Commentary.
Weale, Martin ; Riley, Rebecca ; Pain, Nigel 等
Introduction
It is now reasonably certain that the recovery to growth rates,
both in the United Kingdom and internationally, has started. While
growth in the first quarter was below the long-run average, we expect a
growth rate of about 0.7 to 0.8 per cent per quarter in the remainder of
this year; giving a growth rate of 2.6 per cent through the year (2002Q4
relative to 2001Q4) and a level of output 1.8 per cent higher this year
than last year. Inflationary pressures remain low and we expect
inflation to remain slightly below target until late next year.
For quit a while, and in particular since mid-September, our
forecasts have been slightly above the consensus. The experience of the
past eight months certainly demonstrates the pitfalls of paying too much
attention to movements in consumer and business confidence. However,
partly in the light of poor economic growth in the first quarter of the
year, lower projections for the growth of government spending this year
and a poor performance by British exporters in sales outside the Euro
Area, we are now more gloomy than we were three months ago. We had
expected the United Kingdom to be the fastest growing major economy this
year, as it was last year, while we now expect it to be beaten by both
Canada and the United States.
The international environment
In both the United Kingdom and the United States strong growth in
private consumption played the major role in sustaining overall output
growth at the end of last year. This was, no doubt, underpinned by the
interest rate reductions and was sharper in the United States where
interest rates were reduced much further. In purely arithmetic terms,
growth in government spending in the United States more than accounted
for the aggregate rise of 0.4 per cent in GDP in the fourth quarter of
last year. Thus it could also be said that the United States avoided a
second quarter of falling output only because of this contribution from
government spending. Without the expansion of public consumption growth,
the United States would have experienced recession and the United
Kingdom's performance would have been much more like that of other
countries.
The United States is, of course, experiencing further fiscal
stimulus, both because of the packages of tax cuts made over the past
year, and as a result of the higher military spending associated with
the aftermath of the destruction of the World Trade Centre. While we are
starting to hear the argument again that fiscal intervention is
invariably mistimed, the evidence of the fourth quarter of last year and
the prospects for this year suggest that a more appropriate adverb would
be sometimes. In 2002 we expect government demand to contribute 0.7
percentage points to growth in the United States and a further 0.6 per
cent of GDP is to be added to private sector income through tax cuts. In
the United Kingdom government spending will add 1 percentage point to
GDP. In the Euro Area, by contrast, government demand will add only 0.3
percentage points to GDP and there is little extra stimulus from tax
cuts. While interest rate reductions have undoubtedly been the dominant
factor in supporting the world economy, the i mportance of discretionary
fiscal developments should not be overlooked.
It is easy, also, to overlook the impact of the developing
countries. Measured in purchasing power parity terms, the economies of
China and India are now larger than Britain's. On the same basis
the expansion of these two economies is estimated to have contributed
over 40 per cent of world economic growth in 2001.
Interest rate and inflation prospects
At home there are conflicting signals for interest rates. On the
one hand, inflation remains below target and wage pressures are easing
despite continued falls in unemployment. On the other hand, as growth
rates return to normal and with only a small output gap, it is difficult
to see interest rates staying as low as 4 per cent per annum for much
longer. The term structure of interest rates suggests that markets
expect rates to rise by 1/4 point in the next three months and to reach
5 per cent by the end of the year and our forecast reflects this. This
rise is slightly later than had been expected in the winter reflecting,
in turn, the fact that growth in the first quarter appears to have been
sluggish. However, it is possible that the Monetary Policy Committee
will want to wait for evidence that growth rates have returned to the
long-run average before they start raising rates. Even then, on past
form, the rise may be fairly gradual because of concerns that a sudden
rise might weaken confidence again. Thus t he rise could well be slower
and later than current market expectations. In the short term, the
Budget amounts to a modest fiscal tightening, but beyond 2003/4 it has
given a stimulus to the economy, putting upward pressure on interest
rates. Indeed by 2006/7 the stimulus reaches about 1 per cent of GDP,
similar to the much-discussed fiscal package in the United States. We
discuss this further below.
The proposed expansion of the health service and the increase in
other categories of public spending does raise some awkward problems
about pay, despite the favourable combination of declining wage
inflation and falling unemployment which the country has been enjoying
in the early part of this years. In April 2001 the average weekly pay of
a full-time worker in the public sector was [pounds]432, while for the
private sector it was [pounds]450. Increased demand for workers in the
public sector is likely to lead to upward pressure on wages, and it is
plain that the Government has revised upward its expectations of cost
movements in the public sector. The increase in the cost of public
sector consumption is now expected to be 1 per cent higher this year
than was anticipated in the Pre-Budget Report of November last year.
Focus on the Monetary Union
In this Review we include four articles on aspects of the Euro Area
and the European Union. The main points which emerge from our analysis
are that there is a body of evidence which suggests that joining single
currency areas can have a very favourable effect on trade and income
levels, although there are reasons to believe that these overstate the
benefits which would be likely to accrue to Britain because they are
mainly based on findings for much smaller and less-developed countries.
Euro Area membership would be likely to lead to a more stable price
level as a result of removing the influences of exchange rate changes
against much of Europe and this might be expected to be good for
investment, although a reduction to exchange rate uncertainty could
actually discourage some types of foreign investment in Britain (Pain,
2002, p.96).
However, O'Mahony (2002, p.72) argues that productivity
differences between different European countries are more due to
differences in infrastructure and skill bases, so that membership of the
Euro Area could be expected to have only a relatively small effect on
productivity. Employment depends mainly on labour market structures
rather than monetary arrangements, but the effects of improved
productivity on real wages could have a favourable effect on labour
force participation and thus on employment. In terms of similarities
between financial institutions in the United Kingdom and the Euro Area,
Byrne and Davis (2002, p. 83) point out the diversity in the structures
of financial markets and financial institutions within the existing Euro
Area. Britain fits inside the existing spread of Euro Area financial
structures instead of lying outside it. Thus there is no reason to
believe that Britain would face any particular need to make its
structures converge to a monolithic Euro Area model.
It is in the nature of research that, since more and more
information can accrue, no one could expect the five rests on Euro Area
membership to be answered beyond all reasonable doubt. However; Barrell
(2002, p. 54) concludes that they have been met for practical purposes.
The question of the exchange rate continues to dog the issue of
Euro Area membership and with it the question of whether and by how much
sterling is overvalued. Barrell (2002, p. 54) concludes that the
benefits of Euro Area membership should be compared to the transition
costs of entering at the wrong rate, either too low or too high. In
particular the benefits from greater exchange rate stability may have to
be set against the short to medium-term output losses that would come
from entering at an overvalued exchange rate. Pain (2002, p.96)
acknowledges that joining the Euro Area at too high an exchange rate
might mean that the benefits of membership never arrive. Barrell
simulates the effects of membership at different exchange rates and
suggests that in view of the risks involved membership should take place
in the range [pounds sterling]1 = [euro]1.50-1.55. But a particular
problem could arise if Britain were to join at even 1.50, and the euro
were to subsequently rise markedly against the US dollar.
Perhaps it is harder to see the exchange rate adjusting outside the
Euro Area than if Britain were to join. Given the fact that the
inflation targets are similar in Britain and in the Euro Area, and that
jumps to exchange rates cannot sensibly be forecast, it follows that for
the real exchange rate to be expected to change against the euro, either
Britain has to be expected to undershoot its inflation target or the
Euro Area has to be expected to overshoot its target. With both the Bank
of England and the European Central Bank having broadly similar
inflation targets, it is difficult to see how this could happen.
Financial markets expect only small changes to the nominal exchange rate and they also expect, based on a comparison of the interest rate on
indexed government stocks, that inflation in the United Kingdom is
expected to be faster than that in France, driving the real exchange
rate up rather than down.
We have previously attributed much of the weakness in manufacturing
to weakness in world trade (Riley, Pain and Weale, 2002) rather than the
high exchange rate, and it will be interesting to see whether
manufacturing output starts to recover as world trade improves.
Certainly we note that recently business sentiment has improved, which
is encouraging. On the other hand, early evidence suggests that, having
held its share of world trade for two years, Britain saw it decline in
the fourth quarter of 2001. This is, nevertheless, difficult to
interpret because the decline was in exports to non-EU countries, while
the concern about overvaluation is most marked vis a vis the euro.
However, there is no doubt that a lower exchange rate would increase
manufacturing margins, which are now low and are probably curtailing
manufacturing investment. Manufacturers must be puzzled why the
government is concerned about the effects of euro membership on the
financial services industry, which are directly explored in one of the
five tests, more than it seems concerned about the impact of
non-membership on manufacturing industry.
Government spending and the long-term fiscal position
The government's spending plans and the Wanless report
(Wanless, 2002) point the way to further increases in taxation. There
are several factors compounded. First of all, an analysis by the
National Institute based on long-term projections implied that, for the
public sector to remain solvent, i.e. with the present discounted value
of spending plans equal to the present discounted value of revenues, but
not taking account of the budget changes, taxes needed to be raised by
0.5 per cent of GDP. The longer such a tax rise is delayed the larger it
becomes. But this calculation inevitably relies on a number of arbitrary
assumptions and one could regard the position pre-budget as having been
broadly consistent with long-term balance.
Secondly, we are now concerned that the Government's tax
revenue forecasts are over-optimistic. Our own model of the economy
indicates that, for the Government to meet its own revenue target for
2006/7, a second tranche of taxation equal to 0.5 per cent of GDP is
needed. This difference arises mainly because our general view of tax
revenue is less buoyant than is the Government's.
Thirdly, even with the tax increase, our forecast shows public
borrowing higher in 2006/7 by [pounds sterling]7bn (0.5 per cent of GDP)
compared to the Pre-Budget Report. Given the position before the budget,
which we regard as reasonably close to long-term balance, this extra
deficit needs correcting with an additional tax rise.
Wanless suggests that spending on the health service is likely to
need to rise further, from the 7.8 per cent of GDP which the Chancellor
expects to reach in 2006/7, to an eventual 9.9 per cent of GDP, creating
a need for further taxation of 2.1 per cent of GDP. This figure may be
reduced, if rising incomes mean that the proportion of health treatment
provided privately increases. But it is more likely that, if the quality
of National Health Service treatment improves, there will be a flow of
patients back to the National Health Service, and the expenditure faced
by the public purse will be increased.
Taking these figures together, the implication is that for the full
implementation of the Wanless Report and of the other changes described
in the budget, total extra taxation of over 3 per cent of GDP is needed.
We should, however, note first that there are inevitably large error
margins around these calculations and secondly, that if the tax rises
are implemented ahead of the spending increases, then the eventual size
of the tax rises is somewhat reduced. But, starting from the finding
that the public sector was, before the budget, close to balance, there
is the clear implication that, given the budget and if Wanless'
proposals are to be implemented in full, very substantial further tax
rises will be needed.
Effects on saving
There is another aspect of the Budget which merits some attention.
At a time when the government is keen to encourage saving for
retirement, there is more than a small risk that the increased revenue
will be paid for out of saving rather than out of consumption.
Logically, it ought to make no difference whether taxes are collected as
payroll taxes paid by firms or as income taxes paid by employees. In
much the same way, labour markets should establish wage rates based on
overall labour costs, taking on board factors such as employers'
pension contributions. But in practice these market forces may take some
time to work through the system. Firms are likely to meet at least some
of the increased national insurance employers' contributions by
reducing pension contributions. Since it is unlikely that such
reductions are immediately offset by other increases to household
saving, the overall impact may well be a reduction to saving. In
consequence, while the extra national insurance contributions will raise
revenue , they will not reduce demand as much as might have been
expected. It is true that, because national insurance contributions are
not paid on employers' pension contributions, there will be a
substitution effect encouraging pension contributions. We expect this to
be more than offset by the income effect set out above.
This pattern would follow one we have seen since 1997, with a sharp
increase in public sector revenues being associated with a sharp fall in
household saving. It has the consequence that interest rates will be
pushed higher than if the tax revenue had been collected from a tax such
as VAT which impacted more upon consumption. In that sense the budget is
likely to be expansionary in both the short and the long term.
Summary of the forecast
UK economy
Probabilities (a)
Inflation Real gross Manufact-
target Output national Real uring
met (b) falling (c) income (d) GDP (d) output (d)
2001 - - 2.9 2.2 -2.3
2002 74 1 1.7 1.8 -2.8
2003 50 2 3.4 2.9 2.0
UK economy
Retail price index (f)
Unemploy- Excl. Current
ment (e) All items mortgages balance (g) PSNB (h)
2001 5.1 1.0 2.0 -17.4 -2.6
2002 5.4 2.5 2.0 -28.2 12.0
2003 5.7 2.7 2.5 -28.9 15.1
World economy
Real Consumer World
GDP prices (i) trade (j)
2001 2.4 2.1 0.0
2002 2.6 1.5 3.6
2003 3.7 2.1 8.5
(a)In percentage terms.
(b)Inflation excluding mortgages below 2 1/2 per cent per annum at the
end of the year.
(c)A fall in annual output.
(d)Percentage change, year-on-year.
(e)ILO definition, four quarter rate.
(f)Percentage change, fourth quarter on fourth quarter.
(g)Year, [pounds] billion.
(h)Public sector net borrowing, fiscal year, [pounds] billion.
(i)OECO countries, percentage change, year-on-year.
(j)Volume of total world trade, percentage change, year-on-year.
REFERENCES
Barrell, R. (2002), 'The UK and EMU: choosing the
regime', National Institute Economic Review, 180, April.
Byrne, J and P. Davis. (2002), 'A comparison of balance sheet
structures in major EU countries', National Institute Economic
Review, 180, April.
O'Mahony, M. (2002), 'Productivity and convergence in the
EU', National Institute Economic Review, 180, April.
Pain, N. (2002), 'EMU, investment and growth: some unresolved
issues', National Institute Economic Review, 80, April.
Riley, R, N. Pain and M.R. Weale. (2002), 'Commentary',
National Institute Economic Review, 179, January, p. 5.
Wanless, D. (2002), 'Securing our future health: taking a
long-term view',
http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Consultations_and_Legislation/wanless/c
onsult_wanless_final.cfm