首页    期刊浏览 2024年09月21日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Commentary: pensions and pensions policy.
  • 作者:Broadbent, Simon ; van de Ven, Justin ; Weale, Martin
  • 期刊名称:National Institute Economic Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0027-9501
  • 出版年度:2005
  • 期号:July
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:National Institute of Economic and Social Research
  • 摘要:For many years the British system of a relatively frugal contributory state pension combined with funded occupational and personal pensions appeared relatively successful. Pensioners' incomes grew faster than average earnings, although some people did better than others--anyone relying upon the Basic State Pension (BSP) saw a steady erosion of their position. People who had changed jobs a lot, and many women, also did poorly. In retrospect this 'golden age' seems to have been something of a fool's paradise. Unusually and unsustainably high investment returns (and hence annuity rates) allowed pension schemes to meet their obligations while running up surpluses and even taking contribution holidays. Looking ahead, it must be assumed that real investment returns will be closer to the long-term rate of growth of the economy and that life expectancy will rise and with it the number of pensioners. Any new arrangements will have to embody some combination of the three changes mentioned above.
  • 关键词:Pensions;Private banking

Commentary: pensions and pensions policy.


Broadbent, Simon ; van de Ven, Justin ; Weale, Martin 等


The Pensions Commission is to make its recommendations on pension policy reform later this year, in the light of comments on the challenges identified in its first Report. Widespread agreement on the need for such reform is partly a consequence of problems which have already surfaced, such as the insolvency of some pension schemes, moves to curtail benefits and mis-selling scandals. However the main impetus comes from the fact, clearly demonstrated by the Pensions Commission (2004), that for pensioners to enjoy the current relative standard of living in fifty years time will require people either to (i) retire later (ii) save more; or (iii) pay higher taxes. In the Commission's view the key issues are to find a consensus on the appropriate combination of these three, or of the alternative of lower pensioner incomes, and to find ways of bringing about such an outcome. We focus on aspects of such a reform and suggest one measure which could be implemented without further ado.

For many years the British system of a relatively frugal contributory state pension combined with funded occupational and personal pensions appeared relatively successful. Pensioners' incomes grew faster than average earnings, although some people did better than others--anyone relying upon the Basic State Pension (BSP) saw a steady erosion of their position. People who had changed jobs a lot, and many women, also did poorly. In retrospect this 'golden age' seems to have been something of a fool's paradise. Unusually and unsustainably high investment returns (and hence annuity rates) allowed pension schemes to meet their obligations while running up surpluses and even taking contribution holidays. Looking ahead, it must be assumed that real investment returns will be closer to the long-term rate of growth of the economy and that life expectancy will rise and with it the number of pensioners. Any new arrangements will have to embody some combination of the three changes mentioned above.

Pensions and the Government

It may seem self-evident why the Government should prescribe the structure of the pension system in great detail. Pensions are, after all, the largest single item of public expenditure, even before tax incentives to encourage private provision are taken into account. At the very least these resources need to be efficiently deployed. But this requires a clear view of the most basic question: why have a pension system at all? In today's society, people can expect to spend a lengthy period of their lives in retirement. The fact that this is expected, however, means that individuals can presumably plan for it. One may take the view that the issue of when during their lives an individual chooses to spend their income is not very different from the issue of what they choose to spend their money on at any one time. The state does not interfere to any great extent in the latter decision so why should it need a policy over the former?

There are three obvious answers to this question. First, it is not politically feasible for the state to wash its hands of people who reach retirement with inadequate savings or pensions, however clearly they have been urged to save for themselves. The conclusions of the Commission's first report demonstrate the failure of policy that leaves people to make their own arrangements. For more than twenty years, people have known that the Basic State Pension (BSP) was linked to prices rather than wages. The very elderly have seen their pensions fall relative to wages as a result, but have not been in a position to do much about it. People who are now reaching retirement age, however, have had plenty of time to adjust their savings in light of price indexation, and in many cases have not done so. It is possible that they believed (correctly) that the pension regime would become more generous by the time that they reached retirement, as it has done with the introduction of the Pension Credit (PC).

A variant of this answer is that we need a pension system because people do not understand or wish to think about the financial consequences of retirement, and so need state assistance and perhaps a degree of compulsion to make adequate provision for themselves.

A second need for pensions arises from the fact that some people have low lifetime incomes and are therefore not in a position to save for their retirement. It has become increasingly clear that policymakers need to think in terms of individuals rather than couples in assessing lifetime incomes, and that therefore many women, because they have worked only part-time or not at all, fall into this category. Of course, if people have low lifetime incomes, then it is not necessary to defer helping them until they have reached retirement age. A possible justification for delaying support until retirement is that people's lifetime incomes are known more precisely after retirement than at the start of their working lives. Although this argument may seem persuasive, it is complicated by the potential for associated behavioural responses during the working lifetime (e.g. that people face reduced incentives to work while of working age if they know that the Government will support them in retirement).

Thirdly, there is the question of whether any generation should receive pensions worth more than their contributions (including appropriate interest) at the expense of their successors. If this is the case, then the pension scheme should be designed to transfer resources to the related cohorts from future generations. This distributional question is closely related to the second point referred to above, and is consequently associated with many of the same issues. It is also possible to argue that such a policy is justified if there is an expectation of rising living standards, as was the case when the current pension system was introduced. In such circumstances, it may seem reasonable that children collectively should contribute to supporting their parents.

In general then, a pension scheme can be designed to fulfil three basic functions: it can transfer resources from people's working lives to their retirement, it can transfer resources from people with high lifetime incomes to people with low lifetime incomes (or vice versa), and it can transfer resources between generations. Desirable pension policy reform depends on views regarding these three redistributive issues, and differences between the various proposals that have been suggested often reflect different attitudes towards the three motivated by self-interest.

The pension credit and means testing

Means testing is, in essence, an arrangement whereby a benefit, such as the pension credit, is targeted at people in particular need, usually because without the benefit they have low incomes. It is tapered so that it is withdrawn from people as their incomes rise. In essence the taper is equivalent to a high rate of income taxation on people with low incomes. If means testing is reduced (see Appendix), by replacing some or all of the pension credit with a universal benefit, then the gainers are the people who currently do not receive much of the pension credit because of the means test. Within a fixed expenditure on pensions the cost has to be met by reducing the amount of the benefit paid before the means test, in which case poor people suffer.

Not surprisingly, the need for such a revision tends to be justified by the beneficiaries not because it makes them better off but on the grounds that means testing is a disincentive to building up private wealth. This is not as obviously true as it might seem. The means test has a substitution effect because it is, in effect, a tax on the marginal consumption of the retired people who face it. As such it is indeed a disincentive to save. But it also has an income effect; people who face the means test receive lower retirement incomes than they would in its absence. This income effect is an incentive to save. It is by no means clear which effect will dominate, although work at the National Institute based on a simulation model (Sefton and van de Ven, 2004) suggests that replacing the pension credit with a universal benefit of equal cost will actually lead to lower average private wealth holding in the long run (see chart 1). The effect on the wealth holding of the top income quintile is particularly pronounced. A reversion to the Minimum Income Guarantee with its more pronounced means testing has the effect of raising pension saving relative to the pension credit.

While these distributional arguments suggest that there is a strong case for maintaining means testing, there is nevertheless a powerful argument against. This is that means-tested benefits are often not claimed by the people who are entitled to them and who may be those most in need of help. We see this as the most powerful argument for finding a way to avoid means testing even if it results in greater deadweight costs.

Private pensions

Properties of different pension schemes

In addition to the various changes which may take place to public sector pensions, the Government cannot avoid the question of private retirement saving. Many people with private pension schemes have been disappointed recently. In some cases occupational pensions have failed to deliver expected benefits, often because employers have become bankrupt while their pension funds were in deficit. In other cases people have saved for their own pensions; they have earned lower returns than they had hoped and also had to face declining annuity rates.

Schemes in which pensions are linked to final salary or sometimes peak salary are seen by many people as the gold standard of the pension system. Nevertheless they embed major injustice. Final salary schemes pay high pensions to people retiring on high salaries with long contribution records. They thus give poor deals to people who change jobs and often also to people who stay with one employer but whose careers do not prosper, If one regards pensions as being earned by a combination of employers' and employees' contributions, the return to someone retiring on a high salary must be high compared with the average return to the fund. Since this has to be paid for somehow it follows that the return to someone retiring on a low salary is poor compared with the return to the fund. Salaries are skewed, with a few high earnings and many low earners and the dispersion increases as people age. Thus the median earner receives a return below the market return on his/her pension contributions; with the same contributions a pension with a closer link to contributions might offer a better deal. It should be noted that this particular abuse is much reduced if only high-paid employees (e.g. executive directors) have access to the defined-benefit scheme. Nevertheless, final salary schemes mean that individuals' pension prospects are affected by career risk.

Of course occupational pension schemes may offer defined benefits even if those benefits are linked to contributions rather than to final salary, and in that sense there is no clear distinction between a defined benefit and a defined contribution scheme. The latter tend to reduce the career risk faced by scheme members. Reforms to the Civil Service pension scheme proposed in March 2005, moving from a final salary pension to a career average pension were, given unchanged contributions, plainly fairer than the present system to the average employee. They were opposed by the trade unions representing them. A part of the support for final salary schemes may be simply that people assume that if their employers want to change conditions of employment it must be a bad idea.

Defined benefit schemes, whether final salary or linked to average salary, reduce the market risk that employees face and raise that faced by employers when compared to defined contribution schemes. The latter are subject to uncertainty about both market rates of return and, when employees come to retire, annuity rates. In essence, with defined benefit schemes employees receive not only their pension contributions but also a form of insurance. This is not shown in their salaries but is, on the face of it, a real cost to employers (1) and an additional factor behind the recent closures of final salary schemes. A failure of actuaries to price this insurance was one of the factors contributing to the pensions fools' paradise from which the country is only now emerging. Employers were not paying for the benefits employees believed they would receive. That employers who close final salary schemes not only aim to shed the burden of this unpriced risk but also want to reduce the contributions that they actually make is a ready explanation of why, in most cases, trade unions are rational in opposing such changes. But, as we have noted with the Civil Service, trade unions can also oppose changes when they are in the interests of the majority of their members.

Defined contribution schemes exist largely because of the tax reliefs offered to people who save in them. This has a number of consequences. One has been that the charges levied by pension fund managers, and particularly those at the retail level, have been high compared with those imposed on other forms of investment such as unit trusts and investment trusts. The industry justifies this with the observation that the costs of running retail accounts are high. Certainly the development of low-cost pension savings arrangements (such as internet-based self-invested pension policies) has not put rapid downward pressure on costs in other parts of the market. Salop and Stiglitz (1977) offer some interesting insights into why normal competition might not be felt in the financial services industry; the continuing existence of suppliers with high fees and high charges may be explained by the fact that many people have difficulty in understanding the nature of the products that they are buying. It is not surprising that pension funds argue for policy changes which will increase the attractions of investment in their products (e.g. by increased tax reliefs). Equally an important aspect of government policy should be to address these market imperfections so as to reduce these deadweight transactions costs.

Compulsion

An important question arises whether contributions to private sector pensions should be compulsory. This is followed by a more sterile debate about whether both employers and employees should be compelled to contribute. The second debate is sterile because it is very difficult to imagine that compulsory contributions are paid out of anything except wages whether they are collected from employers or employees. To the extent that this is also true with our voluntary system, employees have less to lose from changes in employer contribution rates than they perhaps believe. It is, moreover, erroneous to believe that compulsion 'would not work'. The fact is that part of the pensions system is already compulsory. People who go out to work are obliged either to contribute to the second state pension or to contract out by joining a private scheme.

A major benefit of compulsion as compared to the present voluntary arrangements is that the costs are much lower, at least for lower earners. Stakeholder pensions have charges of 1.5 per cent per annum of the value of the fund for the first ten years of its life, falling to 1 per cent per annum after that. The cost of running a compulsory fund would be likely to be around 0.3 per cent per annum Since the charges have to be paid out of a gross real return of perhaps 5 per cent per annum this difference is very important. Whether investment is compulsory or voluntary, people should have some choice about the way in which their contributions are invested. Equity funds are likely to give poor returns in some periods; the difficulties associated with this would be avoided if investors also had the choice of a fund investing in index-linked stock. There is a separate question about the propriety of obliging people to contribute to a pension scheme when the consequence of this is that they lose means-tested benefits. But actually such a concern is simply the more general issue whether it is appropriate to have high effective marginal tax rates on relatively poor people and the issue is best addressed in the context of an overall review of the tax and benefit system to establish overall principles about how to structure it so as to balance the various goals of efficiency, redistribution and financial soundness. One does not hear people arguing that they should not contribute to the basic state pension because they have some other resources and the basic pension is therefore, in effect, means tested.

United States proposals and transactions costs

At this point is its worth noting the reforms proposed to the United States Old Age Pension arrangements proposed by Mr Bush (Bush, 2005). He is attracted by the high average returns earned on stock market investments and the belief that funding old age would be cheaper if social security (i.e. national insurance) contributions were invested in the stock market rather than supporting the current pay-as-you-go scheme. Bush has rightly noted that the Government can operate a very efficient collection system and does indeed collect taxes very cheaply.

Under his scheme people will be able to contribute up to 4 percentage points of their payroll taxes (with an upper limit fixed initially at US$1000 per annum but rising steadily over time) into individual accounts which can be invested in five low-cost broadly-based funds. At the age of forty-seven, the default option is to move the fund gradually from investments seen as high risk/high return to those seen as low risk/low return; individuals and their spouses can, however, jointly waive this. Participation is voluntary in that people can choose to stay with the existing arrangements but it is plainly hoped that the higher returns on offer will encourage them to contract out of the existing scheme and into this new funded scheme.

The document is vague on detail but the presumption is that the fund built up is intended to replace existing Social Security (as Old Age Pensions are known in the United States). The risk that funds will deliver lower benefits than existing Social Security is to be mitigated by the portfolio restructuring which takes place on reaching the age of forty-seven. It is nevertheless not clear from the document what happens if the fund ends up unable to deliver benefits as large as those under the existing Social Security scheme. In any case, it must be questionable whether a contribution rate of only 4 percentage points of payroll taxes will lead to a satisfactory level of retirement income, let alone, as the document suggests, create something beyond this.

Nevertheless, there is a very positive aspect to the scheme. The costs of running the scheme are estimated to be only 0.3 per cent of fund value, (2) as compared to the 1.5 per cent with UK stakeholder schemes. This low cost is made possible through the use of the tax system to collect contributions and is based on a saving scheme already available to US Government employees.

If public resources are to be deployed in encouraging saving, it is almost certainly much better for them to be deployed in making available the tax system as a means of facilitating contributions to private schemes than in extending tax benefits available to private pensions, say by reintroducing dividend tax credits. The first reduces social transactions costs by making a cheap and efficient technology more widely available. The second would raise expenditure on deadweight transactions costs.

Rising and uncertain life expectancy

It is often argued that increasing life expectancy makes pensions expensive and that uncertainty about future life expectancy compounds the problem. These observations are both true but, without the benefit of numbers which underpin them, it is impossible to form a view about how important they are. A focus on life expectancy overstates the impact of living longer on pension costs because the extra payments which fall due arise quite a long way in the future and are discounted.

Assuming an index-linked rate of return of 1.5 per cent per annum, a fair 100 [pounds sterling] annuity for a man aged sixty-five pays an income of 7.43 [pounds sterling] per annum based on the death rates shown in the Government Actuary's current life table. This reflects current death rates rather than projections of the death rates of current sixty-five year olds as they age. It suggests a life expectancy for a man now aged sixty-five of 16.6 years, If all death rates up to the age of 100 fall to half current levels, then the life expectancy rises to 22.2 years and the fair annuity rate falls to falls to 5.69 [pounds sterling] per annum. These figures compare with quoted rates (Financial Times, 2 July) ranging from 4.74 [pounds sterling] to 5.18 [pounds sterling]. Thus current annuity rates may already take account of very substantial reductions in death rates, and/or build considerable allowance for uncertainty into their pricing. However, they may also reflect the fact that people who have saved for pensions tend to live longer than average.

While private pensions face the question of life expectancy risk, pay-as-you-go schemes additionally face the risks associated with uncertain fertility rates. In some countries these are now as low as 1.2 children per woman. Such rates, if maintained, have a much greater impact than does increasing life expectancy on the number of retired people to be supported by people of working age and thus on the burden imposed by a pay-as-you-go pension scheme. Sweden has addressed this problem by linking the values of pay-as-you-go pensions to GDP at retirement. A small population of working age implies a low GDP. Thus the demographic risk is borne by the retiring cohort rather than those currently of working age. Such an arrangement benefits those born in the distant future relative to those already alive, when compared to pensions linked to wages. But it does not impose much risk on people within say twenty years of retirement because the size of the cohort of working age up to twenty years ahead is known with reasonable accuracy. The relevant people have already been born. It remains to be seen whether such arrangements can actually be sustained in the more distant future if Sweden experiences very low fertility for any length of time.

If one could be confident that low fertility rates were temporary, then instead of leaving the implications of this to be carried by pension recipients, as in the Swedish scheme, it would be more satisfactory to spread the burden by means of public borrowing, If the gap between receipts and payments arising from a small cohort of working age is financed by borrowing, then the burden is in effect imposed on the whole of the future instead of on just one cohort. But such a policy helps current generations at the expense of future generations if low fertility rates in fact turn out to be permanent. Thus debt finance imposes extra risk on people who have no choice about whether they bear it or not.

A role for National Savings

Returning to the question of whether pension arrangements are designed mainly to ensure everyone has at least a basic standard of living in retirement, or to reallocate incomes within people's lifetimes, our own view is that the first issue should be the primary purpose of pension arrangements. This means that tax relief or its equivalent should be directed towards the first tranche of retirement saving whether or not that is compulsory; at the same time the Government should facilitate saving in safe media.

One means of delivering this would be through a National Savings product which would combine a safe index-linked rate of return, similar to that on index-linked debt, with an additional contribution from the Government for people who invest in this medium. The additional contribution would probably be fixed at a rate between those generated by relief at the standard and higher rates of income tax. This, combined with an upper limit to contributions, would ensure that the scheme was directed at its primary purpose--provision of a basic standard of living in retirement rather than, as with the current arrangements, tax reliefs which are worth more to high tax payers than to low tax payers. Contributions could be collected through the tax system in order to keep costs low. The scheme would be complemented with the introduction of Government annuities, again sold through National Savings.

The proposal has a number of attractions. It provides a simple guaranteed product. Transactions and running costs will be considerably lower than with many private sector schemes. And it allows tax relief to be focused. From a macroeconomic perspective, this is just another form of government borrowing and one tailored to meet the needs of savers. To the extent that people save for their retirement in a National Savings pensions scheme other forms of government borrowing will be reduced.

Conclusions

Ministers have talked of the need for a consensus on pensions. It is not clear that they are in any hurry to act on the issue. For some changes no doubt a consensus would be needed. Since many changes have both winners and losers, establishing such a consensus is likely to be difficult. But those changes which reduce transactions costs, by making the technology of the PAYE tax system available to savers or which increase choice, through introducing index-linked products sold by National Savings, do not obviously require a consensus. Slow progress with wholesale reform on issues such as means testing or changes to the structure of tax relief need not be an obstacle to the introduction of changes which reduce costs and increase choice.

Appendix: winners and losers from means testing

The way in which means testing generates both winners and losers can be seen from the diagram below. On the horizontal axis we plot income before taxes and benefits and on the vertical axis income after taxes and benefits. The effects of two tax/benefit regimes are shown. The line CC' shows the effects of a regime with a universal benefit. The position of point C shows the value of the benefit. The line CC' has a slope of less than 45 degrees because each household keeps less than 1 [pounds sterling] of every [pounds sterling] that they earn, since taxes are needed to pay for both the benefit and for other government spending.

With means testing the line CC' is replaced by the kinked line DD'. The value of the benefit is D, but the first segment of the line is shallow, reflecting the fact that households do not keep much of the first tranche of their incomes as a result of means testing. Once their pre-tax/ benefit income rises to B the means tested component of the benefit has been completely withdrawn. Beyond this point they keep a higher proportion of their income than with the universal benefit because the scheme is cheaper to operate and thus requires lower taxes. Thus the second segment of the line is steeper than with a universal benefit scheme.

It is plain from the positions of the two lines that people whose pre-tax/benefit income is less than A are better off with means testing than with universal benefit. So too are those with incomes higher than B*. They keep more of their income because the means testing regime is cheap.

Those with incomes in the range AB* are worse off with means testing than without it. However only those with incomes less than B face a disincentive to save as a result of means testing. People with incomes higher than B face a stronger disincentive to save in the absence of means testing because the tax rate is higher. Income effects mean that people with incomes below A or higher than B* have less incentive to save when means-tested retirement benefits are available than when they are not, while the reverse is true for people in the range AB*.

It might be thought that the effects of the higher tax needed to pay universal benefits can be avoided if the retiring age is raised, effectively leaving everyone better off with the universal benefit scheme. Poor people will undoubtedly have to work longer with such an arrangement. But if there is a universal benefit the total retirement income of rich people will be higher than in the presence of means testing; they receive the universal benefit while they did not receive the means-tested benefit. Thus, if anything, they will be able to retire earlier than in the presence of means testing.

NOTES

(1) Occupational pension schemes providing defined benefits have historically been invested largely in equities because these give higher returns. But, if the market is efficient, the risk adjusted return is the same as that on indexed government debt (Cantor and Sefton, 2003). Since the employer is bearing the risk, the difference between the two rates of return can be seen as an additional cost borne by the employer.

(2) Although Diamond (1998) may imply a slightly higher cost.

REFERENCES

Bush, G. (2005), Strengthening Social Security for the 21st Century, http://www.whitehouse.gov/infocus/social-security/200501/ socialsecurity.pdf

Cantor, A.C.M. and Sefton, J.A. (2002), 'Economic applications to actuarial work: personal pensions and future rates of return', British Actuarial Journal, 8, pp. 91-131.

Diamond, P. (1999), 'Administrative costs and equilibrium charges with individual accounts', NBER Working Paper No. 7050.

Pensions Commission (2004), Pensions Challenges and Choices, http:/ /www.pensionscommission.org.uk/

Salop, S. and Stiglitz, J. (1977), 'Bargains and ripoffs. A model of monopolistically competitive price dispersion', Review of Economic Studies, 44, pp. 493-510.

Sefton, J.A. and van de Ven, J. (2004), 'Does means testing exacerbate early retirement?', National Institute Discussion Paper No. 244.

Wolf, M. (2005), 'A shameful pensions confidence trick', Financial Times, 1 July.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有