Modelling financial instability.
Allen, Franklin
Financial instability can have large adverse effects on an economy.
One major cause of instability is asset price bubbles. This paper starts
by considering how such bubbles can arise due to the expansion of money
and credit. The ways in which subsequent financial instability occurs
are then discussed. Banking crises can arise due to panics or as a
result of the business cycle. Contagion and financial fragility can
cause small disturbances to have large effects. Finally, policy issues
are touched upon.
Keywords: Bubbles; crises; contagion; fragility.
JEL classification: G12, G21, G28
I. Introduction
The UK has experienced a large increase in property prices in the
past decade. At the same time consumer price inflation has been
moderate. What has caused property prices to increase so much in an
environment of low inflation? Is the rise in property prices due to the
availability of easy credit or a change in fundamentals? If the increase
is due to easy credit rather than an improvement in underlying
fundamentals, does this mean that property prices will crash at some
point and lead to financial instability? The purpose of this paper is to
investigate these ideas in the context of recent models of financial
instability.
There are a number of recent examples of monetary expansion and
lending booms and apparent bubbles in real estate and stocks. Often
these lending booms are triggered by financial deregulation. The
subsequent bursting of these bubbles has led to financial crises (see
also Borio, 2005, this volume). The idea that the amount of money and
credit available is an important factor in the determination of asset
prices is not new. In his description of historic bubbles Kindleberger
(1978, p. 54) emphasises the role of this factor: "Speculative
manias gather speed through expansion of money and credit or perhaps, in
some cases, get started because of an initial expansion of money and
credit."
Perhaps the best known recent example of this type of phenomenon is
the dramatic rise in real estate and stock prices that occurred in Japan
in the late 1980s and their subsequent collapse in 1990. Financial
liberalisation throughout the 1980s and the desire to support the United
States dollar in the latter part of the decade led to an expansion in
credit. During most of the 1980s asset prices rose steadily, eventually
reaching very high levels. For example, the Nikkei 225 index was around
10,000 in 1985. On December 19, 1989 it reached a peak of 38,916. A new
Governor of the Bank of Japan, less concerned with supporting the US
dollar and more concerned with fighting inflation, tightened monetary
policy and this led to a sharp increase in interest rates in early 1990
(Frankel, 1993; Tschoegl, 1993). The bubble burst. The Nikkei 225 fell
sharply during the first part of the year and by October 1, 1990 it had
sunk to 20,222. Real estate prices followed a similar pattern. The next
few years were marked by defaults and retrenchment in the financial
system. The real economy was adversely affected by the aftermath of the
bubble and growth rates during the 1990s and 2000s have mostly been
slightly positive or negative, in contrast to most of the postwar period
when they were much higher.
Similar events occurred in Norway, Finland and Sweden in the 1980s
(Heiskanen, 1993; Drees and Pazarbasioglu, 1995). In Norway the ratio of
bank loans to nominal GDP went from 40 per cent in 1984 to 68 per cent
in 1988. Asset prices soared while investment and consumption also
increased significantly. The collapse in oil prices helped burst the
bubble and caused the most severe banking crisis and recession since the
war. In Finland an expansionary budget in 1987 resulted in massive
credit expansion. The ratio of bank loans to nominal GDP increased from
55 per cent in 1984 to 90 per cent in 1990. Housing prices rose by a
total of 68 per cent in 1987 and 1988. In 1989 the central bank
increased interest rates and imposed reserve requirements to moderate
credit expansion. In 1990 and 1991 the economic situation was
exacerbated by a fall in trade with the Soviet Union. Asset prices
collapsed, banks had to be supported by the Government and GDP shrank by
7 per cent. In Sweden a steady credit expansion through the late 1980s
led to a property boom. In the fall of 1990 credit was tightened and
interest rates rose. In 1991 a number of banks had severe difficulties
because of lending based on inflated asset values. The Government had to
intervene and a severe recession followed.
Mexico provides a dramatic illustration of an emerging economy
affected by this type of problem. In the early 1990s the banks were
privatised and a financial liberalisation occurred. Perhaps most
significantly, reserve requirements were eliminated. Mishkin (1997)
documents how bank credit to private nonfinancial enterprises went from
a level of around 10 per cent of GDP in the late 1980s to 40 per cent of
GDP in 1994. The stock market rose significantly during the early 1990s.
In 1994 the Colosio assassination and the uprising in Chiapas triggered
the collapse of the bubble. The prices of stocks and other assets fell
and banking and foreign exchange crises occurred. These were followed by
a severe recession.
These bubbles in asset prices typically have three distinct phases.
The first phase starts with financial liberalisation or a conscious
decision by the central bank to increase lending or some other similar
event. The resulting expansion in credit is accompanied by an increase
in the prices for assets such as real estate and stocks. This rise in
prices continues for some time, possibly several years, as the bubble
inflates. During the second phase the bubble bursts and asset prices
collapse, often in a short period of time such as a few days or months,
but sometimes over a longer period. The third phase is characterised by
the default of many firms and other agents that have borrowed to buy
assets at inflated prices. Banking and/or foreign exchange crises may
follow this wave of defaults. The difficulties associated with the
defaults and banking and foreign exchange crises often cause problems in
the real sector of the economy which can last for a number of years.
There is a significant interaction between the financial system and
growth.
How can events such as these be understood? Allen and Gale (2000a;
2003; 2004) provide a theory of bubbles and ensuing crises based on the
existence of an agency problem. Standard theories of asset pricing
assume that investors purchase assets with their own wealth. In most
financial systems, this is not the whole story. Intermediation is
important. Many of the agents buying real estate, stocks, and other
assets do so with other people's money. The purchase of real estate
is usually debt financed. If the investment is successful, the borrower
repays the loan and retains the difference between the value of the
asset and the principal and interest. If the investment is unsuccessful,
the borrower has limited liability and the lender bears the shortfall.
Similarly, a large proportion of stocks is held by mutual funds, pension
funds, and insurance companies. Money managers also have incentives to
take risk. If their investment strategy is successful, they may be
rewarded by a share of the returns, but most importantly they will
attract new investors in the future. Because they receive management
fees in proportion to the assets under their control, they will be
significantly better off as a result of their good performance. If the
investment strategy is unsuccessful, there is a limit to the downside
risk that the manager bears. In the worst case, she will be fired but in
any case her liability is limited. Thus, when intermediaries make
investment decisions, the incentive scheme they face has convex payoffs.
The agency problem of excessive risk taking associated with limited
liability is crucial for the analysis. If the penalties for default on
debt or the reputational loss from being fired from an intermediary are
sufficiently high then there will not be an incentive to take risks.
Hence the theory can be thought of as applying to cases where these
factors are insufficient to prevent risk taking.
If there is an agency problem of the type described the people
making the investment decisions will have an incentive to take on risky
projects. The fact that lenders are unable to observe the
characteristics of a project means the borrowers can shift risk to the
lenders and increase their own payoff. This causes investors to bid up
the prices of risky assets above their fundamental values and there is a
bubble. The more risky the asset the greater is the amount that can be
shifted and the larger the bubble. This risk can come from two sources.
The first is asset return risk. The second is financial risk. This is
the risk associated with future financial conditions such as the amount
of credit that will be available. A framework for analysing these
effects is developed next.
2. A framework
A simple example is developed to illustrate the model in Allen and
Gale (2000a).
For ease of exposition the example is slightly different from the
model presented there. Standard models of asset pricing assume people
invest with their own money. The price of an asset in this benchmark
case is identified as the 'fundamental'. A bubble is said to
occur when the price of an asset rises above this benchmark (see Allen,
Morris and Postlewaite, 1993, for a full discussion of the definition of
fundamental and bubble).
If the people making investment decisions borrow money, they are
only interested in the upper part of the distribution of payoffs of the
risky asset because of the possibility of default. As a result there is
a risk shifting problem and the price of the risky asset is bid up above
the benchmark so there is a bubble.
In the example, the people who make investment decisions do so with
borrowed money. If they default there is limited liability. Lenders
cannot observe the riskiness of the projects invested in so there is an
agency problem. For the case of real estate this representation of the
agency problem is directly applicable. For the case of stocks there are
margin limits that prevent people directly borrowing and investing in
the asset. However, a more appropriate interpretation in this case is
that it is institutional investors making the investment decisions. This
group constitutes a large part of the market in many countries. The
agency problem that occurs is similar to that with a debt contract.
First, the people that supply the funds have little control over how
they are invested. Second, the reward structure is similar to what
happens with a debt contract. If the assets the fund managers invest in
do well, the managers attract more funds in the future and receive
higher payments as a result. If the assets do badly, there is a limit to
the penalty that is imposed on the managers. The worse that can happen
is that they are fired. This is analogous to limited liability (Allen
and Gorton, 1993).
Initially there are two dates t = 1, 2. There are two assets in the
example. The first is a safe asset in variable supply. For each 1 unit
invested in this asset at date 1 the output is 1.5 at date 2. The second
is a risky asset in fixed supply that can be thought of as real estate
or stocks. There is 1 unit of this risky asset. For each unit purchased
at price P at date 1 the output is 6 with prob. 0.25 and 1 with prob.
0.75 at date 2 so the expected payoff is 2.25. The details of the two
assets are given in table 1.
The fundamental
Suppose each investor has wealth 1 initially and invests her own
wealth directly. Since everybody is risk neutral the marginal returns on
the two assets must be equated.
2.25/[P.sub.F] = 1.5/1
or
[P.sub.F] = 2.25/1.5 = 1.5
The value of the asset is simply the discounted present value of
the payoff where the discount rate is the opportunity cost of the
investor. This is the classic definition of the fundamental. The
benchmark value of the asset is thus 1.5 and any price above this is
termed a bubble.
Intermediated case
Suppose next that investors have no wealth of their own. They can
borrow to buy assets at a rate of 33.33 per cent. The most they can
borrow is 1. If they borrow 1 they repay 1.33 if they are able to. If
they are unable to pay this much the lender can claim whatever they
have. As explained above, lenders cannot observe how loans are invested
and this leads to an agency problem.
The first issue is can P = 1.5 be the equilibrium price? Consider
what happens if an investor borrows 1 and invests in the safe asset.
Marginal return to safe asset
= 1.5 - 1.33
= 0.17
Supposed instead that she borrows 1 and invests in the risky asset.
She purchases 1/1.5 units. When the payoff is 6 she repays the principal
and interest of 1.33 and keeps what remains. When it is 1 she defaults
and the entire payoff goes to the lender so she receives 0.
Marginal return to risky asset
= 0.25(1./1.5 x 6-1.33) + 0.75 x 0
= 0.67
The risky asset is clearly preferred when P = 1.5 since 0.67 >
0.17. The total expected payoff of 1.5 on the investment in 1 unit of
the safe asset is the same as on the investment of 1/1.5 units of the
risky asset since (1/1.5) x 2.25 = 1.5. The risky asset is more
attractive to the borrower though. With the safe asset the borrower
obtains 0.17 and the lender obtains 1.33. With the risky asset the
borrower obtains 0.67 while the lender obtains 0.25 x 1.33 + 0.75 x 1 x
(1/1.5) = 1.5 - 0.67 = 0.83. The risk of default allows 0.5 in expected
value to be shifted from the lender to the borrower. This is the risk
shifting problem. If the lender could prevent the borrower from
investing in the risky asset he would do so but he cannot since this is
unobservable.
What is the equilibrium price of the risky asset given this agency
problem? In an equilibrium where the safe asset is used, the price of
the risky asset, P, will be bid up since it is in fixed supply, until
the expected profit of borrowers is the same for both the risky and the
safe asset:
0.25 (1/P x 6 - 1.33) + 0.75 x 0 = 1.5 - 1.33
so
P = 3.
There is a bubble with the price of the risky asset above the
benchmark of 1.5.
The idea that there is a risk shifting problem when the lender is
unable to observe how the borrower invests the funds is not new (see,
for example, Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981).
However, it has not been widely applied in the asset pricing literature.
Instead of the standard result in corporate finance textbooks that
debt-financed firms are willing to accept negative net present value
investments, the manifestation of the agency problem here is that the
debt-financed investors are willing to invest in assets priced above
their fundamental.
The amount of risk that is shifted depends on how risky the asset
is. The greater the risk the greater the potential to shift risk and
hence the higher the price will be. To illustrate this consider the
previous example but suppose the payoff on the risky asset is a
mean-preserving spread of the original payoffs (table 2).
Now the price of the risky asset is given by
0.25 (1/P x 9 - 1.33) + 0.75 x 0 = 1.5 - 1.33
so
P = 4.5.
More risk is shifted and as a result the price of the risky asset
is bid up to an even higher level.
It is interesting to note that in both the stock market boom of the
1920s and the one in the 1990s the stocks that did best were
'high-tech' stocks. In the 1920s it was radio stocks and
utilities that were the star performers (see White, 1990). In the 1990s
it was telecommunications, media and entertainment and technology stocks
that did the best. It is precisely these stocks which have the most
uncertain payoffs because of the nature of the business they are in.
One of the crucial issues is why the banks are willing to lend to
the investors given the chance of default. To see this consider again
the case where the payoffs on the risky asset are those in table 1 and P
= 3. In this case the quantity of the risky asset purchased when
somebody borrows 1 is 1/P = 1/ 3. In the equilibria considered above the
investors are indifferent between investing in the safe and risky asset.
Suppose for the sake of illustration the fixed supply of the risky asset
is 4/3. The amount of funds depositors have is 10 and the number of
borrowers is 10. In the equilibrium where P = 3, 4 of the borrowers
invest in the risky asset and 6 in the safe in order for the fixed
supply of 4/3 units of the risky asset to be taken up. In this case 40
per cent of borrowers invest in risky assets and 60 per cent invest in
safe assets. A bank's expected payoff from lending one unit is then
given by the following expression.
Bank's expected payoff
= 0.4[0.25 x 1.33 + 0.75 x (1/3) x 1] + 0.6[1.33]
= 1.03
The first term is the payoff to the bank from the 40 per cent of
investors in the risky asset. If the payoff is 6, which occurs with
probability 0.25, the loan and interest is repaid in full. If the payoff
is 1, which occurs with probability 0.75, the borrower defaults and the
bank receives the entire proceeds from the 1/3 unit owned by the
borrower. The bank's payoff is thus (1/3) x 1. The 60 per cent of
investors in the safe asset are able to pay off their loan and interest
of 1.33 in full.
If the banking sector is competitive, the receipts from lending,
1.03, will be paid out to depositors. In this case it is the depositors
that bear the cost of the agency problem. In order for this allocation
to be feasible, markets must be segmented. The depositors and the banks
must not have access to the assets that the investors who borrow invest
in. Clearly, if they did, they would be better off just to invest in the
safe asset rather than put their money in the bank or lend to the
investors. The segmented markets assumption is designed to capture the
fact that an investor like the investment bank Goldman Sachs can year
after year earn a much higher return on its equity than the return an
average individual can make. Even if the individual is willing to take
the same risk, she cannot earn the same expected return as Goldman Sachs
because they have much better access to some markets.
Credit and interest rate determination
The quantity of credit and the interest rate have so far been taken
as exogenous. These factors are incorporated in the example next to
illustrate the relationship between the amount of credit and the level
of interest rates. The simplest case to consider is where the central
bank determines the aggregate amount of credit B available to banks. It
does this by setting reserve requirements and determining the amount of
assets available for use as reserves. For ease of exposition it is
simply assumed the central bank sets B. The banking sector is
competitive. The number of banks is normalised to 1 and the number of
investors is also normalised to 1. Each investor will therefore be able
to borrow B from each bank.
The safe asset pays a fixed return r to the investor: if x is
invested in the safe asset at date 1 the return is rx at date 2. The
safe asset can be interpreted in a number of ways. One possibility is
that it is debt issued by the corporate sector. The investors treat the
rate of return as fixed because they are small relative to the size of
the corporate sector. In equilibrium, competition will ensure that the
rate of return on the bonds is equal to the marginal product of capital.
The return on the safe asset is determined by the marginal product
of capital in the economy. This in turn depends on the amount of the
consumption good x that is invested at date 1 in the economy's
productive technology to produce f(x) units at date 2. The total amount
that can be invested is B and the amount that is invested at date 1 in
the risky asset since there is 1 unit is P. Hence the date 1 budget
constraint implies that
x = B - P.
It is assumed
(1) f(x) = [3x.sup.0.5] = 3[(B - p).sup.0.5].
Provided the market for loans is competitive, the interest rate r
will be bid up by investors until it is equal to the marginal product of
investment,
(2) r = f'(B - P) = 1.5[(B - p).sup.-0.5].
At this level the safe asset will not yield any profits for
investors. If it were lower than this there would be an infinite demand
for the safe asset and if it were higher than this there would be zero
demand.
The amount the investors will be prepared to pay for the risky
asset assuming its payoffs are as in table 1 is then given by
0.25(1/P x 6 - r) + 0.75 x 0 = 0.
Using (2) in this,
P = 4[(B - p).sup.0.5].
Solving for P gives
(3) P = 8(-1 + [square root of 1 + 0.2SB]).
When B = 5 then P = 4 and r = 1.5. The relationship between P and B
is shown by the solid line in chart 1. By controlling the amount of
credit, the central bank controls the level of interest rates and the
level of asset prices. Note that this relationship is different from
that in the standard asset pricing model when the price of the risky
asset is the discounted expected payoff,
[P.sub.F] = 2.25/r.
This case is illustrated by the dotted line in chart 1. A
comparison of the two cases shows that the fundamental is relatively
insensitive to the amount of credit compared to the case where there is
an agency problem. Changes in aggregate credit can cause relatively
large changes in asset prices when there is an agency problem.
Financial risk
The previous section assumed that the central bank could determine
the amount of credit B. In practice, the central bank has limited
ability to control the amount of credit and this means B is random. In
addition there may be changes of policy preferences, changes of
administration, and changes in the external environment which create
further uncertainty about the level of B. This uncertainty is
particularly great in countries undergoing financial liberalisation. In
order to investigate the effect of this uncertainty an extra period is
added to the model. Between dates 1 and 2 everything is the same as
before. Between dates 0 and 1 the only uncertainty that is resolved is
about the level of B at date 1. Thus between dates 0 and 1 there is
financial uncertainty. The uncertainty about aggregate credit B at date
1 causes uncertainty about prices at date 1. Given that investors are
borrowing from banks at date 0 in the same way as before this price
uncertainty again leads to an agency problem and risk shifting. The
price of the risky asset at date 0 will reflect this price uncertainty
and can lead the asset price to be even higher than at date 1.
Suppose that there is a 0.5 probability that B = 5 and a 0.5
probability that B = 7 at date 1. Then using (2) and (3) the prices and
interest rates are as shown in table 3.
The pricing equation at date 0 is
0.5(1/[P.sub.0] x 5.27 - [r.sub.0]) + 0.5 x 0 = 0,
where [r.sub.0], the date 0 interest rate, is given by (2) with B
and P replaced by [B.sub.0] and [P.sub.0]. Substituting for [r.sub.0]
and simplifying
[P.sub.0] = 5.27/1.5[([B.sub.0] - [P.sub.0]).sup.-0.5].
Taking [B.sub.0] = 6 and solving for [r.sub.0] and [P.sub.0] gives
[r.sub.0] = 1.19
[P.sub.0] = 4.42.
As when the uncertainty is due to variations in asset payoffs, the
greater the financial uncertainty the greater is [P.sub.0]. Consider a
mean preserving spread on the financial uncertainty so that table 3 is
replaced by table 4.
In this case it can be shown
[r.sub.0] = 1.27
[P.sub.0] = 4.61.
The risk shifting effect operates for financial risk in the same
way as it does for asset payoff risk. Although the expected payoff at
date 2 is only 2.25, the price of the risky asset at date 1 in the last
case is 4.61. The possibility of credit expansion over a period of years
may create a great deal of uncertainty about how high the bubble may go
and when it may collapse. This is particularly true when economies are
undergoing financial liberalisation. As more periods are added it is
possible for the bubble to become very large. The market price can be
much greater than the fundamental.
These examples illustrate that what is important in determining the
risky asset's price at date 0 is expectations about aggregate
credit at date 1. If aggregate credit goes up, then asset prices will be
high and default will be avoided. However, if aggregate credit goes
down, then asset prices will be low and default will occur. The issue
here is what is the dynamic path of aggregate credit? The point is that
the expectation of credit expansion is already taken into account in the
investors' decisions about how much to borrow and how much to pay
for the risky asset. If credit expansion is less than expected, or
perhaps simply falls short of the highest anticipated levels, the
investors may not be able to repay their loans and default occurs. In
Allen and Gale (2000a) it is shown that even if credit is always
expanded then there may still be default. In fact it is shown that there
are situations where the amount of credit will be arbitrarily close to
the upper bound of what is anticipated and widespread default is almost
inevitable.
Discussion
A simple example has been developed where a borrower chooses the
type of investments (safe or risky) and the lender is unable to observe
how the funds are invested. As in Jensen and Meckling (1976) and
Stiglitz and Weiss (1981), these assumptions imply there is a risk
shifting problem. By buying risky assets, the borrower can shift
downside risk onto the lender, but retains the right to any upside returns. The more risky the asset, the more attractive it becomes. When
a significant proportion of investors in the market have these
incentives, the equilibrium asset price will be high relative to the
'fundamental' value of the asset, which is defined as the
price that would obtain in the standard asset pricing model where
everybody is investing his own wealth. The difference between the
equilibrium price and the fundamental value is the 'bubble'.
Two factors are particularly important in determining the size of the
bubble. One is the amount of credit that is available to finance
speculative investment. The other is the degree of uncertainty in the
market. The greater is either of these factors, the greater is the
bubble.
The relationship between credit and asset prices is relatively
straightforward in real estate markets. An expansion of credit reduces
the interest rate at which investors can borrow and this in turn
increases the prices they are willing to pay. In stock markets, the
relationship is more subtle. Margin restrictions imply that only a
proportion of the total investment can be financed with borrowed funds.
However, if credit expands, investors may be willing to borrow a greater
amount against the houses, cars, and other assets they buy and put more
money into intermediaries such as mutual funds. As explained above, the
incentives that money managers face are similar to those that would be
created if the money were directly borrowed and, again, asset prices
will be bid up as a result.
The relationship between credit and asset prices becomes even more
complex in a dynamic context. In deciding how much he should pay for an
asset today, an investor will consider the future price of the asset and
the possibility of capital gains. The future price will depend in part
on the level of credit that is anticipated in future periods. If an
expansion of credit is anticipated, asset prices are likely to rise and
this expectation will feed back into current prices. Thus, it is not
only current credit expansion but anticipated future expansion that
feeds the bubble in asset prices.
There is another aspect of future credit expansion that has a
direct impact on current asset prices. It is unlikely that the future
level of credit can be perfectly anticipated. There may in fact be a
great deal of uncertainty about future credit expansion. This arises
from factors such as the central bank's limited ability to control
the amount of credit, changes of policy preferences, changes of
administration, and changes in the external environment, all of which
may alter the amount of credit that will be created. The more
uncertainty that is associated with future credit, the more uncertain
future asset prices will be. Because of the risk shifting problem,
uncertainty makes assets more attractive to the debt financed investor,
and this results in a higher asset price and a larger bubble.
The theory thus predicts that bubbles will tend to occur when the
current credit levels are high, when future credit levels are expected
to be higher, and when future credit levels are expected to be
uncertain. This is consistent with the fact that many asset bubbles
associated with recent crises were preceded by financial liberalisation.
In the Scandinavian countries, there was a move away from restricted
financial systems towards market oriented ones. This led to an immediate
expansion in credit and also considerable uncertainty about the future
level of credit. In Japan, the Government continually eased regulation
on banks and the financial markets throughout the 1980s. Similar
deregulation occurred in many emerging economies, such as Mexico and the
South East Asian economies.
The second phase of the financial crisis involves the bursting of
the bubble and a collapse in asset prices. In some of the episodes
recounted in the Introduction, it appears that the collapse was
precipitated by a real shock. An example is the collapse in oil prices
that triggered the bursting of the bubble in Norway. In other cases, the
crisis appears to have been triggered by an event in the financial
sector. A good example is Japan's tightening of credit in 1990,
which precipitated the collapse in asset prices.
The effect of a real shock is easy to understand. Anything that
affects the health of the businesses that make up the economy will
clearly have a direct impact on asset prices. Furthermore, uncertainty
about these factors will lead to uncertainty about stock prices. The
effect of a financial shock is more complex.
The model in Allen and Gale (2000a) suggests that a critical
determinant of asset prices is the expected value and the volatility of
credit expansion. In many cases financial liberalisation leads to an
expansion of credit which feeds a bubble in asset prices. These higher
prices are in turn supported by the anticipation of further increases in
credit and asset prices. Any faltering of this cumulative process may
cause the bubble to burst and lead to a financial crisis. What is
critical is the relationship between actual and expected credit
expansion. Since anticipated expansion has been built into current asset
prices, continued expansion is required to allow speculators to repay
their debts. In fact, a positive level of credit expansion may be
required to prevent the bubble from bursting. Allen and Gale (2000a)
call a credit regime robust if there is no financial crisis as long as
the level of credit does not contract. A fragile regime is one in which
credit is actually required to expand at a positive rate in order to
prevent a financial crisis. It is fairly easy to construct examples of
fragile regimes. In fact, examples can be constructed where an
arbitrarily high rate of credit expansion is necessary to prevent a
crisis. In this case, the probability of a crisis is close to one.
The third phase of the crisis occurs after asset prices have
collapsed. At this stage there will be widespread default and the
banking system will come under severe strain. If the fall in asset
prices is not too large, the banking system may be able to survive
intact. However, in more extreme cases either many banks will fail and
be liquidated or the Government will be forced to step in and rescue the
banks. For small countries there may also be a currency crisis as the
Government is forced to choose between lowering interest rates to save
the banking system or raising them to protect the exchange rate. Even if
rates are raised there may still be an exodus of capital. A moderate
increase in interest rates may not be sufficient to prevent capital
flight because of the weakened state of the banking system and the
uncertainty that often accompanies financial turbulence.
Perhaps the most important aspect of the third phase is the
spillover of the financial crisis into the real economy. In practice,
financial crises are often associated with a significant fall in output
or at least a reduction in the rate of growth. Output fell dramatically
in the South East Asian economies that were subject to crises. This was
also the case in the Scandinavian countries. However, the Scandinavian
countries quickly rebounded. In Japan, although the initial effect of
the 1990 crash was relatively mild, growth has been depressed for a long
period of time and the situation has continued to deteriorate.
3. Theories of financial instability
Banking crises
There are two traditional views of banking crises. One is that they
are random events, unrelated to changes in the real economy. The
classical form of this view suggests that crises are panics and are the
result of 'mob psychology' or 'mass hysteria' (see,
for example, Kindleberger, 1978). The modern version, developed by
Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and others, is that bank runs are
self-fulfilling prophecies. Given the assumption of first-come,
first-served and costly liquidation of some assets, there are multiple
equilibria. If everyone believes that a banking panic is about to occur,
it is optimal for each individual to try to withdraw her funds. Since
each bank has insufficient liquid assets to meet all of its commitments,
it will have to liquidate some of its assets at a loss. Given
first-come, first-served, those depositors who withdraw initially will
receive more than those who wait. On the one hand, anticipating this,
all depositors have an incentive to withdraw immediately. On the other
hand, if no one believes a banking panic is about to occur, only those
with immediate needs for liquidity will withdraw their funds. Assuming
that banks have sufficient liquid assets to meet these legitimate
demands, there will be no panic. Which of these two equilibria occurs
depends on extraneous variables or 'sunspots'. Although
sunspots have no effect on the real data of the economy, they affect
depositors' beliefs in a way that turns out to be self-fulfilling.
When there are multiple equilibria sunspots provide one way to
select the equilibria that will occur. However, this approach is not
very satisfactory since the equilibrium that is selected is essentially
arbitrary. In an important paper, Morris and Shin (1998) show how the
global games approach can be used to select an equilibrium in the
context of currency crises. The approach relies on there being a lack of
common knowledge about fundamentals. Goldstein and Pausner (2005) and
Rochet and Vives (2004) have shown how a similar approach can be used to
select a unique equilibrium in the context of banking crises.
An alternative to the view that banking crises are panics is that
they are a natural outgrowth of the business cycle. An economic downturn
will reduce the value of bank assets, raising the possibility that banks
are unable to meet their commitments. If depositors receive information
about an impending downturn in the cycle, they will anticipate financial
difficulties in the banking sector and try to withdraw their funds. This
attempt will precipitate the crisis. According to this interpretation,
panics are not random events but a response to unfolding economic
circumstances.
A number of authors have developed models of banking panics caused
by aggregate risk. Wallace (1988; 1990), Chari (1989) and Champ, Smith,
and Williamson (1996) extend Diamond and Dybvig (1983) by assuming the
fraction of the population requiring liquidity is random. Chari and
Jagannathan (1988), Jacklin and Bhattacharya (1988), Hellwig (1994), and
Alonso (1996) introduce aggregate uncertainty which can be interpreted
as business cycle risk. Chari and Jagannathan (1988) focus on a signal
extraction problem where part of the population observes a signal about
future returns. Others must then try to deduce from observed withdrawals
whether an unfavourable signal was received by this group or whether
liquidity needs happen to be high. Chari and Jagannathan are able to
show panics occur not only when the outlook is poor but also when
liquidity needs turn out to be high. Jacklin and Bhattacharya (1988)
also consider a model where some depositors receive an interim signal
about risk. They show that the optimality of bank deposits compared to
equities depends on the characteristics of the risky investment.
Building on the empirical work of Gorton (1988) and Calomiris and
Gorton (1991) that nineteenth century banking crises were predicted by
leading economic indicators, Allen and Gale (1998) develop a model that
is consistent with the business cycle view of the origins of banking
panics. In their model, crises can improve risk sharing but they also
involve deadweight costs if they cause projects to be prematurely
liquidated. A central bank can avoid these deadweight costs and
implement an optimal allocation of resources through an appropriate
monetary policy. By creating fiat money and lending it to banks, the
central bank can prevent the inefficient liquidation of investments
while at the same time allowing optimal sharing of risks.
Contagion and financial fragility
The prevalence of financial crises has led many to conclude that
the financial sector is unusually susceptible to shocks. One theory is
that small shocks can have a large impact. A shock that initially
affects only a particular region or sector, or perhaps even a few
institutions, can spread by contagion to the rest of the financial
sector and then infect the larger economy. There are a number of
different types of contagion that have been suggested in the literature.
The first is contagion through interlinkages between banks and financial
institutions. The second is contagion through asset prices in financial
markets. De Bandt and Hartmann (2002) contains a survey of this
literature.
Banks are linked in several ways including payments systems and
interbank markets. These linkages can lead to a problem of contagion. We
start by considering models of payment system contagion. Building on a
locational model of payment systems developed by McAndrews and Roberds
(1995), Freixas and Parigi (1998) have considered contagion in net and
gross payment systems. In a net payment system banks extend credit to
each other within the day and at the end of the day settle their net
position. This exposes banks to the possibility of contagion if the
failure of one institution triggers a chain reaction. In a gross system
transactions are settled on a one-to-one basis with central bank money.
There is no risk of contagion but banks have to hold large reserve
balances. A net payment system is preferred when the probability of
banks having low returns is small, the opportunity cost of holding
central bank money reserves is high, and the proportion of consumers
that have to consume at another location is high. Freixas, Parigi and
Rochet (2000) use this model to examine the conditions under which
gridlock occurs. They show that there can be gridlock when the
depositors in one bank withdraw their funds, anticipating that other
banks cannot meet their netting obligations if all their depositors have
also withdrawn their funds. Rochet and Tirole (1996a) consider the role
of the too-big-to-fail policy in preventing contagion.
Allen and Gale (2000b) focus on a channel of contagion that arises
from the overlapping claims that different regions or sectors of the
banking system have on one another through interbank markets. When one
region suffers a banking crisis, the other regions suffer a loss because
their claims on the troubled region fall in value. If this spillover
effect is strong enough, it can cause a crisis in the adjacent regions.
In extreme cases, the crisis passes from region to region and becomes a
contagion. Lagunoff and Schreft (2001) study the spread of crises in a
probabilistic model. Financial linkages are modeled by assuming that
each project requires two participants and each participant requires two
projects. When the probability that one's partner will withdraw
becomes too large, all participants simultaneously withdraw and this is
interpreted as a financial crisis. Van Rijckeghem and Weder (2000)
document linkages through banking centers empirically. Rochet and Tirole
(1996b) use monitoring as a means of triggering correlated crises; if
one bank fails, it is assumed that other banks have not been properly
monitored and a general collapse occurs.
There are a number of papers that consider contagion through
financial markets. King and Wadhwani (1990) considered a situation where
information is correlated between markets. Price changes in one market
are perceived to have implications for asset values in other markets.
Kodres and Pritsker (2000) use a multi-asset rational expectations model
to show how macroeconomic risk factors and country-specific asymmetric
information can combine to produce contagion. Kyle and Xiong (2001)
present a model of contagion in financial markets due to the existence
of a wealth effect.
The notion of financial fragility is closely related to that of
contagion. When a financial system is fragile a small shock can have a
big effect. The shock may be spread by contagion. A financial crisis may
rage out of control and bring down the entire economic edifice. The
memory of the Great Depression and earlier crises is still with us and
it powerfully reinforces belief in financial fragility. Financial
multipliers are modelled by Kiyotaki and Moore (1997). In their model,
the impact of illiquidity at one link in the credit chain travels down
the chain and has a big impact. Chari and Kehoe (2000) show that herding
behavior can cause a small information shock to have a large effect on
capital flows.
4. Policy issues
The theories of crises outlined above raise at least two important
public policy issues. The first is how bubbles in asset prices can be
prevented. The second is how to deal with the banking system and
minimise the loss of output after an asset bubble has occurred and
precipitated a banking crisis. Each of these is discussed in turn.
Although it has long been recognised that there is a link between
monetary policy, inflation and asset prices, there has only recently
been an active debate concerning the extent to which central banks should target asset prices. The standard analysis of the link between
stock prices and inflation suggests that when the money supply is
increased, prices and wages will in the long run increase in line with
the standard quantity theory of money. Depending on the relative speeds
of adjustment of prices in the output and input markets, profits and
hence stock prices can be increased or decreased by inflation. The
empirical evidence suggests that a rise in inflation (realised, expected
or unexpected) reduces stock prices. This type of theory does not
provide much guidance to central banks in how to target asset prices
beyond suggesting that if inflation is controlled asset prices will be
determined by fundamentals.
The theory outlined in Section 2 provides a rather different
perspective on the relationship between monetary policy and asset
prices. The theory emphasises the importance of the level and volatility
of credit for asset price determination and thus provides an important
role for monetary policy and the reserve requirements of banks in
preventing the development of bubbles in asset prices. Governments and
central banks should try to avoid unnecessary expansion of credit as
well as unnecessary uncertainty about the path of credit expansion. This
suggests that financial liberalisation is a particularly risky exercise,
as experience confirms (see also empirical work surveyed in
Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache, 2005, this volume). In a liberalisation
regime, credit tends to increase dramatically and, because there is no
experience with the new regime, uncertainty also increases
significantly. If financial liberalisation is to be undertaken, it
should be done slowly and carefully. To the extent possible, the central
bank should make clear how the volume of credit will evolve over time.
The second policy issue concerns how the Government should
intervene to deal with problems caused by a banking crisis and minimise
the spillovers into the real economy. The collapse of a bubble can cause
a significant debt overhang. The value of the option to continue
together with the difficulty of liquidating loans for their fair value
means that banks will try to remain in business as long as possible. In
order to maintain levels of capital consistent with regulation, banks
will reduce the volume of new loans and this will lead to a credit
crunch. Goodhart (2005, this volume) discusses how the new Basel 2 rules
may aggravate this problem. The reduction in output and the further
negative impact this will have on the creditworthiness of other
borrowers can lead to a significant reduction in output. To offset these
negative effects, the Government can try to recapitalise the banking
system. This can involve direct infusions of funds or outright
nationalisation of the banking system. A comparison of Scandinavia and
Japan provides an interesting contrast between swift intervention in
Scandinavia and the noninterventionist attitude of the Japanese
Government. In the Scandinavian countries, swift intervention and
recapitalisation of the banking systems lead to quick recoveries. In
contrast in Japan, the hesitation to intervene has resulted in an
economy that has stagnated for well over a decade.
Designing policies to prevent the adverse consequences of financial
instability is one of the most important tasks facing policymakers.
Understanding the causes of financial instability is an important
prerequisite to the design of such policies. This remains a crucial and
ongoing area of research.
Table 1. The basic example
Asset Supply Investment at date 1 Payoff at date 2
Safe Variable I 1.5
Risky I P R = 6 with prob. 0.25
= 1 with prob. 0.75
ER = 2.25
Note: All agents in the model are assumed to be risk neutral.
Table 2. A mean-preserving spread of the basic
example
Asset Supply Investment at date 1 Payoff at date 2
Safe Variable I 1.5
Risky I P R = 9 with prob. 0.25
= 0 with prob. 0.75
ER = 2.25
Table 3. The basic example extended to include
financial risk
Probability B P r
0.5 5 4 1.5
0.5 7 5.27 1.14
Table 4. A mean-preserving spread of the example
extended with financial risk
Probability B P r
0.5 4 3.14 1.81
0.5 8 5.86 1.03
REFERENCES
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (1998), 'Optimal financial
crises'. Journal of Finance, 53, pp. 1245-84.
--(2000a), 'Bubbles and crises', Economic Journal, 110,
pp. 236-55.
--(2000b), 'Financial contagion', Journal of Political
Economy, 108, pp. 1-33.
--(2003), 'Asset price bubbles and stock market
interlinkages', in Hunter, W., Kaufman, G. and Pomerleano, M.
(eds), Asset Price Bubbles, MIT Press, pp. 323-36.
--(2004), 'Asset price bubbles and monetary policy', in
Desai, M. and Said, Y. (eds), Global Governance and Financial Crises,
London, Routledge, pp. 19-42.
Allen, F. and Gorton, G. (1993), 'Churning bubbles',
Review of Economic Studies, 60, pp. 813-36.
Allen, F., Morris, S. and Postlewaite, A., (1993), 'Finite
bubbles with short sale constraints and asymmetric information',
Journal of Economic Theory, 61, pp. 206-29.
Alonso, I. (1996), 'On avoiding bank runs', Journal of
Monetary Economics, 37, pp. 73-87.
Calomiris, C. and Gorton, G. (1991), 'The origins of banking
panics, models, facts, and bank regulation', in Hubbard, G. (ed.),
Financial Markets and Financial Crises, Chicago, IL, University of
Chicago Press, pp. 109-173.
Champ, B., Smith, B. and Williamson, S. (1996), 'Currency
elasticity and banking panics: theory and evidence', Canadian
Journal of Economics, 29, pp. 828-64.
Chari, V. (1989), 'Banking without deposit insurance or bank
panics: lessons from a model of the U.S. national banking system',
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 13(Summer), pp.
3-19.
Chari, V. and Jagannathan, R. (1988), 'Banking panics,
information, and rational expectations equilibrium', Journal of
Finance, 43, pp. 749-60.
Chari, V. and Kehoe, P. (2000), 'Financial crises as
herds', working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
De Bandt, O. and Hartmann, P. (2000), 'Systemic risk: a
survey', in Goodhart, C. and Illing, G. (eds), Financial Crises,
Contagion, and the Lender of Last Resort, Oxford, Oxford University
Press, pp. 249-97.
Diamond, D. and Dybvig, P. (1983), 'Bank runs, deposit
insurance, and liquidity', Journal of Political Economy, 91, pp.
401-19.
Drees, B. and Pazarbasioglu, C. (1995), 'The nordic banking
crises: pitfalls in financial liberalization?', Working Paper
95/61, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Frankel, J. (1993), 'The Japanese financial system and the
cost of capital', in Takagi, S. (ed.), Japanese Capital Markets:
New Developments in Regulations and Institutions, Oxford, Blackwell, pp.
21-77.
Freixas, X. and Parigi, B. (1998), 'Contagion and efficiency
in gross and net interbank payment systems', Journal of Financial
Intermediation, 7, pp. 3-31.
Freixas, X., Parigi, B. and Rochet, J. (2000), 'Systemic risk,
interbank relations and liquidity provision by the central bank',
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 32, pp. 611-38.
Goldstein, I., and Pauzner, A. (2005), 'Demand deposit
contracts and the probability of bank runs', Journal of Finance
(forthcoming).
Gorton, G. (1988), 'Banking panics and business cycles',
Oxford Economic Papers, 40, pp. 751-81.
Heiskanen, R. (1993), 'The banking crisis in the Nordic
countries', Kansallis Economic Review, 2, pp. 13-19.
Hellwig, M. (1994), 'Liquidity provision, banking, and the
allocation of interest rate risk', European Economic Review, 38,
pp. 136389.
Jacklin, C. and Bhattacharya, S. (1988), 'Distinguishing
panics and information-based bank runs: welfare and policy
implications', Journal of Political Economy, 96, pp. 568-92.
Jensen, M. and Meckling, W. (1976), 'Theory of the firm:
managerial behavior, agency cost and ownership structure', Journal
of Financial Economics, 3, pp. 305-60.
Kindleberger, C. (1978), Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of
Financial Crises, New York, NY, Basic Books.
King, M. and Wadhwani, S. (1990), 'Transmission of volatility
between stock markets', Review of Financial Studies, 3, pp. 533.
Kiyotaki, N. and Moore, J. (1997), 'Credit chains',
Journal of Political Economy, 105, pp. 211-48.
Kodres L. and Pritsker, M. (2002), 'A rational expectations
model of financial contagion', Journal of Finance, 57, pp. 768-99.
Kyle, A. and Xiong, W. (2001), 'Contagion as a wealth
effect', Journal of Finance, 56, pp. 1401-40.
Lagunoff, R. and Schreft, S. (2001), 'A model of financial
fragility', Journal of Economic Theory, 99, pp. 220-64.
McAndrews, J. and Roberds, W. (1995), 'Banks, payments and
coordination', Journal of Financial Intermediation, 4, pp. 305-27.
Mishkin, F. (1997), 'Understanding financial crises: a
developing country perspective', Annual World Bank Conference on
Development Economics 1996, Washington, DC, The International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development, pp. 29-61.
Morris, S. and Shin, H. (1998), 'Unique equilibrium in a model
of self-fulfilling currency attacks', American Economic Review, 88,
pp. 587-97.
Rochet, J. and Tirole, J. (1996a), 'Interbank lending and
systemic risk', Joumal of Money, Credit and Banking, 28, pp.
733-62.
--(1996b), 'Controlling risk in payment systems', Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking, 28, pp. 832-62.
Rochet, J. and Vives, X. (2004), 'Coordination failures and
the lender of last resort: was Bagehot right after all? ', Journal
of the European Economic Association, 2, pp. 1116-47.
Stiglitz, J. and Weiss, A. (1981), 'Credit rationing in
markets with imperfect information', American Economic Review, 71,
pp. 393-410.
Tschoegl, A. (1993), 'Modeling the behavior of Japanese stock
indices', in Takagi, S. (ed.), Japanese Capital Markets: New
Developments in Regulations and Institutions, Oxford: Blackwell, pp.
371-400.
Van Rijckeghem, C. and Weder, B. (2000), 'Spillovers through
banking centers: a panel data analysis', IMF Working Paper
WP/00/88, Washington, D.C., International Monetary Fund.
Wallace, N. (1988), 'Another attempt to explain an illiquid banking system: the Diamond and Dybvig model with sequential service
taken seriously', Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly
Review, 12(Fall), pp. 3-16.
--(1990), 'A banking model in which partial suspension is
best', Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review,
14(Fall), pp. 11-23.
White, E. (1990), Crashes and Panics: The Lessons from History,
Homewood, IL, Dow Jones Irwin.
Franklin Allen, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. e-mail:
allenf@wharton.upenn.edu