Net migration and the macroeconomy: inflation and output effects.
Kirby, Simon ; Riley, Rebecca
Since the last NIESR forecast in October the Government
Actuary's Department (GAD) has released new projections of the UK
population. (1) In comparison to previous projections these show
substantial upward revisions to growth in the population of working age
and to total population growth from 2005 to 2007. From 2008 and onwards there have been smaller upward revisions. Figure 1 illustrates the
profile for growth in the population of working age implied by both the
GAD 2003-based and the most recent GAD 2004-based mid-year projections.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The revisions to the GAD projections are almost exclusively the
result of revised assumptions about net migration to the UK. According
to Total International Migration estimates produced by the Office for
National Statistics, net migration to the UK was exceptionally strong in
2004, rising to 223 thousand from a stable average of 160 thousand per
annum in the five years before. This was a result of an increase in the
inflow of people to the UK, most notably from the European Union which
expanded with ten new member states on 1 May 2004. Net inward migration
in 2004 was also particularly strong from the Commonwealth, with a
relatively sharp offset from a reduction in net inward migration of
British citizens.
The upward revision to population growth in all years of the
projection follows persistence of historically high net inward
migration. The sharp increase in population growth estimated for last
year takes into account provisional migration data for the second half
of 2004. Otherwise the relatively strong upward revision for 2005-7 is a
direct result of an allowance for additional net inward migration from
the accession countries to the European Union.
In comparison to previous estimates, the population of working age
is expected to be 1 per cent greater than previously thought by 2012 and
2 per cent greater than previously thought by 2026. The total population
rises by a little less, since migrants are typically young and of
working age, such that there is a small reduction in the dependency
ratio (the number of non-working age people per 100 people of working
age) of 1/4 percentage points.
A population shock like the one described above affects the economy
directly in two ways. First, by raising the labour force it increases
the long-run supply capacity of the economy. Second, by reducing the
dependency ratio it reduces the share of government spending in GDE Since the revisions to the GAD projections do not change the dependency
ratio by much, this second effect has only minor consequences for the
macroeconomy. The first effect is by far the most important.
Net migration may also change the equilibrium rate of unemployment.
For example, if the skills of net migrants are such that they complement
the skills of the existing population and relieve bottlenecks in the
labour market, wage pressure will be reduced, all else being equal. This
would tend to reduce the equilibrium rate of unemployment. Dustman et
al. (2005) suggest that, at the national level, the skill mix of
migrants to Britain is fairly similar to the skill mix of native born
workers. Frijters et al. (2005) find that on average the duration of
unemployment spells is greater for migrants to the UK than for people
born in the UK. On the basis of the numbers reported there, one might
expect an increase in the population of the nature discussed here to
lead to a very minor increase in the equilibrium rate of unemployment.
The level of employment would still rise.
Based on simulations using NiGEM (2) it is possible to illustrate
how this additional population growth, arising from stronger net
migration to the UK, may be expected to affect the macroeconomy. The
NIESR forecast is based on the assumption that the population of working
age and the population as a whole grow in line with GAD projections.
Hence, this exercise also illustrates the approximate effects on the
forecast for the UK economy that result from changes to the population
data.
Table 1 shows the effects on the unemployment rate, consumer price
inflation and GDP growth of a shock to the population of the magnitude
implied by the revisions to the GAD projections. In these simulations
net migrants are assumed to display similar labour market
characteristics to those of the existing population. Thus, labour market
participation is assumed to be unaffected by the population shock and
the labour force rises in line with the population of working age. In
addition, net migrants looking for work are assumed to exert the same
pressure on wages as the existing unemployed, leaving the equilibrium
rate of unemployment unaffected in these simulations.
The first set of results in table 1 are generated assuming that
wages are set with reference to expected price inflation as well as past
inflation and assuming that equity prices, long-term interest rates, and
exchange rates are forward looking variables and expectations are
rational. As shown in the table, the additional labour supply that
results from the increase in the population of working age is not
absorbed immediately and as a result the unemployment rate rises for a
few years. This puts downward pressure on wages and two years after the
initial shock to the population reduces inflation by approximately 0.2
percentage points per annum. This helps to raise demand. Real wage
growth is also dampened, increasing the demand for labour. In response
to weaker anticipated inflation, monetary policy is relaxed. As a result
the exchange rate depreciates immediately, boosting export demand and
helping to explain why inflation initially rises, albeit marginally. In
the longer term GDP growth is 0.1 percentage points greater than it
would have been in absence of the population shock, due to the shift in
trend growth of the labour input. The increase in net inward migration
also improves the medium-term budgetary position by approximately 0.2
percentage points of GDP. This outcome is a result of stronger real
growth. The improvement comes about, amongst other factors, via an
increase in taxes on profits, which rise as a share of the economy as
real wage growth is restrained, and a reduction in government interest
payments, which fall as monetary policy is relaxed.
In the second set of results shown in table 1, wages are assumed to
be entirely backward looking and the nominal exchange rate is fixed.
These results are shown to illustrate the importance of the exchange
rate effect and the forward looking element in wage setting in raising
aggregate demand and labour demand initially and in helping the economy
absorb the additional labour supply quickly. In the backward looking
scenario GDP growth is almost 0.1 percentage points weaker for the first
two years of the shock and the rate of unemployment rises by an
additional 0.1 percentage points for several years. In the longer term
GDP growth is stronger as the economy eventually responds to the shock.
In the very long term the level of GDP changes by the same amount in
both cases.
In the simulations underlying the results in table 1 net migrants
were assumed to be identical to the rest of the population in terms of
their labour market characteristics. If, instead, activity rates or the
skill composition differed, the effect of the population shock on the
economy would be marginally different from the results shown in table 1.
For example, if on average the labour market participation rate for net
migrants is 10 percentage points greater than for the existing
population, the initial rise in the rate of unemployment would be
approximately 0.04 percentage points greater than shown in table 1. GDP
growth would be on average less than 0.02 percentage points above the
figures in table 1.
It is not obvious that activity rates should differ between net
migrants and the existing population. Speculatively, if one of the main
reasons for migration to the UK is to participate in education, one
might expect the increase in net migration to reduce the aggregate
activity rate. If, on the other hand, one of the main reasons for
migration is economic, one might expect the average activity rate to
increase. We know that migrants are relatively young. According to the
Labour Force Survey, the labour market participation rate for 18-24
years olds is approximately 4 percentage points below the average for
the population of working age as a whole. The labour market
participation rate for 25-34 years olds, who may also be counted as
relatively young, is approximately 5 percentage points above the average
for the population of working age as a whole. Hence the impact on the
overall participation rate will only become clear once the new flows are
well established.
Another source of uncertainty in ascertaining the effect of
increased net migration to the UK on the aggregate economy relates to
the data itself. As discussed in the Bank of England's (2005)
August Inflation Report, there are reasons to believe that the official
migration data may not accurately reflect true migration to the UK. In
particular, the official data do not capture the flow of migrants who
come to work in the UK only temporarily.
NOTES
(1) These are available at http://www.gad.gov.uk
(2) National Institute Global Econometric Model V4.05, October
2005.
REFERENCES
Bank of England (2005), Inflation Report, August.
Dustmann, C., Fabbri, F. and Preston, I. (2005), 'The impact
of immigration on the British labour market', Economic Journal,
115, F324-41.
Frijters, P., Shields, M.A. and Price, S.W. (2005), 'Job
search methods and their success: a comparison of immigrants and natives
in the UK', Economic Journal, 115, F359-76.
Simon Kirby and Rebecca Riley, Thanks to Ray Barrell and Martin
Weale for helpful suggestions.
Table 1. Economic effects of revisions to population projections
Assuming: Forward looking wages and financial markets
Unemployment rate Inflation GDP growth
(absolute difference from base)
2005 0.20 0.02 0.09
2006 0.40 -0.07 0.13
2007 0.39 -0.20 0.10
2008 0.33 -0.23 0.12
2009 0.24 -0.23 0.14
2010-2014 0.06 -0.10 0.11
Assuming: Backward looking wages and fixed nominal exchange rates
Unemployment rate Inflation GDP growth
(absolute difference from base)
2005 0.20 0.00 0.02
2006 0.48 -0.09 0.04
2007 0.51 -0.22 0.07
2008 0.47 -0.28 0.12
2009 0.37 -0.28 0.17
2010-2014 0.08 -0.13 0.17