Does offshoring reduce industry employment?
Hijzen, Alexander ; Swaim, Paul
This paper looks at the implications of offshoring for industry
employment whilst explicitly accounting for the scale and technology
effects of offshoring. The effects of offshoring on employment are
analysed using industry-level data for 17 high income OECD countries.
Our findings indicate that offshoring has no effect or a slight positive
effect on sectoral employment. Offshoring within the same industry
(intra-industry offshoring) reduces the labour-intensity of production,
but does not affect overall industry employment. Inter-industry
offshoring does not affect labour-intensity, but may have a positive
effect on overall industry employment. These findings suggest that the
productivity gains from offshoring are sufficiently large that the jobs
created by higher sales completely offset the jobs lost by relocating
certain production stages to foreign production sites.
Keywords: International outsourcing; labour demand JEL
Classification: F16
I. Introduction
In recent years, offshoring has become one of the most
controversial economic issues in the public debate. This is clearly
illustrated by the flurry in the US media that followed the publication
of the Economic Report of the President in February 2004 (Mankiw and
Swagel, 2006). Another example is the French no-vote in the referendum on the EU Constitution, which according to the Eurobarometer opinion
poll, reflects to an important extent concerns about job losses due to
the relocation of production to low-wage countries (European Commission,
2005). While offshoring represents no doubt one of the main
distinguishing characteristics of the current stage of globalisation,
its implications for workers, and in particular, for their jobs, are
subject to considerable controversy. It is often felt that whilst
offshoring leads to important gains to producers and consumers, the
costs appear to fall disproportionately on workers, especially those
with low levels of skills.
This paper looks at the implications of offshoring for workers in
terms of their employment opportunities at the sectoral level. In the
present paper offshoring refers to the relocation abroad of tasks that
were previously performed at home and the products of which are
subsequently shipped back home in the form of imported intermediate
inputs. Classical examples of offshoring include the manufacture of
apparel and toys in China (e.g. Toys R Us develops a toy design, the
production of which is sourced to China and imported back for final
packaging and marketing) and the production of car components in Taiwan.
An important element of the analysis is to account explicitly for
the technology and scale effects of offshoring. The technology effect
reflects the destruction of jobs that occurs when firms relocate part of
their production activities overseas. By contrast, the scale effect
captures the creation of jobs following the expansion in industry output
that may arise as a result of the productivity gains from offshoring.
(1)
In order to analyse the employment effects of offshoring in a first
step, we propose a novel decomposition of employment that allows one to
identify the scale and technology effects separately. We subsequently
use this decomposition to relate changes in offshoring intensity to the
scale and technology components of sectoral employment changes. In the
second step, we conduct a detailed econometric analysis of the scale and
technology effects of offshoring for industry employment using sectoral
data for seventeen high income OECD countries.
Our findings indicate that offshoring has no effect or a slight
positive effect on sectoral employment, which is broadly consistent with
previous findings by Amiti and Wei (2005, 2006) for the United States.
More specifically, our results indicate that while offshoring within the
same industry (intra-industry offshoring) reduces the labour-intensity
of production, it does not affect overall industry employment.
Inter-industry offshoring does not affect labour-intensity, but may have
a positive effect on overall industry employment. These findings suggest
that the productivity gains from offshoring are sufficiently large that
the jobs created by higher sales completely offset the jobs lost by
relocating certain production stages to foreign production sites.
The structure of this paper is as follows. Section 2 discusses data
and measurement issues in relation to offshoring and describes the trend
in offshoring across a number of OECD countries. Section 3 provides a
first look at the possible effects of offshoring on industry employment.
Section 4 sets outs the econometric methodology, while Section 5
discusses the results. Section 6 reports a number of robustness checks
that were undertaken to assess the sensitivity of our core results to
the exclusion of outliers and the way one controls for technological
change. Finally, Section 7 concludes.
2. Data and trends
2.1 Data and measurement
Measuring offshoring is not straightforward. Typically, efforts
have focussed on trade in intermediates in one way or another. The main
drawback of focusing on trade in intermediates is that one necessarily
excludes the offshoring of assembly activities. However, direct data on
the value of offshoring are typically not available, and if they are,
they are unlikely to be suitable for empirical work. In line with most
previous work we will therefore also focus on trade in intermediates.
Several different data sources have been used to document trade in
intermediates including data on outward processing trade (similar
concepts are 'foreign trade zones' or 'overseas assembly
programmes'), standard trade statistics and input-output tables.
Data on outward processing trade are based on the customs arrangement in
which complete tariff exemptions or partial levy reductions are granted
in accordance with the domestic input content of imported goods. Outward
processing trade involves the exporting of intermediate inputs for
further processing abroad and the reimporting of those products back to
the home country. The product classification of trade statistics can
also be used to infer how much trade in intermediate goods affects the
nature of world trade. For analytical purposes input-output tables are
usually considered to be the most appropriate data source as they allow
one to make comparisons across sectors, countries and time.
The input-output data used in this paper are obtained from the 2006
edition of the OECD's Input-output Database. Input-output tables
describe the sale and purchase relationships between producers and
consumers within an economy. (2) As such, they allow one to measure
intermediate input purchases by each industry from each industry. The
tables further distinguish between domestically supplied intermediate
inputs and inputs imported from abroad via the so-called domestic-use
and import-use matrices. (3)
Broadly speaking, we measure offshoring by focusing on the foreign
content of production using the ratio of imported intermediates (using
the import-use matrix) to value-added. More specifically, we define two
measures of offshoring: intra-industry and inter-industry offshoring.
Intra-industry offshoring ('narrow offshoring' in Feenstra and
Hanson, 1999), measures the share of imported intermediate inputs from
the same industry in industry value-added. (4) Formally, and suppressing
the country and time subscripts for simplicity, narrow offshoring
[S.sup.N] for industry i is given by:
[S.sup.N.sub.i] = [O.sub.j=i]/[V.sub.i] (1)
where O refers to imported intermediate purchases from industry j =
i by industry i, and V to value-added. Compared to total offshoring, the
measure of intra-industry offshoring is likely to come closer to the
essence of relocation, which tends to take place within the same
industry. (5) Inter-industry offshoring SD is defined as the ratio of
imported intermediate purchases by industry i from all industries j
other than i to value-added:
[S.sup.D.sub.i] = [J.summation over (i=1)] [O.sub.j[not equal
to]i]/[V.sub.i] (2)
where O refers to imported intermediate purchases from industry j
[not equal to] i by industry i and V to value- added.
The input-output data are combined with sectoral production data
from the OECD STAN database and data on R&D expenditure from the
OECD ANBERD dataset. As the input-output tables are available only for
the years 1995 and 2000, the dataset is necessarily constrained to those
two years. The dataset used for the empirical analysis of this paper
includes the following countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium &
Luxembourg, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy,
the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, the United Kingdom and
the United States. The industrial classification broadly follows that
used in the OECD STAN database, which is based on the International
Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC), Rev 3. The agriculture and
mining industries (ISIC 0114) were excluded from the analysis. (6)
2.2 Stylised facts
There is considerable evidence that offshoring has been increasing
for several decades. Campa and Goldberg (1997) document offshoring using
a similar measure to that employed in the present paper. They show that
this measure of offshoring rose from 4 per cent in 1974 to 8 per cent in
1993 in the United States, from 16 per cent to 20 per cent in Canada and
from 13 per cent to 22 per cent in the United Kingdom, but fell from 8
per cent to 4 per cent in Japan. Hummels et al. (2001) focus on a
narrower concept, the foreign content of exports (or 'vertical
specialisation'), which is measured by the share of imported
intermediates in exports. They find that vertical specialisation
increased by 28 per cent between 1970 and 1990 in fourteen countries and
that this increase accounted for 30 per cent of total export growth for
these countries.
Figure 1 presents more recent statistics for the foreign content of
production for seventeen OECD countries using the OECD Input-output data
for 1995 and 2000. (7) The data on offshoring confirm that imported
inputs constitute a prominent feature in production in OECD economies,
although the degree of offshoring varies significantly across these
countries. (8) Between 1995 and 2000, offshoring grew in fifteen out of
seventeen of those countries, but often by only a small amount. (9)
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
3. A first look
In order to analyse the employment effects of offshoring one needs
to account for both its technology and its scale effect. The technology
effect reflects the destruction of jobs that occurs when firms relocate
part of their production activities overseas. By contrast, the scale
effect captures the creation of jobs following the expansion in industry
output as a result of the productivity gains from offshoring. In order
to render this more explicit we propose the following decomposition of
the change in sectoral employment:
[DELTA]L = [DELTA]l[bar.Y] + [bar.l] [DELTA]Y (3)
where L refers to employment in sector i, I to the labour intensity
(L/Y), and Y to gross output; bars refer to period averages. Thus, the
change in sectoral employment consists of the change in labour intensity
at constant output plus the change in output at constant labour
intensity. Offshoring is expected to reduce the first component via its
technology effect, but increase the second component through its scale
effect. The total effect of offshoring is therefore ambiguous.
The relative importance of both effects however may depend on the
nature of offshoring, i.e. whether intermediate inputs are imported from
the same industry or from different industries. To the extent that
imports from the same industry are more likely to replace activities
previously conducted in the same domestic industry than imports from
other industries, one would expect intra-industry offshoring to have a
more pronounced negative effect on labour-intensity than inter-industry
offshoring. By contrast, there seems to be no reason for the scale
effect to depend on the industry from which the intermediate inputs are
purchased.
In order to get a first idea of the role of technology and scale
effects, figure 2 plots the change in intra-industry and inter-industry
offshoring against the change in labour-intensity and gross output. The
scatter plots are generally consistent with the hypotheses set out
above. In particular, both types of offshoring are associated with
declining levels of labour-intensity via the technology effect and
positive output growth through the scale effect. Moreover, all the
correlations are statistically significant at the 5 per cent level.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The correlations provide mixed evidence that the sectoral origin of
intermediate imports matters. The negative correlation between the
change in intra-industry offshoring and the change in labour-intensity
is weaker than that between inter-industry offshoring and labour
intensity (-0.21 versus -0.60 respectively). This suggests that the
technology effect of inter-industry offshoring is more pronounced than
that associated with intra-industry offshoring, contrary to what one
would expect. The positive correlation between intra-industry offshoring
and output is also weaker than that for inter-industry offshoring, which
suggests that the productivity gains associated with the latter tend to
be more pronounced. However, bivariate correlations like those presented
in figure 2 do not control for other relevant industry characteristics
that may obscure the scale and technology effects, especially in the
case of intra-industry offshoring where within-sample variation is quite
limited. Econometric analysis allows one to study the employment effects
of offshoring conditional on industry characteristics and this is what
we will turn to next.
4. Econometric methodology
In order to study the impact of offshoring on industry employment
in more detail, we estimate two models of labour demand: the conditional
and unconditional labour-demand models. In the conditional model, the
profit-maximising level of labour demand is determined by minimising the
costs of production conditional on output. More specifically, industry
i's production costs [C.sub.i]([w.sub.i], [x.sub.i]) are a function
of factor prices w (for the variable factors), and output x. By
Shephard's lemma, the partial derivatives of the cost function with
respect to variable factor prices give factor demands. The conditional
model of labour demand thus allows one to assess the technology effect
of offshoring by keeping output constant.
In the unconditional labour-demand model, it is assumed that firms
maximise profits, [[PI].sub.i]([w.sub.i], [p.sub.i]), by choosing the
optimal mix of input quantities and the level of output for given input
and output prices. The profit maximising quantity of factor demand is
obtained by setting the partial derivative of profits to zero. In the
case of labour demand, this corresponds to adjusting hiring so that the
marginal value product of labour equals the wage. The unconditional
model of labour demand thus allows one to analyse the total effect of
offshoring on labour demand. The difference between the total effect and
the technology effect gives an indication of the scale effect associated
with offshoring.
In order to study sectoral labour demand, the log-linear model of
conditional and unconditional labour demand is employed (Hamermesh,
1993). This has the advantage that the coefficients can be interpreted
as elasticities. As is common in the literature, capital is treated as
quasi-fixed (see for example Berman et al., 1994). There are at least
two reasons for doing so. First, this avoids measurement problems
related to the user cost of capital. Second, to the extent that in the
unconditional labour-demand model one may not be able to control
effectively for the location of the labour demand curve, there is a risk
of confounding shifts in the labour-demand schedule with changes in its
slope. Including the capital stock, rather than the cost of capital,
helps to control for this, while it also leaves some scope for changes
in output. (10) Omitting country and time subscripts for ease of
presentation, conditional labour demand in industry i is represented by:
ln [L.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.o] + [J.summation over
(j=1)][[alpha].sub.j] ln[w.sub.ij] + [[beta].sub.k] ln[k.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.y] ln[y.sub.i] + [L.summation over
(i=l)][[gamma].sub.l][z.sub.il] (4)
where L corresponds to industry-level labour demand; w to the
nominal price of variable factors (i.e. the wage and the price of
materials); k to the capital stock and y to gross output. The core model
is augmented by a set of demand shifters, z, which are intended to
capture factor biased technological change. These include a measure for
the intensity of research and development and, most importantly for this
paper's analysis, intra-industry and inter-industry offshoring as
discussed in Section 2. (11) To the extent that R&D leads to
labour-saving innovation we would expect, an increase in R&D
intensity, like offshoring, to affect labour demand negatively,
conditional on output.
Similarly, unconditional (or 'capital-constrained')
labour demand in industry i is represented by:
ln [L.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.o] + [J.summation over
(j=1)][[alpha].sub.j] ln[w.sub.ij] + [[beta].sub.k] ln[k.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.p] ln[p.sub.i] + [L.summation over
(i=l)][[gamma].sub.l][z.sub.il] (5)
where L corresponds to industry level labour demand; w to the price
of variable factors; k to the capital stock, and p to the price of gross
output. As in the conditional model, the core model is augmented with a
set of variables z, which in addition to the capital stock, are intended
to control for the shifts in labour demand.
In order to implement the two labour demand models empirically we
add a random error term which is assumed to be normally distributed with
zero mean and constant variance. Each labour-demand model is estimated
separately using 5-year differences. Differencing takes account of any
time invariant fixed effects. Long differences are used to account for
lags in the adjustment of labour demand to shocks. Moreover, estimates
based on long differences are less sensitive to bias due to measurement
error than either fixed effects or first differences (Griliches and
Hausman, 1986). Given the homogeneity properties of the cost and profit
functions homogeneity is imposed on the empirical model. (12)
5. Results
Table 1 presents cross-sectional estimates of the impact of
offshoring on sectoral labour demand. A priori, offshoring should have a
negative effect on the labour intensity in an industry (the
'technology effect'), but a positive effect on the level of
output, due to the productivity gains from offshoring (the 'scale
effect'), so that the overall effect is ambiguous. The effect on
labour intensity is given by the offshoring coefficient in the
conditional labour-demand estimates, while the total effect is given by
the unconditional labour-demand estimates. The following results emerge:
* The conditional and unconditional labour demands estimated with
the cross-section data appear to be well identified. In particular, the
unconditional elasticities with respect to wages (relative to the price
of materials) are considerably larger than the conditional wage
elasticities of labour demand, as predicted by economic theory. However,
R&D intensity does have a positive effect on labour demand in the
cross-section estimates, contrary to what we did expect. This could
indicate that R&D intensity reflects merely skill-biased
technological change associated with increased skilled labour demand and
reduced demand for unskilled labour rather than labour-saving
technological change. However, this may also be due to the high degree
of correlation between this variable and the offshoring variables. As
excluding R&D might bias the coefficient on offshoring due to the
presence of an omitted variable, it was decided to leave R&D
intensity in the baseline regressions. However, we get back to this
issue in more detail in the sensitivity analysis in the next section.
* The conditional demand estimates indicate that there is a
significant negative correlation between offshoring within the same
industry (intra-industry offshoring) and labour-intensity (employment at
given output). Given the actual increase in intra-industry offshoring,
the estimated coefficients imply that increased intra-industry
offshoring was associated with a reduction in employment of 0.12 per
cent (0.19 per cent in manufacturing) over the period 1995-2000. (13)
Note however that this only reflects the technology effect of
offshoring. In order to evaluate the full implications of offshoring for
employment one needs to refer to unconditional labour demand-estimates.
There is no association between inter-industry offshoring and labour
intensity. (14)
* The estimates for unconditional labour demand indicate that
offshoring within the same industry has no impact on the level of
employment. The difference between the conditional and unconditional
estimates is consistent with the productivity gains from intra-industry
offshoring being sufficiently large for the jobs created by higher sales
to completely offset the jobs lost by relocating certain production
stages to foreign production sites. Similarly, inter-industry
offshoring, for which the employment losses in the offshoring industry
are expected to be more limited, but the productivity gains similar, is
found to increase industry-level labour demand when using the full
sample. This, however, does not necessarily mean that the total effect
of inter-industry offshoring is more positive (or less negative) than
that of intra-industry offshoring, because the present analysis does not
take account of possible dis-employment effects from inter-industry
offshoring spread over different sectors of the economy. That is, the
labour market effects of inter-industry offshoring may tend to fall on
industries other than the purchasing industry (i [not equal to] j),
whereas the regressions exclusively focus on the effects in the
purchasing industry (i).
6. Sensitivity analysis
In order to analyse the sensitivity of the results we conducted two
robustness checks. First, outlier robust regressions were estimated with
the help of the rreg command in STATA. This involves first excluding any
outlier observations from the standard model using Cook's distance
(D > 1) and then iterating the model using the absolute residuals
from the previous regression as weights. Second, we re-estimated the
model using industry and country-specific trends instead of R&D
intensity. This reflects the desire to account appropriately for other
forces towards technological change and our dissatisfaction with the
role of R&D intensity in the baseline regressions. One plausible
explanation of why R&D intensity is associated with a positive or
insignificant coefficient in the conditional labour demand
regressions--contrary to what economic theory predicts--is that this
reflects the multi-collinearity problem that arises when including
R&D and offshoring simultaneously in the regressions. As there is no
direct way to address this issue country and sector-specific trends are
included instead of R&D intensity to control for technological
change that occurs independent of offshoring.
The outlier robust results are reported in table 2. The results are
very similar in nature to our baseline regressions, but generally
stronger. As before, intra-industry offshoring exerts a statistically
significant and negative effect on labour demand conditional on the
level of output. In addition, we also find that inter-industry
offshoring has a negative effect on industry employment conditional on
output. Once we allow for scale effects we find that the negative effect
of offshoring on employment entirely disappears. There is some
indication that inter-industry offshoring raises employment in the
services sector. The control variables generally have the correct sign
except for R&D intensity which has a positive and significant effect
on employment in most specifications. We will address this issue next.
In order to understand better the role of R&D intensity in our
regressions we re-estimate both labour demand models excluding R&D
intensity. When doing so, intra-industry offshoring is no longer
significant in the conditional model of labour demand. This probably
reflects the omitted variable bias that arises when excluding R&D
intensity due to the negative correlation between R&D intensity and
intra-industry offshoring. In an effort to control for technological
change independent of offshoring, we gradually introduce industry and
country-specific trends into our regressions. After including both
country and industry-specific trends, the coefficients on intra-industry
and inter-industry offshoring become again statistically significant. In
particular, the inclusion of industry-specific trends appears to be
important. However, including trends also has a tendency to absorb the
explanatory power of the other control variables.
The consequences of including industry and country-specific trends
in the unconditional model of labour demand are similar in the sense
that the coefficients on offshoring become increasingly negative when
controlling more fully for unobserved trends. When including both
industry and country-specific trends we find a weak negative effect for
intra-industry offshoring on labour demand. This specification suggests
that the scale effects associated with intra-industry offshoring are
insufficient to offset completely the jobs lost due to its technology
effect. However, the positive scale effect is still substantial.
Inter-industry offshoring is positive, but statistically insignificant.
In sum, the sensitivity analysis suggests that the main results
presented in the previous section are robust to the exclusion of
outliers and the way one controls for technological change. The results
consistently indicate that offshoring has a negative effect on
employment
conditional on output and no effect or a small positive effect when
allowing for both scale and technology effects. Moreover, the technology
effect associated with intra-industry offshoring tends to be more
negative than that with inter-industry offshoring.
The analysis of offshoring presented here may be considered an
extension of the analysis provided by OECD (2007b), which uses the same
data but concentrates on the role of total offshoring. OECD (2007b)
finds that total offshoring has a negative effect on employment
conditional on output and that this is particularly important in the
manufacturing sector. When using total offshoring instead of
intra-industry and inter-industry offshoring, the results suggest no
effect of offshoring on employment conditional on output and a weak
positive effect on the total level of employment. The difference between
these results and the results presented in OECD (2007b) can be
attributed to differences in the way offshoring is measured, differences
in the specification and differences in the sample used. Furthermore,
OECD (2007b) does not find any evidence that offshoring is associated
with any positive scale effects. The complete absence of scale effects
cannot be easily explained on either theoretical grounds or differences
in the methodology.
7. Concluding remarks
An important element of the analysis is to account explicitly for
the technology and scale effects of offshoring. To this end, we proposed
a novel decomposition of sectoral employment change that allows one to
identify the scale and technology effects separately and conducted a
detailed econometric analysis of the scale and technology effects of
offshoring for industry employment using data for seventeen high income
OECD countries.
The main finding in this paper is that offshoring has no effect or
a slight positive effect on sectoral employment. Offshoring within the
same industry (intra-industry offshoring) reduces the labour-intensity
of production, but does not affect overall industry employment. By
contrast, inter-industry offshoring does not affect labour-intensity,
but may have a positive effect on overall industry employment. These
findings suggest that the productivity gains from offshoring are
sufficiently large that the jobs created by higher sales completely
offset the jobs lost by relocating certain production stages to foreign
production sites.
While these findings may be striking to some they are broadly
consistent with previous findings for the US by Amiti and Wei (2006),
but also with Barba Navaretti and Castellani (2003), who find that
establishing an affiliate abroad raises employment at home, and Hanson
et al. (2005) who find that an increase in the scale of affiliate
production abroad raises domestic employment.
Even if offshoring typically does not result in net employment
losses at the level of the industry or even the firm, this does not
necessarily mean that workers do not encounter significant adjustment
difficulties. OECD (2007a) shows that intra-industry offshoring is
associated with increasing skill demands, suggesting that some of the
workers whose jobs are lost due to the technology effect from offshoring
may lack the qualifications required for the jobs created by the scale
effect. A number of earlier studies have also analysed changes in the
skill composition of sectoral employment associated with offshoring.
Feenstra and Hanson (1996), Hijzen et al. (2005) and Ekholm and Hakkala
(2006) find that offshoring may have important implications for the
skill composition in an industry, although not necessarily in the same
way. Whereas Feenstra and Hanson (1996) for the US and Hijzen et al.
(2005) for the UK find that offshoring moves labour demand away from
workers with low levels of skills to workers with high skill levels,
Ekholm and Hakkala (2006) find that offshoring moves labour demand away
from workers with intermediate levels of skills.
The offshoring data for 1995 and 2000, which are used in this
study, may understate the future impact of offshoring on the sectoral
and occupational composition of employment. As many have observed,
advances in information and communications technologies appear to be
greatly expanding the range of service activities that could be
relocated to foreign production sites. It is therefore worth noting that
even should offshoring come to have important implications for
industry-level labour demand, this still would not imply a reduction in
the total number of jobs in the economy. In this case, offshoring, like
trade in final goods, would be a force for structural adjustment along
the lines implied by the principle of comparative advantage. OECD
(2007a) suggests that trade openness is not systematically related to
aggregate employment. The extent to which increased job reallocation will be associated with temporary increases in unemployment depends for
an important part on the role of institutions (Amiti and Ekholm, 2006).
This constitutes a very important area for future research.
Finally, OECD (2007a) suggests that increased offshoring may not
only represent a shock to which labour markets need to adjust, but may
also have an impact on the way labour markets work. Rodrik (1997)
hypothesised that globalisation may increase the responsiveness of
employment and wages to economic shocks, by increasing the own-price
elasticity of labour demand. OECD (2007a) provides new evidence that
labour demand has become increasingly elastic across a number of OECD
countries and that the growing practice of offshoring may have
contributed to this trend. This could help to explain why workers appear
to feel increasingly insecure. A more elastic labour demand would also
tend to reduce the bargaining power of workers relative to employers and
reduce the scope for risk-sharing arrangements between workers and
firms, for example when firms provide stable wages to long-term workers,
despite fluctuations in external labour market conditions.
ANNEX
Variable Definitions
Employment Log of total persons engaged.
Wage Log of total labour costs divided by the number
of employees.
Materials Log volume of materials at 2000 constant prices.
Price of materials Log price index of materials.
Data adjustments For observations for which information on the
price of materials was not available, the price
of materials was imputed. The composition of
inputs was obtained from the input-output tables.
The price index of materials was imputed by
multiplying the share of total purchases
(domestic plus imported) by industry i from
supplying industry j in total intermediate
purchases (domestic plus imported) by industry i
with the price of value-added of industry j.
Capital stock Log volume of gross capital stock at 2000
constant prices. Data adjustments. For countries
for which the capital stock was not available or
industry coverage was insufficient, capital
stocks were reconstructed from gross fixed
capital formation using a perpetual-inventory
method based on an assumed depreciation rate of
10 per cent.
Output Log volume of output at 2000 constant prices.
Price of output Log price index of output.
R&D intensity Ratio of real expenditure on research and
development over real value-added.
REFERENCES
Amiti, M. and Wei, S. (2005), 'Fear of service outsourcing; is
it justified?', Economic Policy, 20, pp. 308-47.
--(2006), 'Service offshoring, productivity and employment:
evidence from the US', CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 5475.
Amiti, M. and Ekholm, K. (2006), 'The effect of offshoring on
employment in rigid labor markets: evidence from EU countries',
mimeo.
Barba Navaretti, G. and Castellani, D. (2003), 'Investments
abroad and performance at home', CEPR Discussion Paper, No. 4284.
Berman, E., Bound, J. and Griliches, Z. (1994), 'Changes in
the demand for skilled labor within U.S. manufacturing: evidence from
the annual survey of manufacturers', Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 109, pp. 367-97.
Campa, J. and Goldberg, L.S. (1997), 'The evolving external
orientation of manufacturing industries: evidence from four
countries', Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy
Review, 3, 2, pp. 53-81.
Clark, K.B. and Freeman, R.B. (1980), 'How elastic is the
demand for labor?', Review of Economics and Statistics, 62, 4, pp.
509-20.
Ekholm, K. and Hakkala, K. (2006), 'The effect of offshoring
on labor demand: evidence from Sweden', Scandinavian Journal of
Economics (forthcoming).
European Commission (2005), Standard Eurobarometer 63: Public
Opinion in the European Union, Brussels, European Union.
Feenstra, R.C. and Hanson, G.H. (1996), 'Globalisation,
outsourcing, and wage inequality', American Economic Review, 86, 2,
pp. 240-5.
--(1999), 'The impact of outsourcing and high-technology
capital on wages: estimates for the United States, 1979-1990',
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 3, pp. 907-41.
Griliches, Z. and Hausman, J. (1986), 'Errors in variables in
panel data', Journal of Econometrics, 31, pp. 93-118.
Hamermesh, D. (1993), Labor Demand, Princeton, New Jersey,
Princeton University Press.
Hanson, G., Mataloni, R. and Slaughter, M. (2005), 'Vertical
production networks in multinational firms', Review of Economics
and Statistics, November 87, pp. 664-78.
Hijzen, A., Gorg, H. and Hine, R. (2005), 'International
outsourcing and the skill structure of labour demand in the United
Kingdom', Economic Journal, 115, pp. 860-78.
Hijzen, A., Inui, T. and Todo, Y. (2007), 'Does offshoring
pay? Firm-level evidence from Japan', GEP Research Paper, 2007/ 14.
Hummels, D., Ishii, J. and Yi, K. (2001), 'The nature and
growth of vertical specialisation in world trade', Journal of
International Economics, 54, pp. 75-96.
Mankiw, N.G. and Swagel, P. (2006), 'The politics and the
economics of offshore outsourcing', NBER Working Paper, No. 12398.
OECD (2007a), OECD Employment Outlook, Chapter 3, Paris, OECD.
--(2007b), Offshoring and Employment: Trends and Policy
Implications, Paris, OECD (forthcoming).
Olsen, K.B. (2006), 'Productivity impacts of offshoring and
outsourcing: a review', OECD Science, Technology and Industry
Working Papers, 2006/1, Paris, OECD.
Rodrik, D. (1997), Has Globalisation Gone Too Far?, Washington,
D.C., Institute for International Economics.
NOTES
(1) See Olsen (2006) for a review of the literature on offshoring
and productivity and Hijzen et al. (2007) for a recent case study for
Japan.
(2) They can be produced by recording flows between the sales and
purchases (final and intermediate) of industry outputs or by recording
the sales and purchases (final and intermediate) of product outputs. The
OECD Input-output Database is presented on the former basis, which
facilitates linking data with other sources, which are in the main
collected by establishments, and so industry.
(3) The input-output tables may differ somewhat from official
country estimates due to adjustments that were made with respect to
disclosure rules.
(4) Feenstra and Hanson (1996) measure offshoring as the share of
imported inputs in total intermediate inputs thereby emphasising the
choice between purchasing intermediate inputs at home and abroad. In the
present case, we define offshoring as the share of imported intermediate
inputs in value-added, which emphasises the relocation of production
activities formerly produced in the home industry.
(5) The drawback of this measure is that it relies on the way
industries are classified.
(6) More precisely, in terms of ISIC Rev. 3 the following
industries were included in the analysis: 15-16, 17-19, 20, 21-22, 24,
25, 26, 27, 28, 29, 30, 31, 32, 33, 34, 35, 36-37, 45, 50-52; 70-71;
73-74, 55, 60-63, 72.
(7) The data values reported here tend to be quite a bit lower than
those reported by Campa and Goldberg (1997), because the primary sector
is excluded.
(8) The shares of trade in intermediate goods are higher for small
countries, such as Belgium and the Netherlands (respectively, 16 per
cent and 12 per cent of GDP in 2000), than for large countries,
particularly the United States (3 per cent). This may be due, in part,
to the fact that larger countries can achieve economies of scale more
easily than small countries and can thus retain more stages of
production at home.
(9) The scale of services offshoring to date remains quite modest,
typically at around 2 per cent of sales. However, improvements in IC
technologies (e.g. the Internet) make it increasingly feasible and
profitable to offshore certain service activities. The data suggest that
the growth of offshoring of business services during 1995-2000 was more
widespread and somewhat more rapid than the growth of material
offshoring (OECD, 2007a).
(10) This thus represents a compromise solution between
identification of the labour-demand curve and the ability to capture
scale effects in the unconditional labour-demand model. As such, one may
alternatively like to refer to it as the capital-constrained model.
(11) Arguably, the degree of automatisation/computerisation may be
a more appropriate measure of labour-saving technological change. The
main reason for using R&D intensity instead of a proxy for
computerisation is the availability of comparable data across countries
and time. To the extent that R&D intensity is skill-biased rather
than labour-saving, its effect on total labour demand may be ambiguous.
(12) Clark and Freeman (1980) argue that this may aggravate bias in
the estimation when measurement error is important. Standard F-tests
suggest that measurement problems are unlikely to be very important here
as the restriction of homogeneity could not be rejected by the data.
(13) Offshoring within the same industry increased on average in
the whole economy by about 1.5 percentage points (recorded in the data
as 0.015) over the period 1995-2000 and in manufacturing by 2 percentage
points.
(14) To the extent that all or some imported intermediate inputs
from industries other than one's own were previously purchased from
domestic suppliers, one would expect a larger coefficient for intra-
than inter-industry offshoring as is also observed. Ideally, one would
also like to estimate the importance of job losses that may arise when
firms substitute domestic suppliers in other industries by suppliers
located abroad. However, cross-industry relocation effects of this type
are not estimated in this paper.
Alexander Hijzen, OECD and GEP, University of Nottingham. e-mail:
alexander.hijzen@oecd.org. Paul Swaim, OECD. This research was conducted
as part of the OECD project on Globalisation and Structural Adjustment
Ill. The present paper is an extension to the analysis of offshoring
that was published in Chapter 3 of the OECD Employment Outlook 2007,
'OECD workers in the global economy: increasingly vulnerable?'
The authors would like to thank Sebastien Martin for excellent research
assistance. The authors are also grateful to Andrea Bassanini, Sven
Blondal, Boris Cournede, Martine Durand, Sam Hill, Molly Lesher, John
Martin, Nigel Pain and Raymond Torres for very helpful comments and
suggestions on an earlier draft. The opinions expressed in this paper
are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the
OECD or its member states. All remaining errors are our own.
Table 1: Baseline regression results, OLS over five-year differences
Conditional
All Manuf. Services
log (wage/price of -0.242 -0.222 -0.163
materials)
(2.06) ** (1.62) (1.13)
log capital stock 0.202 0.11 0.453
(2.37) ** (1.69) * (4.63) ***
log output 0.18 0.15 0.364
(3.91) *** (3.40) *** (3.37) ***
log (price of output/price
of materials)
R&D intensity 0.500 0.560 -0.052
(1.85) * (1.39) (0.20)
Intea-industry offshoring -0.082 -0.094 -1.096
(1.85) * (2.44) ** (0.77)
Inter-industry offshoring -0.034 -0.039 -0.64
(1.19) (1.52) (1.51)
Constant -0.003 -0.004 -0.009
(0.94) (1.21) (1.72) *
Observations 238 181 57
R-squared 0.47 0.50 0.60
Unconditional
All Manuf. Services
log (wage/price of -0.42 -0.397 -0.394
materials)
(4.66) *** (4.25) *** (2.87) ***
log capital stock 0.256 0.157 0.596
(2.90) *** (2.21) ** (5.93) ***
log output
log (price of output/price 0.326 0.110 0.415
of materials) (1.35) (0.31) (2.10) **
R&D intensity 0.321 0.243 -0.034
(1.10) (0.49) (0.16)
Intea-industry offshoring 0.013 -0.012 0.306
(0.40) (0.38) (0.19)
Inter-industry offshoring 0.034 0.023 0.211
(1.92) * (1.11) (0.80)
Constant 0.000 -0.002 0.001
(0.04) (0.60) (0.24)
Observations 238 181 57
R-squared 0.41 0.44 0.55
Notes: * significant at 10 per cent; ** significant at 5 per cent; ***
significant at 1 per cent, robust t statistics in parentheses.
Table 2. Outlier robust regression results over five-year differences
Conditional
All Manuf. Services
log (wage/price of -0.124 -0.227 0.006
materials)
(2.32) ** (3.40) *** (0.06)
log capital stock 0.145 0.143 0.253
(5.53) *** (5.03) *** (3.30) ***
log output 0.178 0.151 0.141
(6.68) *** (5.06) *** (1.66)
log (price of output/price
of materials)
R&D intensity 0.595 0.779 0.318
(4.03) *** 3.57 *** (1.23)
Intra-industry offshoring -0.083 -0.07 0.635
(3.33) *** (2.67) *** -(0.67)
Intra-industry offshoring -0.137 -0.111 0.026
(2.50) ** (1.97) * (0.08)
Constant -0.004 -0.005 0.002
(2.28) ** (2.75) *** -0.32
Observations 237 179 57
R-squared 0.44 0.43 0.41
Unconditional
All Manuf. Services
log (wage/price of -0.383 -0.422 -0.037
materials)
(8.06) *** 7.10 *** (0.45)
log capital stock 0.229 0.201 0.29
(8.73) *** (7.27) *** (4.53) ***
log output
log (price of output/price 0.295 0.404 -0.11
of materials)
(3.13) *** (3.01) *** (0.73)
R&D intensity 0.495 0.614 0.317
(3.11) *** (2.70) *** (1.24)
Intea-industry offshoring -0.017 -0.014 0.58
-0.69 -0.58 -0.58
Inter-industry offshoring 0.06 0.037 0.483
(1.30) (0.80) (2.28) **
Constant -0.001 -0.002 0.005
(0.67) (1.17) (1.15)
Observations 237 178 57
R-squared 0.41 0.41 0.35
Notes: * significant at 10 per cent; ** significant at 5 per cent; ***
significant at 1 per cent.
Table 3. Regression results over five-year differences with industry
and country-specific trends
Conditional
Log (wage/price of -0.237 -0.158
materials) (1.99) ** (0.89)
Log capital stock 0.207 0.24
(2.40) ** (2.09) **
Log output 0.162 0.214
(3.94) *** (2.60) ***
Log (price of output/
price of materials)
Intra-industry -0.06 -0.048
offshoring (1.54) (1.13)
Inter-industry -0.012 -0.008
offshoring (0.53) (0.33)
Constant -0.003 -0.012
(0.79) (1.19)
Country dummies No Yes
Sector dummies No No
Observations 238 238
R-squared 0.46 0.52
Conditional
Log (wage/price of -0.093 -0.025
materials) (1.43) (0.23)
Log capital stock 0.072 0.047
(1.37) -0.74
Log output 0.178 0.168
(4.39) *** (2.84) ***
Log (price of output/
price of materials)
Intra-industry -0.123 -0.117
offshoring (2.72) *** (2.52) **
Inter-industry -0.056 -0.049
offshoring (2.15) ** (1.80) *
Constant 0.006 0.003
(0.97) (0.27)
Country dummies No Yes
Sector dummies Yes Yes
Observations 238 238
R-squared 0.75 0.81
Unconditional
Log (wage/price of -0.406 -0.306
materials) (4.48) *** (1.74) *
Log capital stock 0.256 0.293
(2.89) *** (2.56) **
Log output
Log (price of output/ 0.291 0.301
price of materials) (1.23) (1.26)
Intra-industry 0.02 -0.006
offshoring (0.64) (0.16)
Inter-industry 0.043 0.028
offshoring (2.46) ** (1.25)
Constant 0.000 -0.005
(0.05) (0.51)
Country dummies No Yes
Sector dummies No No
Observations 238 238
R-squared 0.41 0.48
-0.287 -0.061
(4.60) *** -0.58
0.127 0.061
(2.00) ** (0.87)
Unconditional
Log (wage/price of 0.131 0.088
materials) (0.87) (0.63)
Log capital stock -0.019 -0.087
(0.51) (1.75) *
Log output 0.016 0.018
(0.83) (0.67)
Log (price of output/ 0.014 0.009
price of materials) (1.94) * (0.79)
Intra-industry No Yes
offshoring Yes Yes
Inter-industry 238 238
offshoring 0.69 0.79
Constant
Country dummies
Sector dummies
Observations
R-squared
Notes: * significant at 10 per cent; ** significant at 5 per cent;
*** significant at 1 per +cent, robust t statistics in parentheses.