Annualised hours contracts: the way forward in labour market flexibility?
Bell, David N.F. ; Hart, Robert A.
Under annualised hours' contracts (AHCs), workers and
management agree to the length and scheduling of working hours over a
12-month period. Such contracts have been widely seen as a potentially
important way of achieving greater labour market flexibility and
enhanced efficiency in work organisation. There exists very little
empirical work on these contracts and this study is intended to provide
insights into their British labour market role and potential. Especially
for workers who are not in management or a profession, the costs of
switching to AHCs are substantial. The enterprises that are likely to
gain from the switch are those that (a) experience significant
fluctuations in output/service demand and (b) desire to utilise plant
and space more intensively over the calendar year. In this latter
respect, plants incorporating complex shift operations are particularly
associated with AHCs.
Introduction
The standard contract of employment of most full-time workers
(excluding managers and professionals) in Britain and Europe stipulates
a common pattern of weekly working hours. Individuals are required to
work a five-day week and each working day is comprised of a specified
number of basic hours. Where hours are insufficient to meet work
requirements, additional labour service is usually provided through the
mechanism of paid-for overtime working. Contracts often cover explicitly
the terms and conditions of overtime working. Of course, the standard
contract is not all pervading. There exists a spectrum of hours'
contracts that range from relatively small variations on the standard
contract to quite radical work arrangements designed significantly to
increase work flexibility. One of the biggest departures--and the one
highlighted in this paper--is the so-called annualised hours'
contract (henceforward, AHC). Here, workers and management agree to the
length and scheduling of working hours with respect to a 12-month
period. In recent years, several well-known British firms have switched
from standard weekly/monthly hours contracts to AHCs. There is strong
evidence that a significant reason for these contract changes is that
AHCs offer a higher degree of hours' flexibility both with respect
to inter-temporal demand changes and the achievement of greater annual
plant utilisation. But is this the start of an important trend in
working time arrangements? We attempt to assess the costs and benefits
of AHC arrangements and hence their prospects for growth.
The British history of AHC agreements is relatively short. They
were not established until the late 1980s, following much earlier
developments among several French, German and Scandinavian companies
(Gall, 1996). By 2001, AHCs covered about 4 per cent of both full-time
female and full-time male British workers. One of the key reasons for
recent interest in AHCs derives from the fact that a number of
well-known manufacturing, service and public sector organisations have
adopted them, at least in respect of parts of their workforces (Incomes
Data Services 1996 and 1999). BP Chemicals, Britvic Soft Drinks, Blue
Circle Cement, ICI Chlor Chemicals, Grampian University Hospitals NHS
Trust, Manchester Airport, United Distillers, Samsung Electronics, Tesco
Stores and Zeneca are among the companies that have negotiated AHCs.
Most are in the private sector, although local government also has
strong representation. Between 1997 and 2001, over 65 per cent of AHCs
covering male workers were in the private sector and 15 per cent were in
local government. The respective figures for females are 42 and 33 per
cent.
The advent of AHCs can be viewed in the context of the debate on
labour market flexibility. Vickery and Wurzburg (1996) argue that in
response to competitive forces, many large firms have adopted new forms
of working that emphasise more efficient workplace organisation,
individualisation of rewards and greater skills. This has resulted in a
blurring of the distinction between functional and numerical labour
market flexibility. Though AHCs change the structure of working time and
therefore could be described as a form of numerical flexibility, they
are rarely implemented without contingent functional reorganisation.
Where AHCs are introduced, they generally replace the standard
contract. A typical AHC is one where management and workers agree on a
basic number of annual, or rostered, hours. Leaving aside holidays,
rostered hours may be distributed evenly over working weeks or they may
be higher than average for parts of the year and lower at other times.
They may also refer to rostered shift systems: we later give an example
of a company with 1872 annual rostered hours designed to cover 156
12-hour shifts. As well as rostered hours, it is not uncommon for the
parties to agree an annual number of reserve hours. These additional
hours may be directed towards enhancing production and service
flexibility beyond that achieved through rostered work scheduling. For
example, they can be used as a buffer to meet unforeseen events such as
short-run upward surges in demand or abnormal absenteeism due to
sickness. They can also be used to provide time to cover planned events
that are supportive of, but not directly tied-up with, production and
service activities. Examples include training courses, planning meetings
and company briefings. The relative proportion of these reserve hours
varies greatly from company to company. While exact requirements are
usually not known a priori, it is important that the firm is able to
formulate reasonably precise estimates of the length of reserve hours.
This is because agreements often guarantee payment whether such hours
are worked or not. Under AHCs, wages are paid weekly or monthly in the
same way as under the standard contract.
What are the perceived benefits of AHCs? Bell and Hart (2002) list
a wide range of potential benefits accruing to workers and firms
operating under AHCs. Among these, we highlight the following. On the
workers' side, risk averse individuals may perceive benefits from
guaranteed annual hours since these provide less income variability
compared with, say, weekly hours that include significant overtime
working. They would also be expected to receive a higher hourly wage
rate as compensation for agreeing to provide abnormal work scheduling
within rostered hours and/or reserve hours at short call. Workers'
marginal utility of leisure is likely to vary over the day/week/year.
Annualised contracts may better match these preferences, thereby
enhancing job satisfaction and commitment. For example, workers may be
happy to work relatively long hours in autumn/ winter/spring thereby
concentrating more leisure time in the summer period. On the firm's
side, annual hours may be better geared to matching the timing of
specific production requirements over the work year (e.g. implementing a
continuous production process, minimising inventories of intermediate
inputs and finished goods, meeting regular seasonal patterns of demand).
AHCs may permit a better annual utilisation of plant--with associated
gains in capital and organisational efficiencies--by extending the
number of working days in a given 12-month period. They may also
facilitate the use of complicated shift working systems since annual
hours can be scheduled to accommodate complex working time rotations.
Reserve hours may be used to facilitate systematic employee training
programmes, thereby enhancing human capital. Finally, through the use of
AHCs, firms may be able to eliminate a culture in which
'guaranteed', or institutionalised, overtime is habitually worked.
In assessing the potential contribution of AHCs, we evaluate their
main costs and benefits. Our principal data source is the British Labour
Force Survey (LFS). Details are given in the Appendix together with an
explanation of why, in large part, we use information obtained only from
direct (and not proxy) LFS respondents. Apart from standard contracts,
we concentrate on four additional types of contract for comparative
purposes. The first two of these are structurally very similar to the
standard contract. The four and a half day week, is a simple variant of
the standard contract that usually involves finishing work early on
Fridays. Closely related is the nine-day fortnight that involves workers
having one day off every other week. (The actual day may vary but the
alternation of a four-day week following a five-day week does not.)
Term-time working typically involves school and college teachers with
work time designed to cover students' prescribed terms or
semesters. Under flexible working hours' contracts, workers can
vary their daily start and finish times. Working time is subdivided into
accounting periods--usually four weeks or calendar months--and debit or
credit hours can be carried over from one period to another.
When discussing the incidence of AHCs in the following section, we
deal with both males and females. For space reasons, we show results
only for male workers in the analysis presented in subsequent sections.
We report briefly on equivalent female results.
Incidence and job characteristics of AHCs
Charts 1-4 deal with the incidence of AHCs and, so as not to
underestimate their relative importance, we include LFS responses from
both direct and proxy respondents.
[GRAPHICS OMITTED]
Charts 1a and 1b show, respectively, the proportions of the female
and male workforce under the main working agreements for the period
1994Q1 to 2001Q1. We divide standard contract workers into those who
report working zero overtime and those working paid overtime. The
standard contract is clearly dominant, accounting for over 80 per cent
of male and 70 per cent of female workers throughout the period. By
contrast, AHCs accounted for less than 5 per cent of both groups of
workers. The proportion of workers with AHCs fell during the mid-to-late
1990s but has risen slightly in recent years.
Due to an LFS reclassification of occupations in 2001, the
remaining charts and tables on the incidence of AHCs--together with most
of our analytical work--concentrate on seven quarters of data (observed
at twice-yearly intervals--i.e. quarters 1 and 3) from 1997Q1-2000Q1.
Over all industries and occupations during this period, 3.5 per cent of
females and 3.7 per cent of males worked under AHCs. The respective
percentages in the manufacturing sector are 2.7 and 4.1 per cent. By
contrast, 74 per cent of females and 83 per cent of males worked under a
standard contract over this time.
Chart 2 displays the occupational breakdowns of females and males
working annualised hours. The highest incidence is within professional
occupations, where nearly 10 per cent of females and 6 per cent of males
work on AHCs. Elsewhere, there is a reasonably equal incidence of
between 2 and 3 per cent across all occupations. As for industries in
chart 3, the highest incidence of annualised hours for males is in the
extraction industry at 6.5 per cent and for females in the industry
labelled 'other' at slightly less than 5 per cent. The latter
industry is dominated by educational and health services. Note also from
chart 3 that, as with occupations, there is a reasonably strong
incidence of annualised hours across industrial sectors, covering at
least 2 per cent of workers in virtually all industries. As for the
sectoral incidence, chart 4 reveals that local government and university
sectors lead the way in percentages of both genders under annual
contracts. However, these charts are not weighted by industry size. In
fact, 67 per cent of males and 43 per cent of females under annual
contracts work in the private sector.
Table 1 provides information on hourly pay, average hours and
degree of unionisation of (a) all occupations and (b) occupations
excluding managerial/professional workers, who are often explicitly
excluded from AHC agreements. A problem arises when comparing hourly pay
and hours of work between AHC and other workers. Each individual in the
LFS is observed over five consecutive quarterly waves but data on pay
are collected only in wave 5. While weekly or monthly remuneration of
AHC workers tends to be paid in equal increments throughout the year,
agreed actual hours worked may be unevenly distributed. Thus, unlike
standard contracts, recorded per-period pay may not fluctuate in line
with hours worked. In order to counter this potential bias, we limited
our sample to individuals classified as AHC workers for the entire
5-wave period. Their hours and hourly pay were then calculated with
respect to hours averaged over three (and sometimes five) quarters. This
allows us to 'average-out' variations in hours over the work
year due to uneven work scheduling. For consistency, we also followed
the same averaging procedure with respect to unpaid overtime of AHC
workers.
Average hourly pay for workers under annualised hours is higher
than under standard contracts. The wage differentials are particularly
large for female occupations including managers/professionals and for
males excluding managers/professionals. For the latter group, hourly
wages are about 26 per cent higher than in the standard contract without
overtime and about 15 per cent higher than the standard contract
including overtime. Note that this male differential is considerably
narrowed when managers and professionals are added. There are two
reasons for this. First, average wages for male managers/professionals
under standard contracts do not differ greatly from their AHC
equivalents. Second, managers/professionals under AHCs work significant
unpaid overtime compared to these groups under standard contracts
(without overtime). Clearly, unpaid hours serve to deflate the average
hourly wage by entering the denominator but not the numerator of the
hourly wage calculation (see Bell and Hart, 1999).
Only the 'nine day fortnight' and flexitime contracts
offer hourly rates comparable to AHCs. The data do not allow us to
distinguish between actual and effective hourly rates under annualised
hours. Since, on average, some reserve hours are paid for but not
worked, the effective rate per hour worked is almost certainly higher
than shown under the annual contract. The degree of underestimation is
probably slight, however. Of course, these statistics almost certainly
reflect differences in occupation, skill and industry, factors we
control for subsequently.
Weekly hours excluding overtime under AHCs are roughly comparable
to those of standard contracts that involve no overtime. Note, however,
that excluding managers and professionals, male total AHC hours are more
than male standard hours under standard contracts with overtime hours,
the latter involve considerably more weekly overtime. Total weekly hours
(i.e. standard plus overtime) under the standard contract with overtime
exceed total AHC hours (44.5 compared to 41.2). The latter observation
is also true for comparable females but the gap is much narrower.
The switch from a standard to an annual hours contract invariably requires that management and workers involve themselves in complex
negotiations over time and work organisation together with appropriate
pay scales. It would be expected that such agreements are more easily
undertaken if the workforce is unionised. If a firm perceives advantages
in adopting an AHC, then a necessary condition for it to alter its
working time practices is the presence of a unified bargaining mechanism
with its workforce. The complexity of agreeing to particularly changes
in work schedules under AHCs requires that each party possesses the
ability to deliver agreement on radical departures from standard
practices on behalf of its constituency. We might expect that the more
unionised the workforce, the better the chances of the parties to effect
the required changes. From table 1 we see that there is considerably
more union representation of males with annual contracts than with
standard and most other contracts. For females, unionisation under AHCs
is also higher than under standard contracts while equal to or lower
than other contracts. We note from later results (see table 4), that the
probability of undertaking an AHC is increased if the firm is unionised.
We also conducted three probit regressions (Bell and Hart, 2002)
into the effects of type of contract and other variables on the length
of employment, job search and job status. They indicate that, relative
to a standard contract, jobs held under AHCs are characterised by
longevity (with significantly more employees in the same job for five
years or more), stability (relatively insignificant numbers looking for
a new job), and permanency (significantly more workers with permanent
job status). Further, we undertook a multinomial logit regression
analysis designed to examine non-permanent job status--covering seasonal
work, contract length, agency temping, casual work and other temporary
employment. We found that AHCs are relatively weakly negatively
associated with working time agreements that represented limited
contract duration and casual employment.
Costs
Apart from the transitional costs of switching contracts, an AHC in
the steady state would be expected to involve relatively high hourly
wage costs. Anticipating later findings, suppose that an AHC is designed
to provide greater flexibility in the scheduling of hours over the
working year. This may be attained, for example, by splitting hours into
a regular core component and a flexible reserve component. In this
event, it can be shown formally that--within the context of an efficient
bargain between management and workers--agreement will be reached in
which the hourly wage is higher and per-period hours shorter under an
AHC compared to a standard contract (Bell and Hart, 2002). In effect, a
union increases its share of the rent by giving management more degrees
of freedom to schedule hours outside the typical workweek arrangement
under the standard contract. This rent extraction is predicted to take
two forms. Not only would the average hourly wage rate be expected to
rise but also the total number of per-worker hours in the working year
would be expected to fall in an AHC compared to a standard contract.
Combining these two effects, average hourly wage earnings would rise.
In order to test more systematically for hourly earnings
differences, we estimated Mincer-type wage equations in which the
dependent variable is average hourly earnings. Hours in the wage
calculation include basic hours, paid overtime and unpaid overtime. We
differentiate between occupations including and not including managers
and professionals. There are two reasons for this. First, while the
incidence of AHCs is relatively high among professionals and managers
(see chart 2), many AHC agreements are struck only with respect to
workers outside of these two groups. In fact, the great majority of the
case studies presented by Incomes Data Services (1999 and 2002) exclude
managers and professionals. Second, although subject to collective
bargaining agreements, AHCs under consideration here concern hours'
scheduling determined by the employer. Other annual hours'
configurations may entail significant elements of self-determined hours
scheduling (albeit within boundaries laid down by the employer). In
particular, managers and professionals may have substantial degrees of
freedom over how and when they allocate their hours. To the extent that
such arrangements are coded as AHCs in the LFS questionnaires, they may
serve to introduce measurement error into the analysis.
Results are shown in table 2. Data refer to full-time male workers.
The omitted category in the dummies that describe contract type is the
standard contract with zero overtime. Other variables are familiar to
this type of equation. They include (a) the human capital variables
tenure (length of time in the current job) and experience (current age
minus age when completed full-time education) as well as pre-work
educational attainment, (b) union status, (c) company descriptors (size,
sector), (d) household characteristics (marital status, children), (e)
other controls (industry and year).
Taking all occupations together, the average hourly wage under an
AHC is estimated to be (statistically) the same as under a standard
contract without overtime. However, excluding managers and
professionals, the average hourly wage is found to be significantly
higher--in fact, 12.9 per cent higher--than the standard contract
without overtime. Reasons for the differences with and without
managers/professionals are discussed in relation to table 1. When
managers and professionals are excluded, the wage under the standard
contract with overtime is 1.6 per cent higher than the excluded
contract. So, excluding managers/professionals, the average hourly wage
under an AHC arrangement is estimated to be around 11 per cent higher
than the standard contract with overtime.
There exists little comparative evidence for these wage estimates.
Interestingly, however, we know that our estimates that exclude managers
and professionals are representative of at least one specific case study
(Incomes Data Services, 1999). ICI Chlor Chemicals introduced AHCs for
all employees in 1993. Employees who were previously weekly-paid
received a 14 per cent increase in basic salary in return for agreeing
to more flexible work practices under the AHC agreement.
In general, our remaining results in table 2 conform to findings of
other studies into wage determination. Experience, tenure and size of
company exert a positive influence on the wages. Given that the excluded
education dummy refers to degree-level qualifications, our education
dummies are significantly negative. Single males earn less than their
married, separated or divorced counterparts. Finally, hourly earnings of
males with no children or children over the age of five are lower than
for males with young children under five.
We also estimated equivalent regressions for females. In general
terms, results are quite similar to males. In respect of estimated wage
effects, females wages under AHCs were estimated to by 10 per cent
higher than under the (excluded) standard contract with zero overtime
including managers/professionals--and 20 per cent higher excluding
managers/professionals--but with relatively low t-ratios (1.57 and 1.12,
respectively).
Benefits
In the introduction, we listed a number of potential benefits to
management of workers converting to annual contracts. For some of these,
such as the provision of more training programmes and the elimination of
guaranteed overtime, Bell and Hart (2002) find little supporting
evidence for substantial benefits. In the latter case, guaranteed
overtime is clearly an important phenomenon (see also Bell and Hart,
2003). Moreover, Incomes Data Services provides case studies supporting
the notion that some firms have regarded AHCs as providing the means to
move away from an overtime culture. But, this explanation alone is
insufficient inducement for making a switch in contract. Paid overtime
is rarely available to managers and professional workers. While the high
marginal costs of overtime can be eliminated, expected average hourly
wages are significantly higher for these workers under AHCs (see the
discussion in relation to table 2). In other words, there would be an
expected total payroll increase if overtime workers under a standard
contract were to switch to an AHC.
It is in two other areas--dealing with demand variation and better
plant utilisation--that real benefits are most apparent. We concentrate
on these.
(1) Demand variation
One possible factor associated with the adoption of annual
contracts is that of demand fluctuation. We might expect that AHCs are
associated with companies that experience a relatively unpredictable
flow of demand for their products. The argument is relatively simple.
Consider a manufacturing firm that carries out make-to-stock production.
It faces a well-established and systematic demand pattern throughout the
working year and gears its production activity to maintain an inventory
of finished goods that is adequate to meet the regular flow of products
leaving the factory. A priori, this type of production experience would
be expected to be associated with a standard contract (with little or no
overtime), or one of its close derivatives. There would be no reason to
have recourse to a compensation system that emphasised premium payments
in order to meet irregular work demands. Alternatively, consider a
company with production scheduling that is geared to make-to-order.
Again, if the flow of orders is predictable, exhibiting relatively low
variation, it may be able to meet demand at lowest cost via a standard
contract. However, if unforeseen fluctuations in demand occur quite
commonly then it may have to pay for additional hours on a regular
basis. This could involve the use of paid overtime and/or the employment
of temporary workers and/or the use of subcontractors. Each method
involves additional costs. If unexpected demand variations are
particularly large and persistent then the firm may seek to find a
permanent solution through an AHC that incorporates significant
year-by-year reserve hours. A further cost consideration involved with
standard overtime contracts concerns the voluntary nature of paid
overtime. Under standard contracts, shortfalls in labour supply may
occur if the proportions of workers willing to work extra hours do not
satisfy given short-term demand increases. Under AHCs, reserve hours
apply to all contracted workers. For example, Matsushita Electric UK
(Cardiff plant) cited as one of their reasons for implementing an AHC in
1992 as having sufficient working hours to meet peak levels of
production (Incomes Data Services, 1999).
Demand fluctuations associated with the adoption of AHCs may not
necessarily be unanticipated, however. Where firms face uneven product
demand due to seasonal fluctuations, they may also wish to seek AHC
agreements. Reserve hours would be expected to play a particularly
important role in this instance. Workers may well be happy to work
longer hours for part of the year and shorter elsewhere if these fit
better than even-length workweeks with their leisure preferences. For
example, the firm General Domestic Appliances (Peterborough) implemented
an AHC in 1992--involving over one thousand manufacturing employees (60
per cent of the workforce)--and gave as its main reason for switching to
annual hours that it could devise a system that reflected its seasonal
demand pattern (Incomes Data Services, 1999).
Here, we discuss two approaches towards studying relationships
between output fluctuations and types of contracts. First, we establish
whether or not AHC contracts are associated with relatively large
changes in contractual working hours over the working year. Second, we
attempt to ascertain whether AHCs are associated, specifically, with
unanticipated output fluctuations.
The first part of the investigation takes advantage of the limited
panel aspect of the LFS data. If AHC firms were more prone to output
shocks and/or to seasonal demand fluctuations, we would expect workers
in such firms to experience greater than average per-period hours'
changes over the working year. Respondents answer working time and other
questions for up to five successive quarters. The LFS consists of
overlapping cohorts of interviewees with each cohort surviving up to
five quarters. The information on contract type is gathered in quarters
one, three and five while working time questions are asked in every
quarter. If an individual reported that he/she worked on, say, an AHC in
quarters one and three, we infer that an AHC also applied in quarter two
and so we used the working time information for this middle quarter. The
same procedure was applied to quarter four if the individual reported
working under the same contractual arrangement in quarters three and
five. Two types of LFS working time questions were used to measure
hours' variation. First, we used quarter-on-quarter differences in
actual standard hours worked. Second, we took advantage of the LFS
distinction between, in any given quarter, actual standard hours and
usual standard hours worked.
Based on male direct respondents, we then constructed four measures
of hours' changes for each individual for the time observed on the
same contract. These were:
(i) the mean absolute difference in actual hours worked from one
quarter to the next;
(ii) the maximum absolute difference between successive quarters;
(iii) the mean absolute difference between actual standard hours
and usual standard hours within the same quarter;
(iv) the maximum absolute difference between actual and usual
standard hours.
Table 3 shows the results of OLS regressions of each of the above
measures of hours' changes on contract type as well as controls for
industry and company size. The coefficients on the three contracts shown
are expressed relative to the excluded standard contract (with and
without overtime). Firms with AHC contracts are significantly more
associated with (all four measures of) hours' variation than the
standard contract while flexitime and the four-and-a-half day week
display a significantly weaker association. To the extent that
hours' variations are caused by output variations then this
evidence points firmly towards this influence on the formation of AHC
agreements. But does the hours' variation stem from anticipated or
unanticipated output movements?
Establishing that AHCs are associated with relatively strong
contractual annual hours' fluctuations tells us nothing about
whether these derive from anticipated or unanticipated economic events.
In order to investigate the role of the latter, we examined the
associations of contract type and 'surprise' output
fluctuations within manufacturing industries. We obtained gross value
added for manufacturing industries from 1986 to 1997--supplied by the
Office for National Statistics--at the level of 3-digit 1992 industry
codes. We used data on 228 industries. Output variation was measured as
the standard deviation of the deviation from trend of deflated gross
value added calculated over the period 1986-97. Individuals were matched
to the relevant industry code. For regressions not including a union
variable, the data relate to seven quarters (i.e. Q1 and Q3 of each
year). We tested for union effects in the manufacturing using Q3
data--the one quarter for which union information is available.
Manufacturing industry results, based on multinomial logit
regressions, are shown in table 4. The first three columns deal with our
full sample: that is, they cover seven quarters (although they exclude
the union variable). Relative to the excluded standard contract (with
and without overtime), output variation has a significant impact on the
probability of working under an AHC. By contrast, and unsurprisingly,
output fluctuation significantly reduces the probability of adopting 4
1/2 day week contracts relative to a standard contract. It has no
differential effect on flexitime relative to standard contracts.
In the reduced sample, shown in the last three columns of table 4,
we find that unionisation significantly increases the probability of
working under an AHC. Note, however, that the output variable is no
longer significant in the AHC column using this reduced sample.
We summarise briefly the remaining key findings in tables 4. We
find that the probability of working an annualised hours contract,
relative to the base contract, is
(a) positively related to company size;
(b) positively associated with male employees;
(c) higher for workers with lower educational attainments.
We also conducted similar regressions--though without output
fluctuation--for service industries (Bell and Hart, 2002). The
contributions of unionisation and company size in the service sector
were very similar to the results reported in table 4.
(2) Workplace utilisation
Association between AHCs and output variation is one aspect of
hours' flexibility. More important, we believe, is the fact that
AHCs offer enhanced workplace utilisation throughout the working year.
In this dimension, hours' flexibility stems from the fact that AHCs
more readily accommodate unconventional work patterns that are designed
to provide enhanced utilisation of plant, machinery and space. Some
firms are willing to trade-off the higher fixed costs of guaranteed
rostered and reserve hours for the ability to achieve improved plant
utilisation (e.g. complex shift systems) or continuous service delivery
(e.g. hospitals). The claim has been made by several companies that
planning operations over a 12-month period permits detailed organisation
of complex shift working schedules designed to (a) ultilise plant
efficiently and (b) maximise individuals' leisure intervals between
shifts. Three examples are among the case studies covered by Incomes
Data Services (1999). First, Britvic Soft Drinks (Widford Factory)
introduced annual hours in 1997. Total annual hours (running from April
to April) are 2,100 and are made up of 1872 rostered hours and 228
reserve hours. Annual hours were selected on the basis of annual
production time, with an allowance of 15 per cent of this time to cover
changeovers and basic maintenance. The rostered hours cover 156 12-hour
shifts. Workers are 'rostered off' for eleven weeks with a
further 'floating' week deducted from the roster for a
selected week. Second, Devro-Teepak (biomedical and food processing applications), introduced an AHC in 1995. It was designed to extend the
working year from 338 to 355 days by working through the annual summer
shutdown and to moving from a four-shift to a five-shift continental
system. Third, Holliday Dyes and Chemicals implemented an AHC in 1999 in
order to reduce the number of workers on site, introduce teamwork and a
move from five to seven-day production.
Our analysis of the determinants of shiftworking is based on probit
regressions and is shown in table 5. Since no earnings variables are
included, the sample size is substantially enhanced. The results
indicate that, relative to a standard contract (with and without
overtime), shiftworking is significantly positively associated with AHC
arrangements. As we would expect, flexitime and 4 1/2-day week contracts
also display significantly less shiftworking. In a more detailed
breakdown of shiftworking, Bell and Hart (2002) show that the AHC
contract is particularly associated with the more complex continental
shift system, a finding consistent with several of the case studies
reported by Income Data Services (1999 and 2002). Continental shifts
denote three-shift systems that rotate rapidly--e.g. three mornings,
then two afternoons, then two nights. Such shifts are especially
designed to maximise the utilisation of plant on a near-continuous
basis. (We also carried out these shift work regressions for females,
but found no significant association with AHCs. One problem here is that
relatively few females work shifts and we had to deal with relatively
very small samples.)
The picture that emerges concerning shift working is that AHCs
appear to be suited to accommodating complicated male shift patterns
that involve constantly changing configurations of work attendance
through time, interspersed with compensating long (and, often, uneven)
breaks from work. To the extent that this is true, we might expect that
workers under AHCs would be more likely to experience work weeks in
which they worked clusters of shift work days that are of significantly
less duration than continual weekly work periods experienced on standard
and other contracts. This expectation is confirmed by the multinomial
logit regressions presented in table 6. Compared to standard contracts,
AHC workers display a significantly greater propensity to work between 1
and 4 different days per week. (Of the other contracts, only job-share
workers display this tendency.) By contrast, their propensity to work on
six or seven different days does not differ from standard contract
workers. Many workers under AHCs are more likely to work complicated
rotating shift patterns with each shift applying over a relatively short
span of days, interspersed with relatively long rest periods.
The attempt to utilise plant, equipment and space more intensively
over the work year may also be expected to reflect AHC agreements that
involve greater work cover during statutory holidays and weekends.
Evidence that AHC contracts help firms to utilise more working days in
the year in these directions is provided in two probit regressions shown
in table 7. Compared to the standard contract, AHC workers are
significantly more likely to work during bank holidays and on Sundays.
Note that these findings are independent of shift working effects since
the latter variable is one of the controls in these regressions. (As in
the case of shift working, the female-equivalent regressions to those in
table 7 revealed no significant associations with AHCs.)
Assessment
Annual hours' arrangements have drawn increasing interest in
the general debates concerning labour market flexibility and working
time. There is undoubtedly a link between AHCs and the achievement of
hours' flexibility. The fact that a number of major manufacturing
and service companies as well as public sector enterprises have
introduced AHCs in recent years has served to stimulate interest in
their potential for achieving a more adaptable labour market. However,
the take-up of such schemes has been relatively modest, although there
is some indication of recent trend increases (see charts 1a and 1b). The
evidence points to a limited likelihood of future growth. Undoubtedly,
the costs of switching from standard contracts to AHCs may be quite
substantial, especially (given the findings in table 2) for the set of
workers that excludes managers and professionals. Costs include:
(a) time and money costs of evaluating the most suitable AHC
arrangements;
(b) detailed employer-worker negotiations--generally relying on
formal union bargaining agreements--over implementation of the chosen
scheme;
(c) a mark-up in average hourly pay for workers, (excluding
managers and professionals) that is probably in excess of 10 per cent;
(d) likely increases in fixed employment costs since, in the
majority of negotiated contracts, payment for annual rostered and
reserve hours is guaranteed.
What type of firm is willing to incur such costs? The pursuit of
greater hours' flexibility almost certainly lies at the heart of
many decisions to move to annual hours' settlements. We identify
three types of enhanced hours' flexibility offered by AHCs.
(i) Where product or service demand varies systematically over the
working year, as within firms prone to seasonal demand fluctuations,
AHCs may be used to provide hours' supply that better matches the
variations in hours' demand.
(ii) Through holding reserve hours that can be called on at short
notice, AHCs offer firms the ability to respond more effectively to
unexpected fluctuations in product and service demand. The inbuilt advantage compared to conventional overtime working is that the supply
of reserve hours are guaranteed across all workers and not subject to
the whims of individual supply decisions.
(iii) Planning hours over the entire working year offers firms the
ability to design and plan complex shift and other working time patterns
that facilitate a fuller year-round utilisation of plant and other work
facilities.
Future moves towards AHCs will be concentrated among organisations
that perceive the benefits of one or more of the above advantages to
outweigh the high costs of implementation. In such cases, AHCs offer
great potential towards achieving enhanced operational efficiency
through greater labour flexibility. Where future switches towards AHCs
occur, they are likely to involve relatively large companies (see the
results in table 4). It is here, especially, where scale economies and
organisational efficiencies are most likely to derive from the
introduction of complicated work schedules.
Appendix: Labour Force Survey (LFS)
This is a major survey carried out by the Social Survey Division of
the Office for National Statistics (ONS) and provided by the ESRC Data
Archive. It is a household survey. Since spring 1992 the survey has been
carried out quarterly, each quarter containing data on 150,000
individuals. Of these, 80,000 are in employment and 60,000 are in
full-time employment. Information on earnings is also available for 8000
people in 1995, this number rising to 15,000 in 2002. Data are collected
quarterly from March to May (Spring), June to August (Summer) September
to November (Autumn) and December to February (Winter). Each quarter
consists of five waves. Each wave is interviewed in five successive
quarters, such that in any one quarter, one wave will be receiving their
first interview, one wave their second and so on. This gives an 80 per
cent overlap in samples from one quarter to the next. Also it is
possible for any one individual to be observed in five successive
quarters. Earnings data have been available from waves 1 and 5 since
1997Q1. We restrict the earnings information to wave 5 to maintain
compatibility with earlier data and to provide independent observations
for the analysis.
The data used here fall into three groups.
(a) 1994Q1-2001Q1 (see charts 1a and 1b): Because the information
on contract type is only available in the Spring and Autumn quarters,
these data are from the Spring of 1994 to the Spring of 2001--fifteen
quarters in all. To avoid duplicating individuals, only wave S is used
from each quarter.
(b) 1997Q1-2000Q1 (all charts and tables excluding (a) and (c)): in
these data, seven quarters were used, starting in Spring 1997 through to
Spring 2000. Again only wave S data were used.
(c) 1997Q1-2000Q1 panel data (table 3): all the quarters from
Spring 1997 to Spring 2000 were used. However the data were confined to
people who had not changed their job during this period and who had the
same contract type throughout the period. By doing this it was possible
to use the information on hours of work from the two intervening
quarters i.e. summer and winter. In the majority of cases this meant
hours of work information in three successive quarters and for a much
smaller number, five successive quarters.
Proxy respondents and the Labour Force Survey
An important feature of the LFS is that it allows interviewers to
record answers to questions by proxy if a respondent is unavailable.
Proxies account for about 30 per cent of LFS responses. A proxy response
is usually from another related adult who is a member of the same
household, although there are exceptions to this rule: (i) a young
person, of the same household, may translate for a non-English speaking
relative; (ii) a carer, of the elderly or infirm, although not related,
may answer for someone in their care; (iii) anyone can respond by proxy
with the personal permission of the head of household or spouse.
It may well be the case that, in general, the quality of
information provided by proxy respondents is inferior to that given by
direct respondents. Accordingly, we have taken the risk-averse strategy,
for most of the analytical work reported here, of incorporating only the
data provided by direct respondents. We indicate where the exceptions
occur; for example, in the early descriptive material.
Measuring hours of AHC workers
Hourly pay for AHCs is calculated using hours averaged over at
least three quarters, up to a maximum of five quarters. If an individual
was AHC in quarter 1 and quarter 3 and did not change job, it is assumed
that they were also AHC in quarter 2 and therefore we know their hours
in that quarter. For all other contract types, the hours are those as
given in wave 5, i.e. the same quarter that information on pay is
recorded. We excluded all AHC respondents observed for only one quarter.
Table 1. Wages, hours and unionisation by working time
contracts, 1997Q 1-2000Q1
Annualised Standard Standard
hours contract contract
without with
overtime overtime
Males (including managers and professionals and excluding proxy
Hourly pay 10.02 9.42 9.31
Weekly hours (excl. overtime) 40.20 41.79 38.36
Paid overtime hours 1.30 0.00 3.93
Unpaid overtime hours 2.48 0.00 3.08
% union representation 73% 24% 34%
Females (including managers and professionals and excluding proxy
respondents)
Hourly pay 9.91 6.60 7.75
Weekly hours(excl, overtime) 38.10 37.77 36.90
Paid overtime hours 0.58 0.00 1.73
Unpaid overtime hours 6.55 0.00 3.31
% union representation 70% 25% 33%
Males (excluding managers and professionals and excluding proxy
respondents)
Hourly pay 8.62 6.90 7.38
Weekly hours(excluding overtime) 41.51 40.84 38.79
Paid overtime hours 1.51 0.00 5.71
Unpaid overtime hours 0.343 0.00 0.95
% union representation 72% 27% 40%
Males (excluding managers and professionals and excluding proxy
respondents)
Hourly pay 6.21 5.63 6.16
Weekly hours(excluding overtime) 38.15 37.26 36.92
Paid overtime hours 1.74 0.00 2.38
Unpaid overtime hours 0.77 0.00 1.48
% union representation 38% 20% 26%
Four and a Nine day
half day fortnight
week
Males (including managers and professionals is and excluding proxy
Hourly pay 8.56 10.51
Weekly hours (excl. overtime) 37.50 37.13
Paid overtime hours 3.11 3.64
Unpaid overtime hours 0.99 0.47
% union representation 45% 70%
Females (including managers and professionals and excluding proxy
respondents)
Hourly pay 6.18 8.77
Weekly hours(excl, overtime) 37.27 36.90
Paid overtime hours 1.40 1.15
Unpaid overtime hours 0.47 1.47
% union representation 40% 61%
Males (excluding managers and professionals and excluding proxy
Hourly pay 7.31 9.87
Weekly hours(excluding overtime) 37.60 37.50
Paid overtime hours 3.51 3.92
Unpaid overtime hours 0.17 0.21
% union representation 51% 76%
Males (excluding managers and professionals and excluding proxy
respondents)
Hourly pay 5.69 6.75
Weekly hours(excluding overtime) 37.39 36.39
Paid overtime hours 1.37 1.56
Unpaid overtime hours 0.12 0.33
% union representation 38% 48%
Term-time Flexitime
working
Males (including managers and professionals is and excluding proxy
Hourly pay 9.44 10.37
Weekly hours (excl. overtime) 37.92 37.73
Paid overtime hours 0.51 1.41
Unpaid overtime hours 8.01 1.98
% union representation 78% 45%
Females (including managers and professionals and excluding proxy
respondents)
Hourly pay 8.04 7.89
Weekly hours(excl, overtime) 36.32 36.78
Paid overtime hours 0.12 0.80
Unpaid overtime hours 6.82 1.11
% union representation 69% 47%
Males (excluding managers and professionals and excluding proxy
Hourly pay 5.21 7.82
Weekly hours(excluding overtime) 37.64 37.98
Paid overtime hours 1.21 2.10
Unpaid overtime hours 0.71 0.61
% union representation 31% 44%
Males (excluding managers and professionals and excluding proxy
respondents)
Hourly pay 5.56 6.58
Weekly hours(excluding overtime) 33.80 36.77
Paid overtime hours 0.23 0.80
Unpaid overtime hours 1.02 0.42
% union representation 43% 44%
Note: See Appendix for calculation of AHC pay and hours.
Table 2. Determinants of hourly wages (full time
males): LFS 1997Q1-2000Q1
Dependent variable: log hourly earnings.
Excluding proxy respondents
With managers
and professionals
Coefficient t-stat.
Union -0.049 -3.62
Tenure 0.025 13.75
[Tenure.sup.2] 0.000 -8.14
Experience 0.006 9.57
[Experience.sup.2] 0.000 -3.39
Company size >50 0.153 12.63
Private sector -0.015 -0.83
Annualised hours 0.038 0.76
4 1/2 day week -0.010 -2.95
Flexitime -0.018 -0.91
Standard (with o/time) -0.014 -1.10
Other higher
education -0.253 -13.90
A-level, Highers -0.346 -16.82
O-levels -0.397 -24.25
YT certificate -0.470 -19.59
Any other prof. quals. -0.504 -23.66
Married 0.1454 9.66
Separated 0.189 5.88
Divorced O.120 4.91
Widowed -0.002 -0.03
Youngest child
aged 5-11 -0.039 -1.83
Youngest child
aged 12-18 -0.042 -1.84
No children -0.070 -3.98
Sample size 5323
F statistic 80.8
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.34
Other controls industry, year
Without managers
and professionals
Coefficient t-stat.
Union 0.051 2.29
Tenure 0.022 10.48
[Tenure.sup.2] 0.000 -5.55
Experience 0.003 3.71
[Experience.sup.2] 0.000 -3.12
Company size >50 0.080 5.52
Private sector -0.009 -0.21
Annualised hours 0.121 2.20
4 1/2 day week -0.077 -1.92
Flexitime 0.042 2.01
Standard (with o/time) 0.016 2.64
Other higher
education -0.102 -3.67
A-level, Highers -0.230 -7.65
O-levels -0.210 -7.76
YT certificate -0.215 -7.02
Any other prof. quals. -0.291 -9.64
Married 0.139 7.71
Separated 0.174 4.55
Divorced 0.114 4.26
Widowed 0.071 1.01
Youngest child
aged 5-11 -0.035 -1.36
Youngest child
aged 12-18 -0.049 -1.83
No children -0.086 -4.12
Sample size 2816
F statistic 32.1
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.27
Other controls Industry,year
Notes: The excluded variables are non-union, company size<50, public
sector, standard contract with zero overtime, degree, single,
youngest <5.
Table 3. Difference in hours regressions (panel data,
males) LFS 1997Q1-2000Q1 (OLS regressions)(a)
Mean quarter on Maximum difference
quarter difference in in quarter on quarter
basic hours basic hours
Coefficient t Coefficient t
Annualised hours 1.113 263 1.153 1.78
Flexitime -0.406 -1.91 -0.744 -2.29
4 1/2 day week -0.763 -2.42 -1.379 -2.87
Sample size 4848 4848
[R.sup.2] 0.0202 0.0114
Other controls Industry, company size Industry, company size
Mean difference between Maximum difference
usual and actual basic between usual and actual
basic hours basic hours
Coefficient t Coefficient t
Annualised hours 0.989 3.78 1.820 3.09
Flexitime -0.267 -2.03 -0.639 -2.16
4 1/2 day week -0.380 -1.95 -0.989 -2.25
Sample size 4848 4848
[R.sup.2] 0.0120 0.0142
Other controls Industry, company size Industry, company size
Note: (a) Excluding proxy respondents and managers/professionals.
Coefficients are expressed relative to the excluded standard
contract (with and without overtime).
Table 4. Determinants of working time contracts: multinomial logit
regressions, LFS 1997Q1-2000Q1 (a)
Manufacturing Annualised Flexitime
industries hours
RRR t-stat RRR t-stat
Output variation 2.340 2.48 0.788 -0.76
Private 0.889 -1.07 0.283 -24.03
Company size 1.570 6.39 1.535 8.52
Union
Sex 1.395 4.34 0.657 -8.91
Year 1998 0.835 -2.34 0.984 -0.30
Year 1999 0.855 -2.02 0.987 -0.24
Year 2000 1.184 1.91 1.014 0.21
Other higher
education
qualification 1.713 4.13 0.643 -7.39
A-level, higher 2.047 5.13 0.401 -11.09
O-level, SCE 1.961 5.76 0.353 -18.31
YT certificate 2.088 5.55 0.337 -13.82
Other professional/
vocational
qualifications 2.112 5.81 0.313 -14.66
Energy & Water 1.332 2.07 3.205 13.58
Minerals, ores,
metals 1.761 6.57 2.189 10.74
Metal goods,
engineering &
vehicles 0.846 -2.22 1.817 9.79
Construction 0.720 -3.11 2.190 10.74
Other details Sample size = 36199
Log likelihood = -21799.1
Pseudo [R.sup.2] = 0.073
Manufacturing 4 1/2 day week Annualised
industries hours
RRR t-stat RRR t-stat
Output variation 0.314 -3.24 2.088 1.38
Private 0.800 -2.44 0.890 -0.70
Company size 2.157 13.17 1.404 2.92
Union 1.867 6.28
Sex 0.888 -2.26 1.095 0.79
Year 1998 0.912 -1.62 0.890 -1.04
Year 1999 0.906 -1.70 1.132 1.15
Year 2000 0.844 -2.26
Other higher
education
qualification 1.604 5.16 1.332 1.42
A-level, higher 1.499 3.83 1.617 2.22
O-level, SCE 1.576 5.45 1.582 2.57
YT certificate 1.911 6.81 1.622 2.37
Other professional/
vocational
qualifications 1.634 5.18 2.003 3.58
Energy & Water 0.133 -6.57 1.166 0.73
Minerals, ores,
metals 0.539 -5.89 1.822 4.50
Metal goods,
engineering &
vehicles 2.211 14.96 0.899 -0.90
Construction 0.240 -11.41 0.725 -1.90
Other details Sample Sample size - 15714
size = 36199 Log likelihood = -9397.1
Log Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.078
likelihood
= -21799.1
Pseudo
[R.sup.2]
= 0.073
Manufacturing Flexitime 4 1/2 day
industries
RRR t-stat RRR t-stat
Output variation 0.429 -1.68 0.292 -2.29
Private 0.278 -15.87 0.910 -0.67
Company size 1.415 4.51 1.820 6.63
Union 1.180 2.29 1.799 8.09
Sex 0.645 -6.06 0.791 -2.96
Year 1998 1.097 1.24 1.017 0.21
Year 1999 1.074 0.94 1.049 0.59
Year 2000
Other higher
education
qualification 0.618 -5.22 1.425 2.55
A-level, higher 0.422 -6.87 1.330 1.79
O-level, SCE 0.361 -11.63 1.391 2.61
YT certificate 0.323 -9.33 1.621 3.35
Other professional/
vocational
qualifications 0.318 -9.43 1.455 2.63
Energy & Water 2.777 7.72 0.107 -4.92
Minerals, ores,
metals 2.304 7.47 0.518 -4.22
Metal goods,
engineering &
vehicles 1.885 6.74 2.138 9.60
Construction 2.231 7.20 0.248 -7.57
Other details Sample size = 15714
Log likelihood = -9397.
I Pseudo [R.sup.2] = 0.078
Notes: (a) Excluding proxy respondents. Coefficients are expressed
relative to the excluded standard contract (with and without
overtime). (b) The left side of the table excludes the union
variable and is based on quarters 1 and 3 from the Labour Force
Survey. The right side includes union and refers only to quarter 3.
The dependent variable is type of contract and the base category is
the standard contract. The excluded variables are: public companies;
company size<S0; non union; female; 1997; degree; Other manufacturing.
Table 5. Determinants of shiftworking (males
excluding managers/professionals): probit regression
LFS 1997Q1-2000Q1(a)
Including proxy Excluding proxy
respondents respondents
Coefficient t-stat. Coefficient t-star.
Annualised 0.246 4.41 0.300 4.18
Flexitime -0.979 -15.91 -1.022 -13.65
Term-time -0.651 -1.56 -0.987 -1.71
Job share 1.550 1.71
9 day fortnight -0.107 -0.76 -0.054 -0.30
4 1/2 day week -0.657 -9.54 -0.737 -8.24
Zero hours 0.117 0.79 0.055 0.27
Agriculture -1.026 -6.65 -1.146 -4.76
Extraction 0.273 3.28 0.305 2.81
Engin & Veh 0.000 0.00 0.004 0.04
Other Manuf 0.254 3.36 0.262 2.64
Construction -1.217 -13.54 -1.245 -10.20
Distribution -0.142 -1.88 -0.150 -1.50
Trans & Comms 0.242 3.18 0.304 3.05
Finance -0.183 -2.23 -0.245 -2.28
Other 0.136 1.74 0.163 1.61
Year 1998 0.037 1.26 0.039 1.00
Year 1999 0.020 0.70 0.048 1.25
Year 2000 0.055 1.88 0.057 1.47
Company size>50 0.703 30.60 0.702 22.83
Private sector 0.080 2.37 0.050 1.16
Constant -1.053 -13.97 -0.976 -9.86
Sample size 19781 10696
Log likelihood -9845.4 -5619.3
Note: (a) The excluded variables are: standard contract (with
and without overtime); energy & water, 1997; company size<50;
public companies.
Table 6. Number of different days per week
worked (males excluding managers/professionals)--multinomial
logit regressions, LFS 1997Q1-2000Q1
(excluding proxy respondents) (a)
Work 1-4 Work 6 or 7
different days different days
Coefficient t-stat. Coefficient t-stat.
Annualised 1.623 3.15 0.979 -0.18
Flexitime 0.593 -2.30 0.558 -5.34
Term-time 0.837 -0.18 0.417 -1.15
Zero hours 0.492 -0.96 0.886 -0.40
Agriculture 0.540 -0.81 2.539 4.38
Extraction 1.607 1.64 1.162 0.85
Engin & Veh 1.308 1.00 0.851 -1.02
Other Manuf 1.573 1.69 0.836 -1.10
Construction 0.565 -1.65 0.931 -0.43
Distribution 0.816 -0.71 1.126 0.75
Trans & Comms 0.861 -0.54 1.697 3.33
Finance 0.996 -0.01 0.854 -0.93
Other 1.184 0.61 1.086 0.51
Year 1998 1.105 0.92 1.080 1.29
Year 1999 1.084 0.73 0.981 -0.31
Year 2000 1.301 2.48 0.962 -0.63
Company size>50 1.219 2.05 0.764 -5.61
Private sector 1.137 1.06 0.850 -2.34
Shift dummy 5.813 20.18 1.818 12.07
Other details Sample size = 12415
Log likelihood = -9138.5317
Pseudo [R.sup.2] = 0.0575
Note: (a)The excluded variables are: standard contract (with and
without overtime); energy & water; 1997; company size <50; private
companies. The shift dummy had to be imputed. This limited the number
of observations since the pattern of response necessary to form this
variable required information for all five waves in which an
individual might be surveyed.
Table 7. Bank holiday and weekend working (males--excluding managers/
professionals)--probit regressions: 1997Q1-2000Q1 (excluding proxy
respondents)
Worked bank holidays Ever work on a Saturday
Coefficient t-stat Coefficient t-stat
Annualised 0.516 2.33 0.076 0.99
Flexitime -0.510 -2.50 -0.217 -4.19
Term-time 0.250 0.28 -1.108 -3.30
Job sharing -- -- -0.750 -0.76
9 day fortnight -0.113 -0.18 -0.015 -0.09
4 1/2 day week 0.010 0.04 -0.007 -0.01
Zero hours -- -- -0.154 -0.81
Agriculture 0.680 1.51 0.345 2.13
Extraction -0.296 -0.77 -0.132 -1.18
Engin & Veh -0.974 -2.87 -0.259 -2.63
Other Manuf -0.469 -1.36 -0.421 -4.23
Construction -0.401 -1.08 -0.100 -0.97
Distribution -0.134 -0.39 -0.213 -2.13
Trans & Comms -0.019 -0.06 -0.158 -1.55
Finance -0.320 -0.89 -0.530 -5.13
Other -0.089 -0.25 -0.180 -1.77
Year 1998 -- (6) -- -0.036 -1.04
Year 1999 -- -- -0.473 -12.60
Year 2000 -- -- -0.407 -10.79
Company size>50 0.125 1.12 -0.082 2.81
Private sector 0.114 0.73 -0.040 -0.93
Shift dummy 0.951 7.84 0.515 15.06
Constant -0.338 -1.03 0.960 8.82
Sample size 784 10584
Log likelihood -9214.4 -7162.7
Ever work on a Sunday
Coefficient t-stat
Annualised 0.164 2.34
Flexitime -0.228 -4.44
Term-time -0.894 -2.49
Job sharing -0.403 -0.40
9 day fortnight 0.031 0.20
4 1/2 day week 0.055 0.82
Zero hours -0.163 -0.90
Agriculture 0.320 2.33
Extraction -0.470 -4.54
Engin & Veh -0.592 -6.47
Other Manuf -0.716 -7.67
Construction -0.210 -2.22
Distribution -0.617 -6.64
Trans & Comms -0.453 -4.82
Finance -0.605 -6.21
Other -0.132 -1.39
Year 1998 -0.021 -0.65
Year 1999 -0.226 -6.49
Year 2000 -0.240 -6.85
Company size>50 0.073 2.68
Private sector -0.007 -0.19
Shift dummy 0.872 28.17
Constant 0.222 2.44
Sample size 11416
Log likelihood -7790.1
Notes: The excluded variables are: standard contract (with and
without overtime); energy & water; 1997; company size<50; public
sector. Bank holiday details are only available for one quarter
(2000Q1); the first regression, therefore, has no time dummies. None
of the regressions above required hours information, resulting in a
substantial increase in the number of observations. However, bank
holiday and shift questions were asked in different quarters and,
given that the shift dummy was again imputed as in table 5, the number
of observations in the first regression above was limited.
REFERENCES
Bell, D.N.F. and Hart, R.A. (1999), 'Unpaid work',
Economica, 66, pp. 271-90.
--(2002), 'Annualised hours' contracts', ESRC main
report, under Grant R 000 22 3442.
--(2003), 'How important is guaranteed or institutionalised
overtime?', (mimeo) Department of Economics, University of
Stirling.
Gall, G. (1996), 'All year round: the growth of annual hours
in Britain', Personnel Review, 25, pp. 35-52.
Incomes Data Services (1996), Annual Hours, Study 604, London.
--(1999) Annual Hours, Study 674, London.
--(2002), Annual Hours, Study 721, London.
Vickery and Wurzburg (1996), 'Flexible firms, skills and
employment', OECD Observer 202, Oct-Nov, pp. 17-21.
Robert A. Hart, Department of Economics, University of Stirling.
e-mails: d.n.fbell@stir.ac.uk or r.a.hart@stir.ac.uk. This project was
funded by the ESRC (ESRC grant R 000 22 3442). Elizabeth Roberts
provided excellent research assistance. We thank a referee for a number
of very helpful comments. We are also grateful to Julian Dowsell (Office
for National Statistics) for supplying us with detailed manufacturing
output data. This paper is based on a fuller report entitled 'Annualised hours contracts' (Bell and Hart, 2002). The
authors would be happy to supply a copy on request.