely by increases in returns to test scores these would have to rise four-fold, an extremely unlikely scenario. For ix to generate these changes it would need to rise by 0.17, again this is unlikely, particularly over a period when there is no evidence that the relationship between parental income and test scores or behaviour increased.

Table 7b performs the same exercise considering degree attainment by age 23 as the driving mechanism behind intergenerational persistence. In this case the relevant cohorts to explore are the changes between the two BHPS periods, therefore focusing on sons born on average in 1975 and 1979. As before, if k and ix are unchanged across the cohorts then [beta] also remains unchanged.

The annualised increase equivalent to the 1958 and 1970 change is 0.04 over the four years between the two BHPS cohorts. In the third and fourth panels we once again explore the changes in k and ix that would be necessary to generate this change and find them to be implausibly large. In particular, the earnings differential associated with a degree would need to increase from 0.84 to 1.50, when in fact recent estimates show no rise in the returns to a degree among cohorts recently entering the labour market (O'Leary and Sloane, 2005).

5. Conclusion

In this paper we have presented evidence on changing patterns of intergenerational mobility for more recent cohorts of people than have previously been considered in the literature on intergenerational mobility in Britain. We think this is important as these more recent cohorts (born after 1970) are of most relevance for contemporary (and future) discussions about public policy design and implementation.

Studying more recent cohorts presents some difficult modelling issues, not least the fact that many of the cohorts we study are not yet old enough to earn an income. We thus present a modelling framework where one can, under certain assumptions, say something about more recent patterns of changing mobility. We compare and contrast the findings from this framework for the post-1970 cohorts, with results from the two earlier birth cohorts (born in 1958 and 1970) for which we have earnings data.

Our results show that the widely quoted fall in mobility experienced across the 1958 and 1970 cohorts appears to have been an episode where social mobility worsened and took a step change downwards. However, results from our more up-to-date data show that this decline is not likely to have continued. At the same time, mobility patterns have neither reversed nor started to improve and mobility appears to be set to remain at the low level seen for the 1970 cohort, at least for cohorts born up to 2000.

Data issues appendix

'Kids of' data

Our outcome measures are based on relative performance within age. For both datasets the impact of age in months within age in years is removed before converting reading/vocab test scores into percentiles within age in years. This relative measure is used in our analysis. This is useful as children of the 1970 cohort aged 3-5 are given a vocabulary test, whereas older children are tested in reading. By converting to percentiles we should have a comparable measure across all age groups. The PIAT reading score is available for all sampled children of the 1958 cohort from five onwards, and a small number of 4-year olds.

Our aim in this paper is to discover as much as possible about trends in intergenerational transmissions for recent cohorts of children. It is therefore essential to base our conclusions upon representative samples of children. The children of cohort members pose a difficulty in this regard, as while the initial sample of parents were representative of cohorts of births the children are not. In particular, the older children in the 'kids of' sample were born to younger parents, who are more likely to be more poorly educated or differ from other cohort members in other unobservable ways. In addition the pattern of this selection into fertility may be different for cohort members born in 1958 and 1970.

To evaluate this we can consider figures from Birth Statistics 2004 (ONS, 2004) which allow us to compare fertility rates of women born in 1958 and those born in 1970. By 1991 women equivalent to the 1958 cohort had given birth to 1711 children per 1000 women, while by 2004 the full cohort equivalent to the 1970 cohort had given birth to 1564 babies per 1000 women. Assuming that overall fertility is not declining across these cohorts these figures indicate that the 1970 cohort members are likely to be earlier in their child-bearing career than the 1958 cohort at the point when we observe them, despite being a year older. This indicates that it might be legitimate to compare slightly older children from the children of the 1958 cohort compared with the children of the 1970 cohort. We therefore compare 3-5 year olds from the BCS with 4-6 year olds in the NCDS and so on.

There is a further issue; as the sampling frame is co-resident natural or adoptive children of male cohort members are less likely to be included as they are more likely to live with their mothers. In fact 65 per cent of the children of the 1958 cohort who are tested are in the sample because their mother is the cohort member, while in the 1970 cohort, 68 per cent of the sample have cohort member mothers. This statistic also tends to vary by age, with the proportion of fathers much higher among younger children. We therefore concentrate on the children of female cohort members.

Appendix table 2 shows the income association for different age groups from the 'kids of' data for a range of different models. The top left panel gives the association between parental income and test scores using the OLS model. These comparisons indicate that the strength of the association between parental income and test score percentile is constant between the two 'kids of' datasets. 4-6 year old children of the 1970 cohort have a coefficient on family income in a test score regression of 5.63 compared with 5.17 for 5-7 year olds from the 1958 cohort. For slightly older children 5-7 year olds in the 1970 cohort have a coefficient of 6.05, compared with 6.38 for the next age group in the NCDS. This pattern of constancy continues up to the 6-8 age group in the 1970 cohort and the 7-9 year olds in the 1958 cohort. After this income coefficients in the BCS fall off rapidly, with an insignificant association between family income and reading score among the 8-10-year olds. Fertility statistics indicate that children of women in the BCS over eight years old would make up just one third of the births by this age.

The top-right panel presents the coefficients for the same dependent variable from a 2SLS specification; as before, income is predicted on the basis of parental education, employment and housing tenure. Once again, there is very little evidence of strong changes across the cohorts, with very similar coefficients across 1991 and 2004 for all age groups until we reach children of the 1970 cohort at age 7-9.

The lower panel shows the results for two alternative dependent variables, percentile in the maths/number tests and externalising behaviour score. The association between the maths test and parental income is lower overall than it was for reading but there is no strong evidence of changes over time. For the externalising score there is evidence of a slight decline in the association with parental income between 1991 and 2004 with the coefficient from the tobit regression at -0.2 to-0.3 in 1991 and at-0.1 to-0.2 in 2004.11

It therefore seems that comparisons of children of the 1958 cohort aged 5-7 and children of the 1970 cohort aged 4-6 might be appropriate for comparison with the MCS at age five. We now discuss the best way of using the MCS data to make these comparisons legitimate.

A further problem resulting from the design of the 'kids of' datasets is that they tend to under-represent children from ethnic minority backgrounds compared with the population. Of the NCDS cohort members whose children were tested in 1991, 98 per cent were of white British ethnic origin, of the children of the BCS 93 per cent were perceived by the interviewer to be of white British descent. As we shall see below the sampling frame for the MCS is considerably more diverse.

MCS data

The MCS data provides information on a sample if children born from 2000-1. We weight the data throughout to achieve a representative sample of children born in this period. We do not use additional weights to adjust for attrition as these are not available for the cohort datasets. As noted above, the 'kids of' are representative of children of mothers born in certain years. In order to check what difference this makes we also limit the MCS data to those children with mothers aged 33-5.

There are several ways of constructing parental income from the questions available in the MCS. The most straightforward is to use the categorical variables. Parents are asked to indicate the category that their total take-home income falls into (they are coded into weekly, monthly and annual amounts for the respondents' ease). The categories offered for the respondent to choose from vary depending on whether the child lives in a one or two parent family. We convert the categorical information into a continuous measure by treating income as the midpoint of the category stated. In addition to the categorical total income questions parents are also asked in detail about all the sources of income they have and the period to which each applies. Using these questions it is therefore possible to code up continuous net income measures (more similar to what is available in the 1991 and 2004 birth cohort surveys). We compare our results using different income variables.

The top left panel of Appendix table 3 shows the test score--standardised income relationships for all in the MCS, with the panel below showing these estimates for sample restricted on mother's age. The estimates for the full sample show that a 1 standard deviation increase in parental income is associated with a 6 percentile increase in vocab score. Estimates for the smaller sample of age 33-5 mothers are slightly lower. For the behavioural scores the opposite is true with slightly stronger effects found among the subsample. Within these comparisons we also show the effect of using income based on parents' reported category of take home income and a constructed net income measure. These alternatives make little difference to the estimated coefficient.

As noted previously, the Millennium Cohort Study was designed to reflect the UK's ethnic diversity. Indeed the over-sampling of wards with high populations from minority ethnic groups is an important reason why the data must be weighted. In the full unweighted sample 82 per cent of the sample are white while in the weighted data this rises to 87 per cent. It is clearly the case that the ethnic composition of the MCS and 'kids of' data are dissimilar and it is difficult to prove with certainty that this does not have an influence on the results. Experimenting with estimations using white children only for the MCS tends to indicate that inequalities are slightly narrowed when a less diverse group is considered. However this effect is not large enough to alter our substantive conclusions.
Appendix table 1a. Elements used to make
externalising scores in original cohorts

1958 cohort 1970 cohort age 5 1958 cohort age 11
age 7

Generally Destroys Destroys own,
 destructive belongings (d027) others, things

Squirmy, Squirmy, Squirmy, fidgety
 fidgety fidgety (d026)

Irritable Irritable (d032) Irritable,
 quick tempered
Fights other Fights with other Fights other
 children children (d028) children

Disobedient Disobedient (d038) Disobedient at home

Temper Child has temper tantrums Not available
 tantrums (d009)
 Never in last year
 Not in last month
 Not in last week
 More than once a week

Never, Does not Never, sometimes,
 sometimes, apply, applies, frequently
 frequently certainly applies

1958 cohort 1970 cohort age 10
age 7

Generally Destroys
 destructive belongings (m45)

Squirmy, Squirmy,
 fidgety fidgety (m44)

Irritable Irritable (m50)

Fights other Fights other
 children children (m46)

Disobedient Often disobedient (m56)

Temper Not available
 tantrums

Never, Answers are given on a 1-100
 sometimes, scale, and recoded to give
 frequently proportions in 'frequently,
 sometimes, never' to match
 NCDS at 11.

Appendix table 1b. Elements used to make
externalising scores in more recent cohorts

Kids of 1958 Kids of 1958
cohort aged 4-6 cohort aged 7+ Kids of 1970 cohort

Restless or Restless, has Restless,
 overly active difficulty staying overactive over
 (n518219) seated long past 6 months
 (n518345) (qlb)

Stubborn, sullen Irritable and is Temper tantrums
 or irritable quick to 'fly off in last 2
 (n518330) the handle' months (qle)
 (n518352)

Bullies or is Bullies Child often had
 cruel to other other children fights or bullied
 children (n518362) other children in
 (n518321) past 6 months
 (qll)

Disobedient Often disobedient Child has been
 at home (n518357) generally obedient
 (n518329) over past 6 months
 (qlg)

Not true, Does not apply, Not true,
 sometimes true, applies somewhat, somewhat true,
 often true certainly applies certainly true

Kids of 1958
cohort aged 4-6 MCS age 5

Restless or Restless,
 overly active overly active,
 (n518219) cannot stay
 still (cmsdro)

Stubborn, sullen Often has temper
 or irritable tantrums (cmsdtt)
 (n518330)

Bullies or is Fights with
 cruel to other or bullies other
 children children (cmsdfb)
 (n518321)

Disobedient Child is generally
 at home obedient
 (n518329) (cmsdor)

Not true, Not true,
 sometimes true, somewhat true,
 often true certainly true

Appendix table 2. Relationship between test scores
and income for different age groups of 'Kids of
female cohort

 Kids of cohort members
 Income coefficients from
 regression of percentile
 of reading/vocab tests--OLS
Age 1991 2004
group 1958 cohort 1970 cohort

3-5 5.69 (1.37) [567]
4-6 1.93 (1.97) [277] 5.63 (1.31) [541]
5-7 5.17 (1.66) [384] 6.05 (1.31) [579]
6-8 6.38 (1.65) [355] 3.74 (1.38) [517]
7-9 5.95 (1.79) [328] 1.00 (1.46) [4931
8-10 5.58 (1.73) [335] -0.34 (1.54) [430]

 Income
 coefficients
 from of regression of
Age number test percentile
group 1958 cohort 1970 cohort

3-5 4.15 (1.38) [566]
4-6 3.13 (1.95) [281] 3.09 (1.33) [541]
5-7 5.12 (1.65) [387] 3.06 (1.33) [579]
6-8 3.28 (1.66) [3581 1.86 (1.40) [515]
7-9 2.06 (1.82) [329] 0.90 (1.47) [493]
8-10 1.99 (1.75) [335] 2.10 (1.55) [428]

 Income coefficients from
 regression of percentile
 of reading/vocab tests--2SLS
Age 1991 2004
group 1958 cohort 1970 cohort

3-5 7.70 (1.86) [567]
4-6 5.90 (2.42) [277] 7.99 (1.65) [541]
5-7 7.72 (1.98) [384] 7.60 (1.83) [5791
6-8 8.24 (1.92) [3551 6.30 (1.99) [517]
7-9 9.04 (2.08) [329] 3.12 (2.09) [493]
8-10 7.58 (2.02) [335] 4.06 (2.17) [430]

 Income coefficients from tobit model of
Age externalising behaviour
group 1958 cohort 1970 cohort

3-5 -0.11 (0.05) [571]
4-6 -0.14 (0.07) [346] -0.16 (0.06) [545]
5-7 -0.26 (0.07) [366] -0.17 (0.06) [574]
6-8 -0.37 (0.07) [335] -0.16 (0.06) [510]
7-9 -0.39 (0.07) [307] -0.14 (0.06) [486]
8-10 -0.20 (0.07) [301] -0.20 (0.07) [430]

Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis. Sample sizes
in square brackets.

All regressions include controls for the child's sex,
the cohort member's partner's age and a polynomial
in the child's age in days at testing.

Appendix table 3. Relationship between test
scores and parental income in MCS

 In (income) coefficients in regression
Year of vocab score percentile 2006

Sample MCS kids aged 5 MCS kids aged 5

Income Midpoint Continuous
measure of income net income
 category

OLS 6.03 (0.31) 5.87 (0.32)
coefficient

2SLS 12.33 (0.46) 13.83 (0.54)
coefficient

Sample 13448 13448

 Mums 33-35 years old
 In (income)
 coefficient in
 regression of vocab
 score percentile

Year 2006 2006

Sample MCS kids aged 5 MCS kids aged 5

Income Midpoint Continuous
measure of income net income
 category

OLS 6.83 5.66
coefficient

2SLS 12.93 13.91
coefficient

Sample 2661 2661

 In (income) coefficient in regression
 of externalising score

Year 2006 2006

Sample MCS kids aged 5 MCS kids aged 5

Income Midpoint Continuous
measure of income net income
 category

OLS -0.18 (0.01) -0.16 (0.01)
coefficient

2SLS -0.38 (0.02) -0.42 (0.02)
coefficient

Sample 13003 13003

 In(income) regression
 coefficient in
 of externalising
 score

Year 2006 2006

Sample MCS kids aged 5 MCS kids aged 5

Income Midpoint Continuous
measure of income net income
 category

OLS -0.20 (0.03) -0.18 (0.03)
coefficient

2SLS -0.34 (0.04) -0.39 (0.05)
coefficient

Sample 2585 2585

Notes: Standard errors in parenthesis. All regressions
include controls for the child's sex, parents' age and
a polynomial in the child's age in days at testing.
Income variables are standardised. The results for the
MCS sample are limited to those who have valid
observations for both income variables. Results change
only slightly if this restriction is lifted. As weights
are required we use a regression model for the
behavioural models rather than the preferred tobit
model.


REFERENCES

Altonji, J., Bharaduraj, P. and Lange, F. (2008), 'Changes in the characteristics of American youth: implications for adult outcomes', NBER Working Paper No. 13883.

Blanden, J. (2008), 'Intergenerational income mobility in a comparative perspective', in Dolton, P., Asplund, R. and Barth, E., Education and Inequality Across Europe, Edward Edgar (forthcoming).

Blanden, J., Goodman, A., Gregg, P. and Machin, S. (2004), 'Changes in intergenerational income mobility in Britain', in Corak, M. (ed.), Generational Income Mobility in North America and Europe, Cambridge, MA, Cambridge University Press.

Blanden, J., Gregg, P. and Macmillan, L. (2007), 'Accounting for intergenerational income persistence: noncognitive skills, ability and education', Economic Journal, 117, C43-C60.

Blanden, J. and Machin, S. (2004), 'Inequality in the expansion of higher education', Scottish Journal of Political Economy Special Issue on Education, 51, pp. 230-49.

Carneiro, P. and Heckman, J. (2003), 'Human capital policy', in Heckman, J. and Krueger, A. (eds), Inequality in America: What Role for Human Capital Policies, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.

DiNarclo, J., Fortin, N. and Lemieux, T. (1996), 'Labour market institutions and the distributions of wages, 1973-1992: a semiparametric approach', Econometrica, 64, pp. 1001-44.

Ermisch, J. and Nicoletti, C. (2007), 'Intergenerational earnings mobility: changes across cohorts in Britain', B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 7, 2 (Contributions) Article 9.

Feinstein, L. (2003), 'Inequality in the early cognitive development of British children in the 1970 cohort', Economica, 70, pp. 7398.

Haider, S. and Solon, G. (2006), 'Lifecycle variation in the association between current and lifetime earnings', American Economic Review, 96, pp. 1308-20.

Heckman, J., Stixrud, J. and Urzua, S. (2006), 'The effects of cognitive and noncognitive abilities on labour market outcomes and social behaviour',Journal of Labour Economics, 24, pp. 411-82.

Mazumder, B. (2001), 'Earnings mobility in the US: a new look at intergenerational mobility', Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper 2001-18.

--(2005), 'Fortunate sons: new estimates of intergenerational mobility in the United States using social security earnings data', The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87, pp. 235-55,

Office for National Statistics (2004), Birth Statistics available at http ://www.statistics.gov.uk/downloads/theme_population/ FM 1_33/FM 1_33.pdf.

O'Leary, N. and Sloane, P. (2005), 'The changing wage return to an undergraduate education', IZA Discussion Paper No. 1549.

Rutter, M., Tizard, J. and Whitmore, K. (1970), Education, Health and Behaviour, London, Longman.

Solon, G. (1989), 'Biases in the estimation of intergenerational earnings correlations', Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, pp. 172-74.

--(1992), 'Intergenerational income mobility in the United States', American Economic Review, 82, pp. 383-408.

Zimmerman, D. (1992), 'Regression toward mediocrity in economic stature', American Economic Review, 82, pp. 409-29.

NOTES

(1) The same requirement is obviously true for mobility measured in terms of social class as well.

(2) Using the British Household Panel Survey, Ermisch and Nicoletti (2007) find evidence of a rise in the intergenerational elasticity over a similar period although less evidence of change based on the intergenerational correlation.

(3) A similar decomposition approach is used in Blanden et al. 2007; in that paper an extensive set of Zs are used to account as much of [beta] as possible.

(4) Some of the older individuals used in our BHPS have earnings recorded in the data and could therefore be used to estimate intergenerational earnings mobility. We do not report these as intergenerational regressions on very young samples lead to [beta]s that are strongly downward biased.

(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]

(6) Note that the figures presented here for the 1970 cohort differ from those in Blanden et al. (2005 and 2007) because we are now using the most up-to-date earnings information.

(7) It should be noted that sample sizes for the 'kids off and BHPS are rather smaller than those for the original cohorts. We are therefore not able to be as accurate in our estimates as is made clear by the larger reported standard errors.

(8) It is the case that the 2SLS for the MCS show a rise in the association between income and test scores compared to the 'kids of' data. We are reluctant to make too much of this as this appears to be an outlying estimate.

(9) If income is not standardised the test score income coefficients (and standard errors) are 8.44 (2.71) for the kids of the NCDS, 8.79 (2.05) for the kids of the BCS and 5.95 (0.84) for the MCS. The relative difference between the MCS and other two cohorts appears to be generated by the wider distribution of income in these data.

(10) Note that our data do not allow us to pinpoint precisely when the fall in mobility stopped.

(11) Additional results experimenting with non-standardised income, using children of all cohort members and income equivalising are available on request.

Jo Blanden * and Stephen Machin **

* Department of Economics, University of Surrey and Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics. e- mail: J.Blanden@surrey.ac.uk. ** Department of Economics, University College London and Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics. e-mail: s.machin@ucl.ac.uk. This project was generously supported by the Sutton Trust. We would also like to thank Richard Murphy, Elizabeth Jones, Kirstine Hansen and Rachel Rosenberg for help with the data.
Table 1a. Intergenerational income mobility transition
matrix for the 1958 cohort

 Sons' quartile

Parental Lowest 2nd
income quartile quartile

Lowest quartile 0.30 0.29
2nd quartile 0.31 0.27
3rd quartile 0.22 0.25
Top quartile 0.18 0.20

 Sons' quartile

Parental 3rd Top
income quartile quartile

Lowest quartile 0.24 0.18
2nd quartile 0.24 0.19
3rd quartile 0.25 0.28
Top quartile 0.27 0.35

Notes: Sample size 2163; Immobility Index 2.81.

Table 1b. Intergenerational income mobility transition
matrix for the 1970 cohort

 Sons' quartile

Parental Lowest 2nd
income quartile quartile

Lowest quartile 0.37 0.27
2nd quartile 0.29 0.30
3rd quartile 0.22 0.25
Top quartile 0.13 0.18

 Sons' quartile

Parental 3rd Top
income quartile quartile

Lowest quartile 0.22 0.13
2nd quartile 0.24 0.17
3rd quartile 0.28 0.25
Top quartile 0.24 0.45

Notes: Sample size 1703; Immobility index 2.96.

Table 2. Linear estimates of intergenerational income
persistence

 Intergenerational
 elasticities, [beta]
 Parental income to
 child's earnings

 1991 2004
 (1958 cohort, (1970 cohort
 age 33) age 34)

A. Sons
OLS 0.21 0.33
 (0.03) (0.03)
2SLS 0.33 0.50
 (0.04) (0.05)

B. Daughters
OILS 0.36 0.43
 (0.05) (0.05)
2SLS 0.55 0.63
 (0.08) (0.07)

 Intergenerational partial
 correlations Parental
 income to child's earnings

 1991 2004
 (1958 cohort, (1970 cohort
 age 33) age 34)

A. Sons
OLS 0.17 0.30
 (0.02) (0.02)
2SLS 0.27 0.45
 (0.04) (0.04)

B. Daughters
OILS 0.17 0.25
 (0.02) (0.02)
2SLS 0.26 0.37
 (0.04) (0.04)

 Cross-cohort
 change in
 inequality
 adjusted
 [beta]

A. Sons
OLS 0.13
 (0.03)
2SLS 0.18
 (0.05)

B. Daughters
OILS 0.08
 (0.03)
2SLS 0.11
 (0.06)

Notes: The OILS regressions include controls for
parental age. Instrumental variables used are mother's
and father's education, employment status and housing
tenure at age 16. Sample sizes are 2163 for the 1958
cohort and 1703 for the 1970 cohort.

Table 3. Associations between intermediate outcomes
and parental income in the cohorts

 Standardised log(income)
 sensitivities, [theta]

 1958 1970
 cohort cohort

Degree by age 23, OLS 0.05 0.11
 (0.01) (0.01)
Degree by age 23, 2SLS 0.07 0.19
 (0.02) (0.01)
Test Scores (age 11, 1958 5.65 8.72
cohort; age 10, 1970 cohort), OLS (0.32) (0.37)

Test Scores (age 11, 1958 11.89 15.93
cohort; age 10, 1970 cohort), 2SLS (0.56) (0.64)

Behavioural (age 11, 1958 -0.06 -0.12
cohort; age 10, 1970 cohort), OLS (0.01) (0.02)

Behavioural (age 11, 1958 cohort; -0.1 -0.18
age 10, 1970 cohort), 2SLS (0.02) (0.02)

Behavioural (age 7, 1958 cohort; -0.06 -0.15
age 5, 1970 cohort), OLS (0.01) (0.02)

Behavioural (age 7, 1958 cohort; -0.13 -0.22
age 5, 1970 cohort), 2SLS (0.02) (0.02)

 Standardised log(income)
 sensitivities, [theta]

 Cross-
 cohort
 change
 in [theta]

Degree by age 23, OLS 0.06
 (0.01)
Degree by age 23, 2SLS 0.12
 (0.01)
Test Scores (age 11, 1958 3.07
cohort; age 10, 1970 cohort), OLS (0.49)

Test Scores (age 11, 1958 4.04
cohort; age 10, 1970 cohort), 2SLS (0.85)

Behavioural (age 11, 1958 -0.06
cohort; age 10, 1970 cohort), OLS (0.02)

Behavioural (age 11, 1958 cohort; -0.08
age 10, 1970 cohort), 2SLS (0.03)

Behavioural (age 7, 1958 cohort; -0.09
age 5, 1970 cohort), OLS (0.02)

Behavioural (age 7, 1958 cohort; -0.09
age 5, 1970 cohort), 2SLS (0.03)

Notes: OLS estimates conditional on parental age and
the sex of the child. Instrumental variables used are
mother's and father's education, employment status and
housing tenure at age 16. The degree coefficients are
estimated using a linear probability model, although
marginal effects from a probit model are almost identical.
The behavioural score models are fitted using a tobit
as in all cases around 15% of cases have the lowest
score. Parental income data is standardised to have
mean 0 and standard deviation 1. Sample sizes: Panel
1: 7233; 4706. Panel 2: 7766; 5983. Panel 3: 7580; 6296.
Panel 4: 7709; 5616.

Table 4. Inequalities in intermediate outcomes by
parental income in the cohorts

 Lowest 20%
 of family
 income

Degree 1981 (1958 cohort age 23) 0.05
 acquisition 1993 (1970 cohort age 23) 0.07
Cross-cohort
 change

Test score 1969 (1958 cohort age 11) 42.59
 percentile 1980 (1970 cohort age 10) 38.12
Cross-cohort
 change

Externalising 1969 (1958 cohort age 11) 0.042
 behaviour
 score 1980 (1970 cohort age 10) 0.15
Cross-cohort
 change

Externalising 1965 (1958 cohort age 7) 0.06
 behaviour
 score 1975 (1970 cohort age 5) 0.20
Cross-cohort
 change

 Middle 60%
 of family
 income

Degree 1981 (1958 cohort age 23) 0.08
 acquisition 1993 (1970 cohort age 23) 0.15
Cross-cohort
 change

Test score 1969 (1958 cohort age 11) 49.16
 percentile 1980 (1970 cohort age 10) 50.35
Cross-cohort
 change

Externalising 1969 (1958 cohort age 11) 0.03
 behaviour
 score 1980 (1970 cohort age 10) -0.033
Cross-cohort
 change

Externalising 1965 (1958 cohort age 7) 0.03
 behaviour
 score 1975 (1970 cohort age 5) -0.04
Cross-cohort
 change

 Highest 20%
 of family
 income

Degree 1981 (1958 cohort age 23) 0.20
 acquisition 1993 (1970 cohort age 23) 0.37
Cross-cohort
 change

Test score 1969 (1958 cohort age 11) 58.81
 percentile 1980 (1970 cohort age 10) 63.44
Cross-cohort
 change

Externalising 1969 (1958 cohort age 11) -0.11
 behaviour
 score 1980 (1970 cohort age 10) -0.18
Cross-cohort
 change

Externalising 1965 (1958 cohort age 7) -0.11
 behaviour
 score 1975 (1970 cohort age 5) -0.2
Cross-cohort
 change

 Inequality

Degree 1981 (1958 cohort age 23) 0.15 (0.01)
 acquisition 1993 (1970 cohort age 23) 0.30 (0.05)
Cross-cohort 0.15 (0.02)
 change

Test score 1969 (1958 cohort age 11) 16.22 (1.05)
 percentile 1980 (1970 cohort age 10) 25.32 (1.10)
Cross-cohort 9.10 (1.51)
 change

Externalising 1969 (1958 cohort age 11) -0.15 (0.03)
 behaviour
 score 1980 (1970 cohort age 10) -0.33 (0.04)
Cross-cohort -0.19 (0.05)
 change

Externalising 1965 (1958 cohort age 7) -0.16 (0.04)
 behaviour
 score 1975 (1970 cohort age 5) -0.40 (0.04)
Cross-cohort
 change -0.24 (0.06)

Notes: Sample sizes are as for table 3. Standard
errors are in parentheses.

Table 5. Associations between intermediate outcomes and
parental income in more recent cohorts

 Standardised log (income)
 sentivities, ([theta])

 1970 Cohort BHPS
 (age 23 (age 23
 in 1993) in 1999)
Degree by
 age 23, OLS 0.11 (0.01) 0.10 (0.02)
Degree by
 age 23, 2SLS 0.19 (0.01) 0.23 (0.04)

 Standardised log (income)
 sentivities, ([theta])

 BHPS Cross-cohort
 (age 23 change
 in 2003) in [theta]
Degree by
 age 23, OLS 0.09 (0.02) -0.02 (0.02)
Degree by
 age 23, 2SLS 0.19 (0.04) 0.00 (0.04)

 Standardised log (income)
 sentivities, ([theta])

 Kids of 1958 Kids of 1970
 cohort cohort
 (aged 5-7 (aged 4-6
 in 1991) in 2004)

Test Scores, OLS 5.17 (1.66) 5.63 (1.31)
Test Scores, 2SLS 7.72 (l.98) 7.99 (1.65)
Behavioural, OLS -0.21 (0.06) -0.14 (0.04)
Behavioural, 2SLS -0.29 (0.07) -0.28 (0.06)

 Standardised log (income)
 sentivities, ([theta])

 MCS (aged Cross-
 5 in 2006) cohort
 comparable change in 0,
 1991-2006

Test Scores, OLS 5.66 (0.80) 0.49 (1.83)
Test Scores, 2SLS 13.91 (1.28) 5.59 (2.55)
Behavioural, OLS -0.18 (0.03) 0.03 (0.07)
Behavioural, 2SLS -0.39 (0.05) -0.10 (0.09)

Notes: OLS estimates condition on parental age and the sex of the
child. Instrumental variables used are mother's and father's
education, employment status and housing tenure at the time the
income variable is observed. Standard errors are displayed in
parentheses. The degree coefficients are estimated using a linear
probability model. As it is necessary to weight the MCS data we
report regression models for the behavioural scores. Tobit models
for the 'kids of data can be found in the Appendix. 'Kids of are
restricted to the children of female cohort members. Sample sizes
from left to right: Panel I: 4706; 725; 363. Panel 2: 384, 541,
2661. Panel 3: 366, 545, 2585.

Table 6. Inequalities in intermediate outcomes by
parental income in more recent cohorts

 Lowest 20% Middle 60%
 of family of family
 income income

Degree 1993 (1970 cohort age 23) 0.07 0.15
acquisition 1999 (BHPS age 23) 0.11 0.23
 2003 (BHPS age 23) 0.10 0.21

Cross-cohort change (1993-2002)

Test scores 1991 ('Kids of 1958
 cohort age 5-7) 38.39 52.84
 2004 ('Kids of 1970
 cohort aged 4-6) 40.76 50.86
 2006 (MCS comparable
 age 5) 38.96 48.75

Cross-cohort change (1991-2006)

Behavioural 1991 ('Kids of 1958
 cohort age 5-7) 0.29 0.06
 2004 ('Kids of 1970
 cohort aged 4-6) 0.21 -0.09
 2006 (MCS comparable) 0.20 -0.07

Cross-cohort change (1991-2006)

 Highest 20%
 of family
 income Inequality

Degree 1993 (1970 cohort age 23) 0.34 0.30 (0.01)
acquisition 1999 (BHPS age 23) 0.40 0.30 (0.05)
 2003 (BHPS age 23) 0.44 0.34 (0.05)

Cross-cohort change (1993-2002) 0.04 (0.07)

Test scores 1991 ('Kids of 1958
 cohort age 5-7) 52.74 14.35 (4.73)
 2004 ('Kids of 1970
 cohort aged 4-6) 56.00 15.24 (3.92)
 2006 (MCS comparable
 age 5) 55.61 16.65 (1.98)

Cross-cohort change (1991-2006) 2.30 (5.13)

Behavioural 1991 ('Kids of 1958
 cohort age 5-7) -0.21 -0.50 (0.13)
 2004 ('Kids of 1970
 cohort aged 4-6) -0.14 -0.34 (0.14)
 2006 (MCS comparable) -0.32 -0.52 (0.07)

Cross-cohort change (1991-2006) -0.01 (0.15)

Notes: MCS data is weighted using longitudinal weights.
Sample sizes are as for table 5. Standard errors are
provided in parentheses.

Table 7a. Simulations based on test score
sensitivities for sons
 Cross-
 cohort
 [theta], [lambda] change in
 and [alpha] [beta] [beta]

Older cohorts--actual changes when can
estimate [theta], [lambda] and [alpha]

NCDS 1958 [theta] = 3.29, 0.17
 [lambda] = 0.01,
 [alpha] = 0.13

BCS 1970 [theta] = 6.86, 0.30 0.13
 [lambda] = 0.01,
 [alpha] = 0.23

Younger cohorts--simulate changes
when can estimate [theta] (Keep [lambda]
and [alpha] at BCS 1970 values)

Kids of [theta] = 7.48, 0.31
NCDS, 1985 [lambda] = 0.01,
 [alpha] = 0.23

MCS, 2001 [theta] = 5.63, 0.29 0.02
 [lambda] = 0.01,
 [alpha] = 0.23

Younger cohorts--simulate changes
when can estimate [theta] (change
[lambda] so that [beta] rises
by 0.17)(a)

Kids of [theta] = 7.48, 0.31
NCDS, 1985 [lambda] = 0.01,
 [alpha] = 0.23

MCS, 2001 [theta] = 5.63, 0.48 0.17
 [lambda] = 0.04,
 [alpha] = 0.23

Younger cohorts--simulate changes
when can estimate [theta] (change
[alpha] so that [beta] rises
by 0.17)((a)

Kids of NCDS, 1985 [theta] = 7.48, 0.310 0.17
 [lambda] = 0.01,
 [alpha] = 0.23

MCS, 2001 [theta] = 5.63,
 [lambda] = 0.01,
 [alpha] = 0.40

Note: (a) 0.17 is the annualised change between the 1985 and 2001
cohorts that would be equivalent to the 0.13 increase across the
1958 and 1960 cohorts.

Table 7b. Simulations based on degree
attainment sensitivites for sons
 Cross-
 [theta], cohort
 [lambda] change
 and [alpha] [beta] in R

Older cohorts--actual changes when can
estimate [theta], [lambda] and [alpha]

NCDS 1958 [theta] = 0.04, 0.17
 [lambda] = 0.72,
 [alpha] 0.14

BCS 1970 [theta] = 0.09, 0.30 0.13
 [lambda] = 0.84,
 [alpha] = 0.22

Younger cohorts--simulate changes
when can estimate [theta] (Keep [lambda]
and [alpha] at BCS 1970 values)

BHPS 1976 [theta] = 0.10, 0.31
 [lambda] = 0.84,
 [alpha] = 0.22

BHPS 1980 [theta] = 0.09, 0.30 -0.01
 [lambda] = 0.84,
 [alpha] = 0.22

Younger cohorts--simulate changes when
can estimate [theta] (change [lambda]
so that [beta] rises by 0.04)(a)

BHPS 1976 [theta] = 0.100, 0.31
 [lambda] = 0.84,
 [alpha] = 0.22

BHPS 1980 [theta] = 0.087, 0.35 0.04
 [lambda] = 1.49,
 [alpha] = 0.22

Younger cohorts--simulate changes when
can estimate [beta] (change [lambda] so
that [beta] rises by 0.04)(a)

BHPS 1976 [theta] = 0.10, 0.31
 [lambda] = 0.84,
 [alpha] = 0.22

BHPS 1980 [theta] = 0.09, 0.35 0.04
 [lambda] = 0.84,
 [alpha] = 0.28

Note: (a) 0.04 is the annualised change between the
1976 and 1980 cohorts that would be equivalent to
the 0.13 increase across the 1958 and 1970 cohorts.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有