Commentary.
Riley, Rebecca ; Pain, Nigel ; Weale, Martin 等
The current situation
The last quarter has seen something of a recovery in economic
sentiment from the low levels reached in the autumn, while the recent
economic data present a confused picture with output weak and demand
growing strongly. Industrial production fell sharply in October and
suffered a further, more modest fall in November. For last year as a
whole the growth rate of 2.4 per cent is just below the figure forecast
by the Treasury and ourselves in the spring of last year, but slightly
higher than we were expecting in the summer and autumn. Perhaps the most
extraordinary aspect of the year, as far as the UK's economy has
been concerned, was the degree of gloom associated with a GDP growth
rate close to the long-term average.
2002 began with a market expectation that interest rates would rise
in the first half of this year, reaching well over 5 per cent per annum by the end of the year. Data released in January, together with comments
from the Governor of the Bank of England, damped expectations of an
early interest rate rise. No change is now expected until the middle of
the year but markets continue to expect an interest rate of 5 per cent
at the end of the year. Our forecast suggests that this is compatible
with inflation being on target (2 1/2 per cent per annum) in two years
time, although it will be lower this year and could drop below 1 1/2 per
cent per annum, the lower limit of the official range, in the middle of
the year. Our forecast is produced on the assumption that the Bank of
England stays independent and that Britain does not join the European
Monetary Union.
The improvement in sentiment does not necessarily presage a
recovery, although there are reasons for expecting one. First of all,
the recession in the United States was caused by the collapse of an
investment bubble. During the boom the share of investment in GDP had
risen considerably. On page 13 we show that the ratio has now fallen
back to the average of the last twenty-five years. It is also the case
that ratios of inventories to sales are low, even when allowance is made
for the steady downward trend in the ratio. The best explanation of this
is that it is because demand has been higher than businesses expected.
In consequence they are likely to want to increase inventory levels; in
itself this will create extra demand. Thus the combination of less
downward pressure on fixed capital formation and efforts to rebuild
inventory levels should support the early stages of an economic recovery
in the United States and thus in the world economy.
Despite these positive arguments, it is perfectly possible for
green shoots of recovery to wither and there remain two main reasons why
this might happen; we have discussed both at length in the past. First
of all, the growth of consumption, both in the United Kingdom and in the
United States, has been supported by declining household saving. This is
an unusual feature of an economy in recession like the United States but
is probably what would be expected in an investment-led recession.
Economic theory suggests that consumers should use savings to smooth out
fluctuations in incomes. Unless consumption is depressed by long-term
fears about the growth rate of income, this naturally implies that,
during a recession, saving should be low.
Theory aside, it is a source of concern that household debt levels
in both the United Kingdom and the United States are high, but of course
low interest rates make the debt easily affordable. In the United States
the household debt interest burden has fallen recently to its lowest
level for two years as interest rate reductions have more than offset
the effects of rising debt; in neither country do we see a return to the
high interest rates associated with the inflationary periods of the
past. Nevertheless, growth in both countries is vulnerable to changing
saving behaviour. There has been some concern that rising saving may be
provoked by rising unemployment. But, compared with past experience,
unemployment rates in both countries are low. In the United Kingdom we
do not anticipate a return to the high levels of unemployment seen in
the 1980s. In any case the effect of unemployment is likely to arise
mainly through its impact on consumer confidence and, as we have shown
recently (Pain and Weale, 2001), the e ffect of consumer confidence, as
measured in surveys, on consumer spending is small.
The second threat to economic growth continues to arise from the
levels of major stock markets. Looking at prices as multiples of
earnings these are high by comparison with anything except the recent
past. A further fall of share prices would depress consumer spending and
result in economic growth slower than we have forecast.
But the two factors which gave the UK average growth in 2001 remain
in place in 2002. There is the stimulus to consumer spending offered by
monetary policy. There is also the continuing rapid growth in public
spending. Public consumption of goods and services rose by 3 per cent
last year and the government's spending plans point to a further
increase of 4.8 per cent per annum this year. Growth in public sector
consumption and investment is expected to add 1.2 per cent to the
overall growth rate after a public sector contribution of 0.8 per cent
in 2001. With the combination of this fiscal stimulus and the monetary
stimulus offered by low interest rates it is not surprising that the
economy has been able to withstand the contractionary pressures of weak
investment and declining world trade much better than the three larger
economies, the United States, Germany and Japan.
The exchange rate
The physical appearance of the euro has given a new stimulus to the
debate about Britain's entry and also the debate about the rate at
which entry is appropriate, he manufacturing sector, in particular, is
arguing that the current exchange rate is far too high, and that a
substantial depreciation of sterling is needed before euro membership
could be entertained. HM Treasury, on the other hand, has been concerned
about the possible inflationary consequences of euro membership. With
increasing recognition that the five tests cannot be answered
unambiguously by economists (National Institute Economic Review, July
2000, p.4), the economic debate on membership is increasingly likely to
shift to a discus ion of an appropriate rate for membership.
Manufacturing accounts for less than 20 per cent of the overall
economy, but about two-thirds of exports; manufacturing is therefore
disproportionately affected by problems in export markets. It follows
that, at least in part, the argument from manufacturers for a lower
exchange rate may be a response to the weakness of world markets rather
than a reflection of the fact that, in normal trading conditions, the
exchange rate would be self-evidently much too high. Profit margins are
already so low that manufacturers are unable to increase their share of
a declining market by means of price reductions. A depreciation of the
exchange rate would give them room to improve their sales performance.
In 2000 Britain's exports grew almost as fast as world trade;
last year the data so far suggest that they grew slightly faster. The
rise in the exchange rate since the mid-1990s led to a fall in
Britain's share of world trade over the period 1997-9; the
stability in Britain's trading position relative to the rest of the
world last year reinforces our earlier view that the economy has now
broadly adjusted to the high exchange rate. The share of imports in
final demand continues to rise but this is a normal consequence of
economic growth and does not, in itself, indicate incomplete adjustment
to the exchange rate. The fundamental question is whether this
adjustment has led to an external deficit which is in any sense too
large. In 2001 our analysis suggests that the deficit was 1.4 per cent
of GDP, down from 1.8 per cent of GDP in 2000. A larger deficit is
projected this year with an increase to over 3 per cent of GDP in 2004
before falling back to under 2 per cent of GDP. Much larger trade
deficits are offset by surpluses in invisibles. The latter include a
number of erratic items, making them difficult to predict. But if the
United Kingdom retains an external deficit of 2 per cent of GDP as our
long-run forecast suggests and continues to grow in nominal terms at
around 5 per cent per annum, then its net external debts will settle at
40 per cent of GDP as compared to a current value of 10 per cent of GDP.
We do not see this as posing any particular problems. As a part of the
process, payments of interest and dividends to the rest of the world
will rise and the real exchange rate will have to depreciate so that
export earnings rise enough to cover this. But the process is slow and
can be accommodated by an inflation rate lower than the average of our
trading partners, particularly since these include developing countries
with rapid inflation as well as developed countries with low inflation.
Nevertheless, we continue to believe that a lower exchange rate against
the euro would be better and believe that EMU entry, if it occurs,
should be at around [pounds sterling]1 = [euro] 1.50 rather than the
current rate of [pounds sterling]1 = [euro]1.61.
Government spending and the fiscal position
The government's fiscal rules are that the current account
should at least be in balance over the cycle and that public debt should
be kept below 40 per cent of GDP. The cumulated current account surplus
since 1999, when the Government believes the current cycle began, has
been over [pounds sterling]40bn; we forecast a further surplus of
[pounds sterling]13bn this year. Taken together, these mean that that
deficits of well over [pounds sterling]50bn can be incurred in the rest
of the cycle, whilst meeting the fiscal rules.
This shows a weakness of the first fiscal rule. The timing of the
cycle is outside government control. If the cycle ends next year the
rule does not allow the cumulated surplus to be spent. If the current
cycle persists for a further ten years, then there will be plenty of
opportunity for spending the cumulated surplus. The rule would be less
arbitrary if it were defined in terms of a fixed window, say five or
seven years.
Looking ahead, recent weaknesses in the tax base, combined with
planned increased spending, leads to a current account of around zero
from next year onwards. This assumes growth in real spending on goods
and services of about 2.5 per cent in 2004 and 2005.
The outcome is spending over [pounds sterling]8 billion higher than
in the Government projection in 2005. If the recommendations of the
Wanless Report were implemented spending on health might rise by around
[pounds sterling]10bn (Wanless, 2001). It is not clear how much of this
would be investment rather than current spending. But our projection
suggests nearly all of the spending can be accommodated without leading
to a current deficit. Even if all of the increase were current spending
and the introduction of the Child Tax Credit, which provisional
estimates suggest could cost [pounds sterling]3 billion, led to an
overall increase in spending of [pounds sterling]13bn compared to
existing government plans, the cumulated surplus over the cycle so far
would be enough to pay for the extra public spending for several years
with no increases in taxes. We doubt that such a fiscal boost would be
consistent with a well-balanced economy, but it is important to note the
degree of flexibility available within the Gover nment's fiscal
rules. The budgetary position does not point to a need for tax increases
in the March budget, although taxes could still be raised if the
Government feels that this would improve macroeconomic stability.
We continue to be concerned that the Government finds it difficult
to meet its investment targets; this is probably because of excessive
reliance on public-private partnerships. Their complexities mean that
they can slow down the decision-making process and put obstacles in the
way of public investment.
Chart 1 shows just how low public net investment has been in this
country as compared to the United States, a country not noted for the
size of its public sector. The data for both countries are taken from
their national accounts so as to put them on a comparable basis. The UK
figures thus exclude capital grants to the private sector which are
included in HM Treasury figures for public net investment. The
comparison is all the more marked because the UK figures include
investment in areas such as the health service which are in the private
sector in the United States.
Arguably the official Treasury data overstate the Government's
true contribution to net investment as well as being not comparable with
those of some other countries. The figures include capital grants to the
private sector. However, unless the depreciation of investments financed
by such grants is included in the depreciation total, the figure is a
combination of net and gross amounts rather than a genuine net figure.
Productivity
We present on pages 38--43, our estimates of how productivity has
changed in France, Britain, Germany and the United States and also an
assessment of relative productivity levels.
The good productivity growth of the United States has been widely
discussed. So it is striking that our figures suggest that
Germany's productivity growth has been slightly better both in the
late 1990s and in the longer run. The factors behind Germany's
recent success are likely to be different from those influencing the
United States. At the start of the last decade Germany had just been
reunited. Productivity levels in East Germany were very poor and there
was considerable room for improvement.
The figures show that Britain itself continues to suffer from low
productivity. It might be hoped that Britain would benefit from the same
sort of catch-up process which has taken place in East Germany but these
data suggest that it is not doing so. A number of reasons are advanced
for this, with our preferred explanation being that Britain's
teaching and education system does not match the performance of others
in Europe (see OECD, 2001a, p. 45). In our previous issue we carried
articles on the problems with Britain's system of vocational
training; here we include two articles on maths teaching in Britain,
where much of the evidence suggests hat standards remain poor and could
be improved relatively cheaply by helping teachers to teach better.
It has to be said, however, that a recent study by the Organisation
of Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD, 2001b) suggested that
maths teaching in Britain's schools performs now well by
international standards. A National Institute paper (Prais, 2002) raises
a number of questions about the way that his study was carried out, and
suggests that these could have led to substantial biases.
The short-term economic outlook
We expect the broadly favourable position that Britain enjoyed last
year to continue with a growth rate of 2.1 per cent forecast for 2002
and 2.6 per cent in 2003. The international picture is likely to improve
as a US recovery is set in train. Inflation prospects continue to be
favourable, with inflation to the end of 2002 projected at 1.6 per cent
per annum rising to 2.5 per cent a ear later. The overall budget surplus
is forecast to be [pounds sterling]1 1/2bn with a surplus on the current
account of [pounds sterling]13bn. These figures are contingent on the
government managing to achieve its spending plans; past experience
suggests hat there remains some risk of under-spending.
REFERENCES
OECD (2001a), OECD Economic Survey: United Kingdom, Paris, OECD.
--(2001b), 'Knowledge and skills for life. First results from
PISA 2000'. 322 pages, Paris, OECD.
Pain, N. and Weale, M.R. (2001), 'The information content of
consumer surveys', Notional Institute Economic Review, 178, pp.
44-7.
Prais, S. (2002), 'Cautions on the recent OECD Educational
Surveys, NIESR, mimeo.
Wanless, D. (2001), Securing our Future Health: Toking a Long-term
View, London, HM Treasury,
http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Consultations_and_Legislation/wanless_i
ndex.cfm?
[Graph omitted]
Summary of the forecast
UK economy
Probabilities (a)
Inflation Real gross
target Output national Real
met (b) falling (c) income (d) GDP (d)
2001 - - 3.5 2.4
2002 84 1 2.2 2.1
2003 50 3 2.7 2.6
UK economy
Retail price index (f)
Manufactring
output (d) Unemployment (e) Excl.
All items mortgages
2001 -2.2 1.55 1.0 2.0
2002 -1.8 1.68 2.3 1.6
2003 2.1 1.75 2.6 2.5
UK economy World economy
Retail price
index (f)
Current Real Consumer
balance (g) PSNB (h) GDP prices (i)
2001 -14.0 -1.4 1.9 2.3
2002 -22.9 10.5 2.3 1.0
2003 -30.1 14.4 3.5 2.3
World economy
World
trade (j)
2001 0.3
2002 4.0
2003 8.1
(a)In percentage terms.
(b)Inflation excluding mortgages below 2 1/2 per cent per annum at the
end of the year.
(c)A fall in annual output.
(d)Percentage change, year-on-year.
(e)ILO definition, fourth quarter millions.
(f)Percentage change, fourth quarter on fourth quarter.
(g)Year, [pounds sterling] billion.
(h)Public sector net borrowing, fiscal year, [pounds sterling billion.
(i)OECD countries, percentage change, year-on-year.
(j)Volume of total world trade, percentage change, year-on-year.