The domestic performance of UK multinational firms.
Girma, Sourafel
This paper analyses the domestic performance of UK multinational
firms from two perspectives: (i) their productivity relative to foreign
multinationals, domestic exporters and non-exporters, and (ii) their
ability to benefit newly acquired affiliates. Nonparametric analysis
shows that the productivity distribution of UK multinationals is
dominated by their foreign counterparts (especially US firms), and
quantile regressions reveal that the performance disadvantage of UK
multinationals is more pronounced at the higher end of the productivity
distribution. Using a difference-in- differences methodology, it is
found that, unlike foreign acquisitions, take-overs of domestic
non-exporting firms by UK multinationals do not appear to lead to any
productivity improvements.
I. Introduction
Between 1996 and 2000, UK multinational corporations had spent 42.6
billion [pounds sterling] in foreign direct investment, and by the end
of this period they owned a staggering 600 billion [pounds sterling]
worth of assets abroad. (1) Yet, in contrast to the literature that
documents the link between foreign multinationals in the UK and economic
performance, (2) research on the domestic efficiency advantages or
disadvantages of those multinationals has been very limited. Using data
on quoted companies, Kumar (1984) finds that UK multinationals earn
higher returns on assets and on sales than their purely domestic
counterparts. Grant (1987) and Grant et al. (1988) report a positive
association between overseas investment and firm-level financial
performance in a sample of large UK manufacturing enterprises. Recently
Criscuolo and Martin (2002) provide cross-sectional evidence that the
average labour productivity of UK multinationals is higher than
domestically oriented firms, and not any worse than non-US
multinationals operating in the UK. But Han and Lee (1998) contend that
multinationality in UK and other G-7 countries' firms does not
generally translate into superior performance compared with otherwise
similar enterprises.
This paper undertakes an empirical investigation into the
performance of manufacturing affiliates owned by UK multinationals
relative to foreign and purely domestically-owned firms, based on
firm-level panel data over the period 1989-98. In so doing, it adds to
the existing literature in three respects. First, instead of focusing on
average productivity differentials, it evaluates the effects of
multinationality on the entire productivity distribution. This is
achieved through the use of two statistical approaches: the
Kolmogorov-Smirnov nonparametric testing procedure and the
semiparametric method of quantile regression. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov
tests employ the concept of stochastic dominance to rank the cumulative
distribution functions of total factor productivity, whilst quantile
regressions trace the entire distribution of productivity, conditional
on a set of regressors. This enables one to identify not just the
average effects of multinationality, but also where in the productivity
distribution these effects are more pronounced.
The second novelty introduced in this paper is the explicit
comparison of the productivity dynamics of UK multinationals with
domestic exporters. While there are a number of papers documenting that
exporters are more productive than non-exporters, (3) none of them
distinguishes between domestic multinationals and simple exporters. Some
scholars have argued in the literature that profit stability (and hence
efficiency) from foreign direct investment exceeds that from simple
exporting since multinationals diversify in both product and factor
markets, whereas exporters diversify in product markets alone (e.g., see
Rugman, 1974). We subject this notion to empirical investigation, as it
may have some implications for policies that seek to encourage domestic
firms to optimally engage in foreign market activities.
The paper also explores the relative performance of domestic
multinationals vis-a-vis their foreign counterparts from a different
perspective; it asks whether UK and foreign multinationals are equally
effective in transferring their firm-specific advantages (e.g. special
know-how) to their newly acquired subsidiaries. Hard evidence on this
issue is extremely limited, (4) and we contrast the productivity effects
of foreign and UK multinationals' acquisitions of domestic firms
that had no previous foreign exposure. This is the third contribution of
the paper.
Our findings from the nonparametric test statistics indicate that
the productivity distribution of foreign multinationals stochastically dominates the productivity distribution of UK multinationals, both in
levels and growth rates. Our results also point out that the
productivity distribution of domestic exporters is not below that of UK
multinationals, whilst the latter stochastically dominate the
productivity distribution of domestic non-exporters. Allowing for a host
of firm-level and industry-wide variables, the results from the quantile
regressions confirm the above findings. Whilst the growth rate of UK
multinationals is comparable to (even more favourable than) their
foreign counterparts at the lower productivity quantiles, foreign firms
exhibit a faster growth rate at the higher end of the productivity
distribution.
We also find evidence that foreign establishments tend to acquire
the better domestic firms. Accounting for this potential endogeneity
problem, we uncover the discernible productivity-enhancing impact of
foreign acquisitions. In sharp contrast, UK multinationals appear to
target firms with lower levels of efficiency, consistent with the notion
of 'acquisitions as disciplinary transactions' (Shleifer and
Vishny, 1988). However, we fail to identify any subsequent improvements
to the productivity of the acquired firms.
The paper proceeds with Section 2, which briefly considers the
theoretical literature concerning the domestic efficiency
advantages/disadvantages of multinational firms. Section 3 discusses the
data, and Section 4 presents the findings from the Kolmogorov-Smirnov
tests. Section 5 reports the empirical results based on the quantile
regressions. Section 6 considers the determinants of acquisitions by
foreign and UK multinationals, and presents the evidence on the
post-acquisition productivity trajectories of the acquired firms.
Section 7 concludes.
2. Performance advantages/disadvantages of multinationals:
theoretical considerations
Theories concerning foreign direct investment (FDI) emphasise that
foreign firms must have inherent firm-specific advantages that allow
them to overcome the higher costs of becoming a multinational (Hymer,
1976; Kindleberger, 1969). (5) Higher costs result because domestic
firms are already familiar with suppliers, demand conditions, culture,
language, the legal environment and product standards, while foreign
firms are not. The firm-specific advantages of multinationals may be
tangible--for instance an improved production process or a product
innovation--or intangible. The latter include brand names, better
management structures or the technical knowledge of employees. But
firm-specific assets are frequently intangible, which provides one
motivation for firms internalising transactions and becoming
multinationals rather than licensing their assets to local firms. The
intangible nature of the assets means that a market may not exist for
them, increasing the difficulty of writing contracts and entering into
licensing agreements. It is a combination of these factors that leads to
FDI--the advantages of the firm, the need to internalise the
transaction, and the advantages of the country in which the FDI is
located (Dunning, 1977).
The assumption that multinational firms have firm-specific assets
implies that they may also possess substantial competitive advantages
over their purely domestic rivals. A number of arguments are advanced in
the literature linking multinationality with performance advantages over
otherwise comparable firms operating in the domestic market alone (see
inter alia, Kogut, 1985; Benvignati, 1987; Grant, 1987; and Gomes and
Ramaswamy, 1999). These include: (i) better access to technological
knowledge and foreign product innovation; (ii) wider international
networks and management structure to meet domestic competition; (iii)
benefits from economies of scale and scope; (iv) dampening domestic
business fluctuations by using foreign market outlets; (v) taking
advantage of factor cost differentials across multiple locations; (vi)
tapping into corporate specific strategies such as transfer pricing and
tax accounting practices; and (vii) greater geographic dispersion, which
facilitates the undertaking of domestic ventures that are high-risk but
also highly profitable.
But the literature has also identified several reasons as to why
the costs associated with expanding abroad might outweigh the potential
benefits. Grant (1987) suggests that limits to the capacity of managers
to cope successfully with greater complexity associated with
multinationality may exert a negative impact on performance. Hitt et al.
(1997) also argue that multinationality may generate a decline in
performance due to excessive spreading of managerial capabilities and
co-ordination problems. Greniger et al. (1989) conjecture that an
inverted-U relationship exists between the degree of multinationality
and performance, where beyond an optimal degree of internalisation,
profit advantages start to be eroded. In the same vein, Gomes and
Ramaswamy (1999) contend that, above a threshold level of
multinationality, transactional and informational costs may exceed the
benefits of diversification. However, Mathur et al. (2001) point out
that due to potentially high initial costs of establishing abroad, there
might be an initial performance decline followed by improvements, as
average costs decline once economies of scale and scope are achieved.
This line of argument predicts that the relationship between the degree
of multinationality and performance is a U-shaped one.
3. Database construction
The primary source of information for this study is the OneSource
database of private and public companies, which is derived from the
accounts that companies are legally required to deposit at Companies
House. All public limited companies, all companies with more than 50
employees, and the top companies based on turnover, net worth, total
assets, or shareholders' funds (whichever is largest) up to a
maximum of 110,000 companies are included in the database. Companies
that are dissolved or in the process of liquidation are excluded. Thus
the database is heavily biased towards the larger firms. This may or may
not be a major problem depending on the purpose at hand. We believe that
the fact that OneSource under-represents firms with fewer than 50
employees is not necessarily a problem for the purposes of this paper.
Multinational firms generally employ more than 50 workers, and comparing
their performance with similar (in terms of size) domestic firms
actually makes sense.
The database provides information on employment, physical capital,
output and cost of goods sold in a consistent way both across firms and
across time. It is also one of the very few databases with firm-level
export data. However, each edition of OneSource contains
foreign-ownership indicators only for the latest year, (6) so that it is
not possible to identify when a firm became a subsidiary of a foreign
multinational. To track the dynamics of ownership, we matched the
population of manufacturing firms in the database to a list of UK firms
acquired by foreign multinationals. (7) OneSource does not provide any
information on the multinational activity of UK-owned firms either.
Fortunately, we were able to merge it with a newly created database of
foreign multinational activity--the European Linkages and International
Ownership Structure (ELIOS) database built at the University of Urbino.
(8) The information obtained from ELIOS was also complemented by a list
of UK firms that had made foreign acquisitions, compiled from various
issues of Acquisitions Monthly.
We focus on manufacturing subsidiaries of domestic and foreign
companies, and independent domestic producers that do not own any
subsidiaries. (9) Firms with annual employment or output growth
exceeding 100 per cent were omitted, given doubts about the reliability
of these extreme data points. Our final sample contains information on
an unbalanced panel of more than 11,000 firms over the period 1989-98.
Table 1 gives the frequency distribution of these firms by type of
ownership and year.
Whatever the object of the productivity analysis, it is very
important to obtain consistent estimates of the parameters of the
production function. Using log values, we write the production function
as [y.sub.it] [equivalent to]
f([l.sub.it],[m.sub.it],[k.sub.it],[r.sub.it],[TFP.sub.it]), where y is
output (10) and TFP is a firm and time-varying productivity shock. There
are four factors of production: labour (l), material or cost of goods
sold (m), capital (k) which is measured by the book value of fixed
assets, and intangible assets (r). The intangible assets variable in
OneSource is an estimate of the firms' investment in R&D and
marketing, and the value of patents, copyrights and goodwill.
Braunerhjelm (1996) argues that intangible assets more closely
correspond to the theoretical notion of 'firm specific
assets'.
For estimation purposes we employ a translog flexible functional
form approximation of the production function, and TFP is assumed to
follow the following AR(1) process:
(1) [TFP.sub.it] = [rho][TFP.sub.it-1] + [delta][D.sub.t] +
[f.sub.i] + [v.sub.it]
where D is a common year-specific shock, f is a time-invariant firm
specific and v a random error term. We estimate the production function
for each three-digit (11) SIC92 industry available in our sample. To
reflect multinationals' use of different technologies, they are
allowed to have distinct factor elasticity parameters. (12)
Table 2 provides summary statistics for some variables of interest.
The raw data confirm previous findings in the literature that
multinationals are generally bigger, more capital intensive and
productive. Within domestically oriented firms, exporters exhibit higher
productivity levels compared to their non-exporting counterparts. It can
also be seen that there is a considerable variation in the data. It is
especially worth noting that within-industry productivity variation
exceeds between-industry heterogeneity, which is in line with findings
reported elsewhere (e.g. Bartelsman and Doms, 2000).
4. Evidence from the nonparametric analysis
A common method of analysing productivity differentials across
distinct groups of firms is to estimate linear regression models of
productivity with appropriately defined dummies. This method yields
ceteris paribus average productivity differentials. Here we take an
alternative nonparametric approach, and analyse productivity
differentials over the entire productivity distribution rather than just
at the conditional mean. To this end, we employ the Kolmogorov-Smirnov
one-sided and two-sided tests (e.g. Covonor, 1999) to rank productivity
distribution using the concept of stochastic dominance. (13)
Let F denote the cumulative distribution function of UK
multinational firms, and let G be the corresponding function of the
comparison group, which consists of US-owned firms, non-US
multinationals, domestic exporters or non-exporters. First-order
stochastic dominance of F with respect to G is defined as: F(z)-G(z)
[less than or equal to] 0 uniformly in z [member of] R, with strict
equality for some. The two-sided Kolmogorov-Smirnov statistics test the
hypothesis that both distributions are identical, and the null and
alternative hypotheses can be expressed as:
(2) [H.sub.0]:F(z)-G(z) = 0 [for all]z [member of] R vs.
[H.sub.1]:F(z)-G(z) [not equal to] 0 for some z [member of] R.
By contrast, the one-sided test of stochastic dominance can be
formulated as:
(3) [H.sub.0]:F(z)-G(z) = 0 [for all]z [member of] R vs.
[H.sub.1]:F(z)-G(z)>0 for some z [member of] R.
For the one-sided test, for example, the Kolmogorov-Smirnov
statistic is given by
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where n and m are the sample sizes from the empirical distributions
of F and G respectively, and N = n + m. Acceptance of the null
hypothesis (3) implies that the distribution of F is to right of G. In
this case, F is said to dominate G stochastically.
Because the limiting distribution of the Kolmogorov-Smirnov
statistics is only known under independence of observations, it is more
appropriate to apply the testing procedure on cross-section by
cross-section basis, rather on the pooled panel where within-firm
dependence is likely to exist.
For representative years, table 3 reports hypothesis test
statistics for productivity level and growth differentials between UK
multinationals and the various comparison groups. As far as the
productivity level is concerned, the hypothesis of equality of
distribution of foreign and UK multinationals cannot be accepted at
conventional levels of significance. Furthermore, the productivity
distribution of UK multinationals is stochastically dominated by the
distributions of both US and non-US firms. Chart 1 presents graphical
depictions of pairs of estimated distribution functions for 1998, to
allow for easy visual comparisons of productivity distributions. It can
be seen that the productivity difference in favour of foreign
multinationals is more pronounced at the higher end of the distribution,
especially for US firms.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
The equality of distribution test between the productivity growth
of US and UK multinationals is also rejected in every year of the sample
period, and the former stochastically dominates the latter. These
differential productivity growth rates provide suggestive evidence that
UK multinationals are not catching-up with US-owned firms. The
hypothesis of equality of non-US and UK multinationals'
productivity growth distributions was not rejected for some years, but
we did not find an instance where the productivity growth distribution
of UK multinationals was above that of their non-US counterparts.
As mentioned in the introduction, a number of empirical studies across a whole range of countries document the existence of a
particularly robust correlation between exporting and firm-level
productivity. (14) But the twist here is the explicit comparison of the
performance of domestic exporters and domestic multinationals. The
argument of Rugman (1974) suggests that multinationals are likely to
enjoy greater competitive advantages than exporters since they diversify
in both product and factor markets. This conjecture does not seem be
borne out by the data, however. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov statistics
indicate that the productivity distributions of UK multinationals is not
above that of simple exporters, and in all years we fail to reject the
hypothesis of equality of distributions. This suggests that, as far as
domestic performance is concerned, the evidence in favour of becoming
multinational rather than engaging in arms-length exporting is not
overwhelming. Finally, we establish stochastic dominance of the
productivity level and growth distributions of UK multinationals with
respect to non-exporting domestic firms. (15) But, by the end of the
sample period, the productivity growth distribution of UK multinationals
was not above that of non-exporters (see also chart 2).
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Using a nonparametric productivity measure, Girma et al. (2003)
also reach the conclusion that the differences in growth rates between
different domestic firms (exporters and non-exporters) and UK
multinationals are not statistically significant. They interpret this
result as evidence against convergence in the productivity levels.
5. Quantile regressions of productivity growth differentials
The nonparametric approach presented in the previous section is a
useful analytical tool in summarising and contrasting the productivity
dynamics of different groups of firms. This section refines the
analysis, and investigates differentials across a range of productivity
distributions by controlling for a host of factors impacting on
firms' productivity trajectories. The total factor productivity
(TFP) growth equation
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
forms the basis for our empirical work. Here i and t index firms
and time periods respectively; [TFP.sub.it-1] denotes initial level of
TFP, and X is a vector of variables hypothesised to impact on plant
level TFP growth, namely plant age, changes in export intensity,
four-digit industry growth and concentration (captured by the Herfindhal
index). OWN denotes ownership dummies for the four comparison group of
firms, and MD is the degree of multinationality of UK multinationals
proxied by the number of countries they have affiliates in. The
rationale of including a quadratic term in MD is to test the hypothesis
that, beyond a certain threshold, the advantages of multinationality
start to dissipate (e.g. Greniger et al., 1989). Finally D represents
the full set of time dummies to account for common macro shocks
affecting the productivity path of the firms, and [epsilon] is a random
error term.
As mentioned in Section 3, the productivity variation in our sample
is in line with recent literature on firm-level productivity dynamics
which has established a large and persistent heterogeneity across firms,
even within narrowly defined industries. (16) This has an implication
for productivity growth empirics: standard techniques, such as OLS and
GMM, which concentrate on the conditional mean function of the dependent
variable, are unlikely to be adequate analytical tools. In the presence
of heterogeneous productivity processes, it is more appropriate (and
arguably more interesting) to examine the dynamics of productivity at
different points of the distribution, rather than 'average'
properties (i.e. conditional means).
Accordingly, this paper employs the quantile regression technique
introduced by Koenker and Bassett (1978). Denoting the vector of
regressors in equation (4) by Z, the quantile regression model can be
written as
(5) [DELTA][TFP.sub.it] = [Z.sub.it][[beta].sub.[theta]] +
[[epsilon].sub.[theta]it],
[Quant.sub.[theta]]([DELTA][TFP.sub.it]]|[Z.sub.it]) =
[Z.sub.it][[beta].sub.[theta]]
where [Quant.sub.[theta]]([DELTA][TFP.sub.it]]|[Z.sub.it]) denotes
the conditional quantile of [DELTA]TFP. The distribution of the error
term [[epsilon].sub.[theta]] is left unspecified, so the estimation
method is essentially semiparametric, (17) and the [theta]th quantile
regression, 0 < [theta] < 1, solves
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
By increasing [theta] from 0 to 1, one can trace the entire
distribution of firm-level productivity growth, conditional on the set
of regressors. Thus quantile regressions allow us to focus attention on
specific parts of the productivity growth distribution, and identify
where in the distribution multinationality exerts the greatest impact.
In this study we consider regression estimates at five different
quantiles, namely, the 10th, 25th, 50th (median), 75th and 90th
percentiles of the TFP distribution.
As reported in Table 4, the estimated coefficients of initial TFP
are negative across all quantiles. This is consistent with the notion of
[beta]-convergence, and the catch-up rate, which denotes the speed at
which a firm approaches its steady level of TFP ranges from 6.9 per cent
to 13.1 per cent. Conditional on initial TFP, older firms grow at a
slower rate, but the magnitudes of the point estimates imply that the
between-ages difference might not be practically important. The results
also suggest that the share of exports in total shipments exerts a
growth-enhancing influence at the higher end of the productivity growth
distribution. As expected, firms in fast growing industries enjoy higher
productivity growth rates, whereas the concentration variable attracts
negative coefficients across all specifications. This indicates that the
absence of strong competition in an industry has detrimental effects on
the evolution of firm-level productivity.
Focusing on the role played by ownership, it is apparent that the
average productivity growth differentials presented in the first column
of table 4 hide some interesting variations across the productivity
quantiles. (18) For example, compared with UK multinationals (the base
group), the productivity growth of US and non-US owned firms is, on
average higher by 1.1 and 1.5 percentage points respectively. However,
at the lower end of the productivity distribution (i.e. at the 10th and
25th percentiles) foreign multinationals actually experience slower
growth rates. By contrast, at the upper end of the distribution (i.e. at
the 75th and 90th percentiles) the performance advantage in favour of
foreign multinationals is quite remarkable: it is two to four times
greater than the average productivity growth regression results would
have suggested. For instance, at the 90th percentile, the productivity
growth of US and non-US multinationals is higher by about 4 percentage
points compared to otherwise similar UK multinationals.
In accordance with the nonparametric analysis, the semiparametric
quantile regression estimates also show that the productivity growth of
domestic multinationals is not any faster than their arms-length
exporting counterparts: the coefficients on the domestic exporters dummy fall short of significance at all points of the productivity
distribution, consistent with the nonparametric analysis. However,
non-exporters exhibit lower levels of growth, and their performance
disadvantages are more pronounced at the upper end of the productivity
growth distribution. It seems that non-exporting domestic firms are not
particularly well represented in the more dynamic end of the
productivity spectrum.
There is some evidence that the productivity growth of UK
multinationals is positively related to their degree of
multinationality. However,
the absolute sizes of the coefficients suggest that the productivity
effect of increasing the number of countries in which the firms operate
is unlikely to be economically significant. But more interestingly, we
did not find any non-linearity in the relationship between performance
and the extent of multinationality: the squared multinationality term in
equation (4) is statistically insignificant in all but one
specification. (19) Thus the data do not lend support to the notion that
the benefits of multinational diversification diminish beyond a certain
level.
A legitimate concern when using quantile regressions based on panel
data is that firms move across quantiles. For example a firm at the
bottom 10 per cent of the productivity distribution in the previous
period might find itself at the top half of the distribution in the
current period. Consequently, it might be problematic to make
predictions about individual firms. But we believe that this is not too
problematic for the purpose of this paper, because the analysis of the
relative performance of different groups of firms does not require that
individual firms stay in the same quantile. Nonetheless, as a robustness
check we also run quantile regressions based on within-firm time
averages. This approach ensures that each firm is confined to a single
quantile, but at the expense of losing the time series variation in the
data. The empirical estimates are reported in table 5 and the results
are qualitatively similar.
6. The productivity effects of acquisitions by UK and foreign
multinationals
Are domestic and foreign multinationals equally effective in
transferring their firm-specific assets to their newly acquired
subsidiaries? In this section we document evidence on the link between
acquisitions of domestic firms with no previous foreign exposure (i.e.
non-exporters) and productivity growth. We confine our analysis to the
acquisitions of domestic non-exporters, as we are interested in
isolating the productivity effects of foreign exposure. Foreign
multinationals and UK-owned companies that are deemed to undertake
internationally mobile projects (20) in underdeveloped regions receive
substantial subventions from the UK government under its Regional
Selective Assistance scheme (RSA). For example, some half a billion
pounds was paid in grants for internationally-owned companies alone
between 1991 and 1995. (21) One of the principal reasons behind this
type of discretionary grant is the expectation that this may help reduce
the 'UK competitiveness gap' by exposing indigenous
establishments to better technological knowledge and foreign product
innovation. It is interesting to note that two-thirds of foreign-owned
projects and three-quarters of UK-owned internationally mobile projects
that received public grants in the above period involved expansions at
existing sites, acquisitions and buy-outs rather than new start-ups or
branch plants. The focus on the productivity growth impacts of
acquisitions by multinationals is therefore practically relevant.
The sample of acquired firms was screened for data availability for
at least three consecutive years surrounding the acquisition event, and
in the final analysis we identified 882 acquisitions made by foreign and
domestic multinationals over the period 1989-96. (22) The frequency
distribution of these acquisitions is given in table 6. The control
group consists of about 4500 non-exporting firms that did not experience
any type of ownership change.
We start by making an exploratory investigation into the
determinants of acquisitions in our sample of firms via a multinomial
logit model with three mutually exclusive events: no change of
ownership, acquisitions by a foreign multinational and take-over by a UK
multinational. The purpose of this analysis is to assess whether
productivity can be considered exogenous to the process of acquisitions.
The literature on corporate take-overs has identified a number of
variables that are likely to impact on the probability of being
acquired, and this guided our choice of covariates in the multinomial
model. Palepu (1986) conjectures that size is an important determinant of acquisition, as it may be more difficult for larger firms to be
acquired due to financial constraints. Older firms are also thought of
as less likely take-over targets. The 'value maximisation
hypothesis' contends that acquisition is a disciplinary device
whereby less efficient or profitable firms are taken over by the most
efficient institutions (Shleifer and Vishny, 1988). Firms with a high
level of liquidity are also identified as being attractive take-overs
targets (Palepu, 1986). However, a high level of liquidity could also
signal a lack of investment opportunities, thereby making the firm less
attractive to potential bidders. The hypothesis put forwards by Shleifer
and Summers (1988) posits that take-overs are motivated by the
opportunity they offer to renege on implicit labour contracts and reduce
extra-marginal payments. This suggests that high wage firms are likely
to be acquired. Among industry-level determinants, industry
concentration has been hypothesised to present a greater deterrence to
domestic acquisitions (Shapiro, 1983). Furthermore, previous foreign
presence in a sector is thought of as capturing the attractiveness of
the sector from the perspective of new foreign entrants (Head et al.,
1995). Also sectors experiencing higher growth rates are supposed to be
attractive to market-seeking entrants. Finally we add a UK Assisted Area
dummy to account for the possibility that firms in underdeveloped
regions are more likely to be acquired due to financial incentives
available to multinationals.
Table 7 presents the marginal effects from the multinomial model.
UK multinationals appear to target smaller and less efficient firms.
They also tend to acquire firms with cash-flow problems, but neither
wages nor the sectoral and regional variables are found to exert any
discernible influence on their decision to acquire. By contrast, wages,
sectoral growth rates and the assisted area dummy play a significant and
positive role in the acquisition decision of foreign multinationals and,
more interestingly, foreign multinationals seem to 'cherry
pick' the most efficient domestic firms from the pool of potential
targets. In sum, this exploratory analysis suggests that it is probably
erroneous to assume that acquisitions are exogenous to the process
governing the productivity dynamics of the firms.
In order to isolate the ceteris paribus impact of multinational
acquisition activity on the productivity growth of domestic
non-exporting firms, we adopt the difference-in-differences methodology
(e.g. Meyer, 1994). This approach proceeds in two steps. Firstly, the
difference between the average productivity growth rates before and
after the change of ownership, say [[DELTA].sup.a]TFP, is calculated.
However this difference cannot be exclusively attributed to acquisition
since the post-acquisition period growth rate might be affected by
factors that are contemporaneous with ownership change. To cater for
this, the difference obtained at the first stage is further differenced
with respect to the before and after difference for the control group of
non-exporting firms. (23) The resulting difference-indifferences
estimator, [delta] = [[DELTA].sup.a]TFP-[[DELTA].sup.c]TFP, therefore
purges the effects of common shocks, and provides a more accurate
description of the productivity impact of acquisition. This procedure is
equivalent to running a regression of the following form:
(7) [DELTA][TFP.sub.it] = [delta][A.sub.it] + [u.sub.it]
where A is a vector of post-acquisition dummies whose coefficient [delta] should produce the average percentage point change in
productivity growth that can be attributed to multinational
acquisitions. To allow for the differential acquisition effect, we
construct two separate dummies for foreign and domestic multinational
acquisitions. We also control for other factors that may be correlated with changes in productivity by including age, initial TFP and sectoral
growth in equation (7).
The regression results are presented in table 8. Controlling for
initial TFP, age, industry characteristics and autonomous technical
changes (via time dummies), and assuming exogenous acquisitions, we find
a 4.4 percentage points increase in total factor productivity growth due
to foreign take-overs. In sharp contrast, no efficiency enhancing impact
of domestic multinational acquisitions is obtained.
If productivity plays some role in driving acquisitions as implied
by the multinomial logit analysis, the post-acquisition dummy may be
endogenous. To break the stochastic dependence between the acquisition
variables and the disturbance term in the productivity growth equation,
we instrument acquisition by the probability of take-over computed from
the multinomial models. Vella and Verbeek (1999) have recently shown
that this method of dealing with endogenous dummies generates estimators
that are equivalent to Heckman's (1978) endogeneity bias corrected
OLS estimator. In other words, the exogenous variation in the covariates
included in the multinomial models reported in table 7 is used to deal
with the endogeneity of acquisition. The instrumental variable estimates
show that foreign acquisitions lead to a 5.4 percentage point growth in
the post ownership change period, whereas domestic acquisitions appear
to cause a reduction in performance.
The positive productivity effect following foreign acquisitions is
consistent with the internalisation theory of FDI, which postulates that
multinational firms transfer a range of intangible proprietary assets to
their affiliates. But how can one explain the lack of success by UK
multinationals to transfer such assets to their newly acquired
subsidiaries? One reason behind the absence of an average productivity
effect could be that UK multinationals tend to target less efficient
firms having a low level of absorptive capacity (Cohen and Levinthal,
1989). Without the necessary absorptive capacity, acquired firms might
not be able to fully benefit from their new association with
multinationals, at least in the short run. One way to explore
empirically the above conjecture is by interacting the post-acquisition
dummy variables with the pre-acquisition TFP of the acquired firms. The
results from this experiment are reported in the last two columns of
table 8, and they are supportive of the notion that greater absorptive
capacity (proxied here by pre-acquisition TFP) increases the degree of
technology transfer. A calculation, based on the point estimates from
the last column of table 8, indicates that firms need to have an initial
TFP level above 0.40 to start having a positive effect from acquisitions
by UK multinationals. The raw data show that at the time of take-over,
fewer than 40 of the 326 firms acquired by UK multinationals had TFP
levels above this threshold. This may explain the finding of
insignificant or negative average acquisition effects. The absence of
efficiency-enhancing effects of domestic acquisitions is also consistent
with the widely held proposition in the literature that some (and
perhaps most) deals are motivated less by considerations of shareholder
value, than by managerial aspirations for empire-building and associated
private gains (e.g. Jensen, 1986). (24)
7. Conclusion
Based on a firm-level panel over the period 1989-98, this paper
provides detailed statistical analyses of two aspects of UK
multinational firms' domestic performance: their relative
productivity dynamics and their ability to benefit newly acquired
affiliates in the form of higher productivity growth.
Using the concept of first order stochastic dominance to rank
productivity distributions, we find that the productivity distribution
of foreign multinationals dominates that of UK multinationals. This
conclusion is corroborated by results from quantile regressions, which
also reveal that the performance disadvantage of UK multinationals is
more acutely felt at the higher end of the productivity distribution.
This suggests that the technology frontier is typically dominated by
foreign multinationals, and UK multinationals do not appear to catch up
fast enough with their foreign counterparts. The paper also finds that
take-overs of non-exporting domestic firms by UK multinationals are not
accompanied by significant productivity improvements, whereas foreign
acquisitions are generally beneficial to the productivity trajectory of
the acquired firms. This would appear to vindicate the effort undertaken
by policymakers in the UK to attract incoming FDI, at least as far as
the direct efficiency gains from FDI are concerned. However, this
conclusion should be somewhat tempered by the realisation that foreign
acquisition activity tends to target the better domestic firms.
Table 1. Frequency of firms by type of ownership
UK-owned Foreign
Year Non- Export- MNE USA Others Total
exporters ers
1989 1722 780 204 208 468 3382
1990 2780 1058 248 226 493 4805
1991 3043 1267 263 236 514 5323
1992 3260 1417 269 244 529 5719
1993 3444 1560 288 259 547 6098
1994 3596 1686 305 267 567 6421
1995 3736 1831 334 277 582 6759
1996 3831 2012 355 302 592 7092
1997 4725 2939 393 310 486 8853
1998 4876 2009 396 290 464 8935
Table 2. Summary statistics
Domestic non- Domestic
exporters exporters
Variable Mean Std. dev. Mean Std. dev.
Labour A 4.189 0.786 4.251 0.688
productivity B 0.445 0.387
C 0.729 0.621
Total factor A -0.061 0.637 0.039 0.543
productivity B 0.253 0.287
C 0.614 .513
Log employment A 4.329 1.322 4.629 1.155
B 0.616 0.544
C 1.257 1.098
Log capital A 6.867 1.146 6.864 1.024
intensity B 0.651 0.654
C 1.039 0.909
UK MNE USA MNE
Mean Std. dev. Mean Std. dev.
Labour A 4.255 0.709 4.464 0.692
productivity B 0.554 0.678
C 0.536 0.539
Total factor A 0.071 0.561 0.158 0.554
productivity B 0.420 0.437
C 0.482 0.492
Log employment A 4.926 1.299 5.361 1.415
B 0.882 1.223
C 1.104 1.179
Log capital A 6.885 1.133 7.270 0.996
intensity B 0.952 0.855
C 0.913 0.780
Other foreign
MNE
Mean Std. dev.
Labour A 4.453 0.687
productivity B 0.429
C 0.601
Total factor A 0.182 0.580
productivity B 0.307
C 0.532
Log employment A 5.079 1.217
B .732
C 1.111
Log capital A 7.171 1.129
intensity B .725
C 0.959
Notes: A = Overall; B = Between industry; C = Within industry. TFP so
measured can be interpreted as efficiency relative to the mean. For
example US multinationals are on average 18.2 per cent more efficient
than the 'average' firm within their industry. The average TFP
advantage of foreign multinationals vis-a-vis UK multinationals is
statistically significant. The latter average TFP is in turn
significantly higher than the TFP of arms-length exporters and domestic
firms.
Table 3. Kolmogorov-Smirnov test statistics of productivity differences
for selected years
US MNES vs UK MNEs Non-US MNES vs UK MNEs
Null hypothesis Null hypothesis
Equality of Difference Equality of Difference
distribution in US MNEs' distribution in non-US
favour MNEs' favour
Productivity
level
1990 0.1252 0.025 0.087 0.015
(0.045) (0.871) (0.077) (0.930)
1994 0.1249 0.032 0.098 0.009
(0.026) (0.749) (0.047) (0.965)
1998 0.126 0.000 0.128 0.001
(0.012) (1.000) (0.002) (1.000)
Productivity
growth
1990 0.139 0.026 0.068 0.389
(0.044) (0.879) (0.575) (0.068)
1994 0.186 0.031 0.183 0.027
(0.000) (0.772) (0.000) (0.757)
1998 0.015 0.034 0.093 0.041
(0.001) (0.695) (0.064) (0.503)
Domestic exporters vs UK Domestic non-exporters vs
MNEs UK MNEs
Null hypothesis Null hypothesis
Equality of Difference Equality of Difference in
distribution in UK MNEs' distribution in US non-
favour MNEs' favour
Productivity
level
1990 0.077 0.077 0.106 0.005
(0.197) (0.099) (0.014) (0.989)
1994 0.075 0.003 0.134 0.004
(0.12) (0.006) (0.000) (0.993)
1998 0.042 -0.019 0.112 0.008
(0.601) (0.013) (0.000) (0.962)
Productivity
growth
1990 0.054 0.049 0.0502 0.047
(0.792) (0.021) (0.078) (0.470)
1994 0.055 0.047 0.151 0.034
(0.471) (0.052) (0.001) (0.503)
1998 0.043 0.027 0.059 0.014
(0.605) (0.037) (0.224) (0.057)
Notes: P-values are given in parentheses. The null hypotheses in the
above table are rejected when the p-values are less than some
pre-specified critical values (e.g. at 5 per cent level of
significance, p values greater than 0.05 suggest that the corresponding
null cannot be rejected.)
Table 4. The domestic performance of UK multinationals: quantile
regression estimates
At the mean 10%
Lagged TFP -0.153 -0.122
(27.17) ** (32.06) **
Age -0.001 -0.001
(14.53) ** (3.22) **
Export intensity 0.036 0.002
(2.10) * (0.10)
Industry growth 0.039 0.036
(4.58) ** (2.60) **
Concentration -0.137 -0.105 *
(4.12) ** (1.99)
USA MNEs 0.011 ** -0.031
(2.35) (2.35) *
Non-USA MNEs 0.015 ** -0.025
(1.96) (2.16) *
Domestic exporters -0.010 -0.009
(1.55) (0.94)
Domestic non-exporters -0.023 -0.023
(3.36) ** (2.35) *
Degree of multinationality 0.002 0.003
(2.64) ** (2.76) **
Square of degree of multinationality -0.0001 -0.0002
(1.54) (1.92)
Constant 0.023 -0.236
(3.07) ** (21.11) **
Observations 46131 46131
Quantiles
25% 50%
Lagged TFP -0.087 -0.069
(50.69) ** (49.27) **
Age 0.002 -0.002
(0.53) (8.40) **
Export intensity 0.012 0.012
(1.09) (1.36)
Industry growth 0.027 0.031
(4.15) ** (6.09) **
Concentration -0.081 -0.102
(2.96) ** (4.61) **
USA MNEs 0.006 0.013
(0.88) (2.37) *
Non-USA MNEs 0.003 0.012
(0.47) (2.53) *
Domestic exporters 0.000 -0.001
(0.08) (0.13)
Domestic non-exporters -0.004 -0.005
(0.83) (-1.23)
Degree of multinationality 0.001 -0.000
(2.14) * (0.31)
Square of degree of multinationality -0.0001 0.0001
(0.76) (1.33)
Constant -0.121 -0.019
(20.90) ** (4.03) **
Observations 46131 46131
75% 90%
Lagged TFP -0.082 -0.131
(35.00) ** (19.36) **
Age -0.001 -0.002
(15.85) ** (14.36) **
Export intensity 0.047 0.066
(3.68) ** (2.14) *
Industry growth 0.032 0.049
(4.29) ** (2.94) **
Concentration -0.088 -0.117 *
(2.65) ** -1.96
USA MNEs 0.028 0.040
(2.24) * (2.38) *
Non-USA MNEs 0.024 0.038
(3.49) ** (2.44) *
Domestic exporters -0.012 -0.019
(1.92) (1.46)
Domestic non-exporters -0.047 -0.037
(2.87) ** (2.08) *
Degree of multinationality -0.001 0.002
(1.78) (1.08)
Square of degree of multinationality 0.0001 -0.0002
(2.13) * (0.58)
Constant 0.111 0.298
(16.60) ** (20.51) **
Observations 46131 46131
Note: UK multinationals form the base group in all regressions. The
full set of time dummies is included throughout. * significant at 5
per cent; ** significant at 1 per cent.
Table 5. Quantile regression estimates based on within-firm time
averages
At the mean 10%
Initial TFP -0.133 -0.076
(17.57) ** (26.19) **
Initial Age -0.001 0.001
(8.50) ** (3.43) **
Average export intensity 0.038 -0.058
(2.41) * (4.46) **
Average industry growth 0.033 0.237
(0.99) (10.00) **
Average concentration -0.414 -0.613
(2.54) * (5.04) **
USA MNEs 0.005 -0.031
(0.37) (2.12) *
Non-USA MNES 0.004 0.020
(0.34) (1.53)
Domestic Exporters -0.024 -0.004
(1.68) (0.37)
Domestic Non-exporters -0.021 -0.028
(2.88) ** (2.49) *
Degree of multinationality 0.002 0.003
(1.00) (1.99) *
Square of Degree of multinationality -0.0001 -0.0003
(0.69) (1.13)
Constant 0.040 -0.118
(3.39) ** (10.23) **
Observations 8925 8925
Quantiles
25% 50%
Initial TFP -0.065 -0.066
(55.55)** (53.66) **
Initial Age 0.001 -0.002
(0.03) (7.13) **
Average export intensity -0.006 0.011
(1.01) (1.99) *
Average industry growth 0.142 0.025
(15.98) ** (3.04) **
Average concentration -0.440 -0.184
(10.34) ** (4.64) **
USA MNEs 0.016 0.006
(2.43) * (0.87)
Non-USA MNES 0.015 0.009
(2.52) * (1.50)
Domestic Exporters -0.002 -0.007
(0.39) (1.38)
Domestic Non-exporters -0.009 -0.07
(1.91) (2.37) *
Degree of multinationality 0.001 0.001
-1.75 (0.05)
Square of Degree of multinationality -0.0001 0.0001
(0.91) (0.68)
Constant -0.056 0.009
(10.94) ** (1.83)
Observations 8925 8925
75% 90%
Initial TFP -0.085 -0.127
(35.14) ** (15.57) **
Initial Age -0.001 -0.001
(11.19) ** (7.99) **
Average export intensity 0.016 0.049
(1.96) * (2.23) *
Average industry growth -0.056 -0.146
(4.23) ** (3.48) **
Average concentration -0.042 -0.021
(0.64) (0.09)
USA MNEs 0.016 0.014
(1.98) * (2.57) **
Non-USA MNES 0.008 0.011
(1.96) * (3.53) **
Domestic Exporters -0.013 -0.031
(1.85) (1.72)
Domestic Non-exporters -0.04 -0.03
(2.52) ** (2.18) *
Degree of multinationality -0.001 -0.003
(0.62) (1.38)
Square of Degree of multinationality 0.0001 0.0002
(1.11) (2.49) *
Constant 0.082 0.204
(10.72) ** (10.38) **
Observations 8925 8925
Notes: * significant at 5 per cent; ** significant at 1 per cent.
Initial age and initial TFP correspond to values of the first year
the firm is observed in the sample.
Table 6. Frequency of acquisitions by year
Acquiring multinational
Year Foreign Domestic
1989 64 52
1990 60 49
1991 74 44
1992 70 48
1993 51 30
1994 94 41
1995 81 32
1996 58 30
Total 552 326
Table 7. The probability of acquisition: marginal
effects from the Multinomial Logit Models
Acquisition by
Regressor UK multinationals Foreign multinationals
Size -0.0022 (2.70) ** 0.009 (8.69) **
Age -0.0002 (3.34) * -0.0001 (2.12) *
Wage 0.0039 (0.38) * 0.0154 (3.17)
TFP -0.004 (2.16) * 0.136 (4.94) **
Liquidity -0.0126 (3.68) ** -0.008 (1.60)
Concentration -0.0204 (1.46) 0.013 (0.51)
FDI 0.001 (0.30) 0.041 (1.50)
Sectoral growth 0.002 (0.51) 0.006 (1.97) *
Assisted Area -0.0004 (0.18) 0.003 * (1.98)
Observations 21838
Log likelihood -2487.3
p-value for test
of IIA 0.71 0.89
Notes: 'No change of ownership during the year' is used as the base
category. All variables are lagged by one period. Liquidity is proxied
by total assets minus current liabilities. The absolute values of the
t-statistics are reported in parentheses. IIA stands for the assumption
of Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives. In our context, this
implies that the effects of the regressors on the probability of being
taken over by a domestic multinational is not affected by the inclusion
of foreign acquisitions as a possible outcome. We fail to reject the
validity of this assumption by conducting Hausman-type tests suggested
by Hausman and McFadden (1984).
Table 8. Post-acquisition productivity trajectories
Baseline specification
Exogenous Endogenous
acquisitions acquisitions
Lagged TFP -0.174 -0.178
(19.22) ** (19.13) **
Age -0.001 -0.001
(10.71) ** (10.70) **
Industry growth 0.050 0.050
(4.61) ** (4.60) **
Concentration -0.119 -0.120
(2.67) ** (2.69) **
Foreign acquisition Effect 0.046 0.054
(5.72) ** (4.34) **
Foreign acquisition * pre-acquisition
TFP
Domestic acquisitions effect -0.007 -0.018
(0.91) (2.16) *
Domestic acquisition * pre-acquisition
TFP
Constant 0.054 0.055
(3.03) ** (3.03) **
Sargan test of validity of instruments .318
(p-value)
Observations 21838 21838
Specification with pre-
acquisition TFP
interaction
Exogenous Endogenous
acquisitions acquisitions
Lagged TFP -0.179 -0.178
(19.09) ** (18.95) **
Age -0.001 -0.001
(10.66) ** (10.63) **
Industry growth 0.050 0.050
(4.58) ** (4.58) **
Concentration -0.119 -0.120
(2.67) ** (2.69) **
Foreign acquisition effect 0.006 0.007
(0.73) (0.56)
Foreign acquisition * pre-acquisition 0.118 0.096
TFP (5.72) ** (4.65) **
Domestic acquisitions effect -0.019 -0.032
(2.37) * (3.42) **
Domestic acquisition * pre-acquisition 0.068 0.080
TFP (2.87) ** (3.39) **
Constant 0.055 0.055
(3.07) ** (3.06) **
Sargan test of validity of instruments .214
(p-value)
Observations 21838 21838
Notes: Robust t-statistics in parentheses. ** significant at 5 per
cent; ** significant at 1 per cent. The full set of time dummies is
included throughout. Unlike the specification in the previous sections
export intensity is not included in the vector of regressors as we
focus on the acquisition of non-exporting domestic firms by
multinationals.
NOTES
(1) Source: Office for National Statistics, Foreign Direct
Investment inquiries.
(2) A robust finding reported in this literature is the existence
of significant productivity differentials in favour of foreign
multinational firms operating in the UK. For recent micro evidence, see
Girma et al. (2001) and Griffith and Simpson (2002). For evidence based
on US data see Doms and Jensen (1998).
(3) Table 1 of Girma et al. (2002) summarises details of recent
papers on nine countries.
(4) Conyon et al. (2002) and Harris and Robinson (2002) report
evidence on the productivity implications of acquisitions. None of these
studies was able to isolate acquisitions made by UK multinationals.
(5) The development of the concept of firm-specific or proprietary
assets can be attributed to a number of authors. See also Dunning
(1977), Buckley and Casson (1976) and Caves (1971).
(6) For this study we used the OneSource CD-ROM entitled 'UK
companies, Vol. I', for October 2000.
(7) This information, which is in hard copy format, is obtained
from the Office of National Statistics upon special request. The
matching process required considerable effort, and I wish to thank
Mehtap Hisarciklilar for helping me in this regard.
(8) I wish to express my gratitude to Davide Castellani and
Antonello Zanfei for allowing me to use some information from this
database.
(9) Parent companies were omitted if they have consolidated
accounts, as this leads to double counting.
(10) To allow cross-time comparisons, we converted current values
of output and inputs using highly disaggregated price indices obtained
from the Office for National Statistics. Some extrapolation is done for
missing years/sectors.
(11) Estimation of production functions is not performed at the
more disaggregated four-digit level to maximise the number of
observations available for estimation.
(12) TFP is therefore generated econometrically from a dynamic
translog production function with four inputs. We also experimented with
other productivity measurement approaches, namely labour productivity
and Solow residuals, and generally find that they are highly correlated.
Results based on these measures are available from the author upon
request.
(13) Recently Delgano et al. (2002) examined productivity
differentials between exporters and non-exporters in a sample of Spanish
manufacturing firms, using the same approach outlined in this section.
(14) For example, see Bernard and Jensen (1997) for evidence on the
US; for Columbia, Mexico and Morocco, Clerides et al. (1998); for Spain,
Delgano et al. (2002); and for the UK Girma et al. (2002).
(15) One should keep in mind, however, Melitz's (2000)
observation that, in an industry with differentiated products, comparing
the productivity of firms based on a common price index might be
misleading. For example Melitz shows that if the elasticity of
substitution is higher in the international market, then measured
productivity differences between exporting and non-exporting firms will
be underestimated.
(16) See Bartelsman and Doms (2000) for a comprehensive review.
(17) See Buchinsky (1998) for an excellent overview of quantile
models.
(18) Although it is not possible to test formally for the
difference between the mean effects and the effects at each quantile, it
is possible to test for the significance in the difference between pairs
of quantiles. The test results vindicate the use of quantile
regressions.
(19) At the 75th percentile the square of the multinationality
variable is positive and significant, whilst the linear term is negative
and weakly significant. If anything, this suggests a U-shaped, rather
than an inverted U-shaped relationship.
(20) A project is deemed internationally non-mobile if it is
considered to be suitable for a location in the UK only. Thus it can
reasonably be inferred that internationally mobile projects are most
probably undertaken by UK multinationals, or domestic firms that have
the potential to be multinationals.
(21) See the official report at http://www.dti.gov.uk/regional/
evaluationRSA91-95.pdf
(22) Apart from distinguishing between domestic exporters,
non-exporters and UK multinationals, this is a much more extended sample
than the one used by Conyon et al. (2001).
(23) Hence the name, difference-in-differences.
(24) See Dickerson et al. (1997) for econometric evidence from the
UK, which supports this view that domestic acquisition activity, is, on
average, detrimental to profitability.
REFERENCES
Bartelman, E.J. and Doms, M. (2000), 'Understanding
productivity: lessons from longitudinal microdata', Journal of
Economic Literature, 38, pp. 569-95.
Benvignati, A.M. (1987), 'Domestic profit advantages of
multinational firms', Journal of Business, 60, pp. 449-61.
Bernard, A. and Jensen, J. (1997), 'Exceptional exporters
performance: cause, effect or both?', Journal of International
Economics, 47, pp. 1-25.
Braunerhjelm, P. (1996), 'The relation between firm-specific
intangibles and exports', Economic Letters, 53, pp. 213-19.
Buchinski, M. (1998), 'Recent advances in quantile regression
models', Journal of Human Resources, 33, pp. 88-126.
Buckley, P.J. and Casson, M. (1976), The future of the
Multinational Enterprise, London, Macmillan.
Caves, R.E. (1971), 'International comparisons: the industrial
economics of foreign investment', Economica, 38, pp. 1-27.
Clerides, S., Lach, S. and Tybout, J. (1998), 'Is learning by
exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence from Columbia, Mexico and
Morocco', Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXIII, pp. 903-48.
Cohen, W.M. and Levinthal, D.A. (1989), 'Innovation and
learning: the two faces of R&D', Economic Journal, 99, pp.
569-96.
Conover, W.J. (1999), Practical Nonparametric Statistics, New York,
John Wiley & Son.
Conyon, M.J., Girma, S., Thompson, S. and Wright, P.W (2001),
'The productivity and wage effects of foreign acquisition in the
United Kingdom', Journal of Industrial Economics, L, pp. 85-102.
Criscuolo, C. and Martin, R. (2002), 'Multinationals, foreign
ownership and productivity in UK businesses', Mimeo, Centre for
Research into Business Activity, ONS.
Delgano, M.A., Farinas, J.C. and Sonia, R (2002), 'Firm
productivity and export markets: a non-parametric approach',
Journal of International Economics, 57, pp. 397-422.
Dickerson, A.P., Gibson, H.E. and Tsakalotos, E. (1997), 'The
impact of acquisition on company performance: evidence from a large
panel of UK firms', Oxford Economic Papers, 49, pp. 344-61.
Doms, M.E. and. Jensen, J.B. (1998), 'Comparing wages, skills,
and productivity between domestically and foreign-owned manufacturing
establishments in the United States', in Baldwin, R., Lipsey, R.
and Richardson, J.D. (eds), Geography and Ownership as Bases for
Economic Accounting, Chicago, Chicago University Press.
Dunning, J.H. (1977), 'Trade, location of economic activity
and MNE: a search for an eclectic approach', in Ohlin, B.,
Hesselborn, P.O. and Wijkman, P.M. (eds), The international allocation
of economic activity, London, Macmillan.
Girma, S., Greenaway, D. and Kneller, R. (2002), 'Exporting
and productivity: a microeconometric analysis of matched firms',
GEP Working Paper, University of Nottingham.
Girma, S., Greenaway, D. and Wakelin, K. (2001), 'Who benefits
from foreign direct investment in the UK?', Scottish Journal of
Political Economy, 48, pp. 119-33.
Girma, S., Kneller, R. and Pisu, M. (2003), 'Exports versus
FDI: an empirical test', mimeo, University of Leicester.
Grant, R.M. (1987), 'Multinationality and performance among
British manufacturing companies', Journal of International Business
Studies, 18, pp. 79-89.
Grant, R.M., Jammine, J.P. and Thomas, H. (1988), 'Diversity,
diversification and profitability among British manufacturing
companies', Academy of Management Journal, 40, pp. 767-98.
Greniger, J.M., Beamish, P.W. and da Costas, R.C. (1989),
'Diversification strategy and internalization: implication for MNE
performance', Strategic Management Journal, 10, pp. 109-19.
Griffith, R. and Simpson, H. (2002), 'Characteristics of
foreign-owned firms in British manufacturing', in Blundell, R.,
Card D. and Freeman, R. (eds), Creating a Premier League Economy,
Chicago, Chicago University Press.
Gomes, L. and Ramaswamy, K. (1999), 'An empirical examination
of the form of the relationship between multinationality and
performance', Journal of International Business Studies, 30, pp.
173-88.
Han, K.C and Lee, S.H. (1998), 'Multinationality and firm
performance', Multinational Business Review, 6, pp. 63-70.
Harris, R. and Robinson, C. (2002), 'The effect of foreign
acquisitions on total factor productivity: plant-level evidence from UK
manufacturing, 1987-1992', The Review of Economics and Statistics,
84, pp. 562-8.
Hausman, J. and McFadden, D. (1984), 'Specification tests for
the multinomial logit model', Econometrica, 52, pp. 1219-40.
Head, K., Ries, J. and Swenson, D. (1995), 'Agglomeration
benefits and location choice: evidence from Japanese manufacturing
investments in the United States', Journal of International
Economics, 39, pp. 223-247.
Heckman, J.J. (1978), 'Dummy endogenous variables in a
simultaneous equation system', Econometrica, 46, pp. 931-59.
Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E. and Kim, H. (1997), 'International
diversification: effects on innovation and firm performance in product
diversified firms', Academy of Management Journal, 40, pp. 767-98.
Hymer, S.H. (1976), The International Operations of National Firms:
A Study of Direct Foreign Investment, Boston, MIT Press.
Jensen, M. (1986), 'Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate
finance and takeovers', American Economic Review: Papers and
Proceedings, 76, pp. 323-9.
Kindleberger, C.P. (1969), American Business Abroad: Six Lectures
on Direct Investment, New Haven, Yale University Press.
Koenker, R. and Bassett, G. (1978), 'Regression
quantiles', Econometrica, 50, pp. 43-61.
Kogut, B. (1985), 'Designing global strategies: profiting from
operational flexibility', Sloan Management Review, 26, pp. 27-38.
Kumar, M.S. (1984), Growth Acquisition and Investment, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Mathur, I., Singh, M. and Kinberly, C.G. (2001), 'The evidence
from Canadian firms on multinational diversification and
performance', The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 41,
pp. 561-78.
Melitz, M.J (2000),'Estimating firm-level productivity in
differentiated product industries', mimeo, Harvard University.
Meyer, B. (1994), 'Natural and quasi-experiments in
economics', NBER Technical Working Paper No. 170.
Palepu, K.G. (1986), 'Predicting takeover targets: a
methodological and empirical analysis', Journal of Accounting and
Economics, 8, pp. 3-35.
Rugman, A.M. (1974), 'Motivation for foreign investment: the
market imperfections and risk diversification hypotheses', Journal
of World Trade Law, 9, pp. 567-673.
Shapiro, D. (1983), 'Entry, exit and the theory of
multinational corporation, in Kindleberger, C. and Audretsch, D. (eds),
The Multinational Corporation in the 1980s, Cambridge, Mass.
Shleifer, A. and Summers, L.H. (1988), 'Breach of trust in
hostile takeovers', in Auerbach, A.J. (ed.), Corporate Takeovers:
Causes and Consequence, Chicago, NBER.
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1988), 'Value maximization and
the acquisition process', Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2, pp.
7-20.
Vella, F and Verbeek, M. (1999), 'Estimating and interpreting
models with endogenous treatment effects', Journal of Business and
Economic Statistics, 17, pp. 473-8.
Sourafel Girma, Department of Economics, University of Leicester.
E-mail: sg116@leicester.ac.uk. I wish to thank an anonymous referee for
some useful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. I also wish to
acknowledge the support of Martin Weale.