Dating the business cycle in Britain.
Artis, Michael
The NIESR's monthly GDP series is an innovative feature; most
GDP estimates are published at an annual, or quarterly frequency at
best. For purposes of dating the business cycle the availability of this
series is an asset, unexploited until this paper. The paper applies a
version of the standard business (or 'classical') cycle dating
algorithm to the data, after light smoothing to remove outliers. Three
classical cycles are detected in the period between the early 1970s and
2002, with turning points which are close to (but usually precede)
classical cycle dating which does not benefit from the availability of
monthly GDP, and instead relies on a 'coincident' indicator
methodology. In addition the turning points of a deviation cycle are
identified.
Introduction
The intention in this paper is to provide a dating of the business
cycle in Britain using the National Institute's innovative series
of monthly GDP (see Salazar et al., 1997) as a base. In the usual way
analysts will describe the cycle as a recurrent -- but not strictly
periodic -- oscillation in the general level of economic activity. The
latter term, in turn, is taken to betoken that a business cycle is
pervasive. Gross Domestic Product is widely accepted as the best measure
we can think of to represent the general level of economic activity and
it is generally assumed that the measure takes adequate account of the
'pervasiveness' that is required in the definition of the
cycle. This being so, most business cycle studies nowadays proceed at
the quarterly or national level, as the availability of GDP data allows.
For dating purposes, however, even the quarterly frequency is rather
coarse; for a given 'true' incidence of peak or trough in a
given month, the corresponding registration of that peak or trough in
quarterly data can easily slip by a quarter. A true peak-incidence in,
say, March, may easily not show up until Quarter 2, thus not making it
distinct from, say, June. This is rather unsatisfactory and analysts
have tried to track the business cycle at a higher frequency in one of
two alternative ways. One way is simply to use the data on industrial
production which are, quite frequently, available at a monthly frequency
(see e.g., Artis et al., 1997, Artis and Toro, 2000). There are at least
two problems with this: industrial production is a declining and, in the
UK now, quite small proportion of overall economic activity as measured
by GDP; second, the series is very noisy, making it sometimes difficult
to turn the higher frequency of availability to good advantage. A second
approach, practised by the analysts at the Economic Cyclical Research
Institute (ECRI: http://www.businesscycle.com/) is to use data on a
variety of series available at the monthly level in an endeavour to be
guided by them to a consen sus on turning points for the general level
of economic activity. In this respect they are following in the
footsteps of the NBER 'founding fathers' of business cycle
analysis -- analysts like Burns, Mitchell and Moore. It will be natural
for us to compare our dating chronology with ECRI's.
In fact we shall produce two chronologies, not just one. The
terminology of 'the business cycle' belongs strictly to that
of the so-called 'classical cycle', where peaks (and troughs)
are marked by subsequent absolute declines (increases) in the chosen
measure of economic activity. But there is also the concept of the
'growth' or 'deviation' cycle, where peaks (and
troughs) are essentially marked by upward (downward) inflections in the
growth rate of the chosen measure of economic activity. This latter
concept of the cycle involves some form of de-trending, where a number
of papers (e.g., Canova, 1998; Osborn, 1995) have shown that there exist
substantial pitfalls awaiting the unwary. Even whilst avoiding the most
obvious of these pitfalls it must immediately be obvious that the
objective of precision in dating will be compromised by the smoothing
involved in the de-trending.
In what follows, we begin in the next section by discussing the
construction of the monthly GDP series as it is described in the
relevant paper (Salazar et al., 1997), and its suitability for our
purpose. In the third section we discuss the concept of the classical
cycle and the algorithm we apply to dating it in the monthly GDP series.
We then discuss some pertinent aspects of the results and compare the
dating we obtain with that obtained by ECRI, also at a monthly level:
more tentatively, we also compare our chronology with the dates proposed
for quarterly GDP in Krolzig and Toro (2001). In the fourth section we
turn to the concept of the growth or deviation cycle, again comparing
our results with those of ECRI.
Monthly GDP
Our basic data series, of monthly GDP, were supplied by the
National Institute of Economic and Social Research and cover the period
from January 1974 to February 2002, on a seasonally adjusted basis. The
method of construction of the data relies heavily on the use of a
technique analogous to the well-known 'Chow-Lin' (1971) method
of interpolating data from related series to the one in question.
Somewhat more than 75 per cent of the (output) series making up GDP are
interpolated this way, which involves the use of genuinely monthly data
to this extent. The remainder, slightly less than a quarter of the
total, is simply interpolated from quarterly series on the output
components involved -- agriculture and non-marketed (public) services --
and does not represent the use of data points observed at the monthly
level. The proportion of the total based on genuine monthly inputs
should be great enough to make the objective of a monthly dating of the
cycle one that is within reach. The data are split into five compo nents
altogether: agriculture (1.9 per cent), industrial production (27.8 per
cent), construction (7.2 per cent), marketed (private sector) services (
41.9 per cent) and non-marketed (public sector) services (21.2 per
cent): the percentage shares are the weights with which the components
are combined to yield total GDP.
As will be demonstrated below, industrial production is among the
more cyclical of these components. However, the fact that the main other
component series are less noisy in general has the advantage that the
overall GDP series is less noisy than that of industrial production
alone. Correspondingly, the need to smooth the series prior to
identifying the turning points should be less pressing and the
subsequent identification procedure should be less plagued by problems
of 'smearing' that arise when smoothing is heavy and there is
consequently considerable uncertainty about the exact timing of events.
The classical cycle
The concept of the classical cycle has recently reclaimed a degree
of popularity. Dating the peak of the cycle by reference to a subsequent
absolute decline in output no longer seems such a 'rare event'
activity as it did before the first oil shock; moreover, the intervening
popularity of the growth cycle has suffered from the realization that
detrending techniques may spuriously create cycles of their own and
shift the timing of the turning points in undesirable ways.
The demands of a classical cycle dating algorithm are relatively
few: first, peaks are to be defined by reference to an immediate
subsequent downturn in the absolute level of output and troughs by
immediate recovery in the level of output. Then, peaks and troughs are
required to alternate; finally, to qualify as cycle phases the downturns
and upturns are required to fulfil minimum duration requirements (here
five months in each case), whilst the cycle as a whole will only be
identified as such provided that it lasts for fifteen months or more.
These criteria have been inherited from the computer algorithm devised
by Bry and Boschan (1971) to mimic for a univariate series the
identification procedures implemented by the NBER in its cycle dating
procedures. Subsequently, the Bry-Boschan (BB) algorithm has also been
adapted for data at the quarterly frequency (as in Pagan (2002) for
example), whilst eliminating some of the steps suggested in the
original. Using the methodology of the Markov chain, it can be show n
how the various restrictions listed here can be enforced (and how they
can be supplemented by additional restrictions on amplitude if desired):
see Appendix A to Artis et al. (2002).
The remaining issue is then to decide to what transformation of the
data (if any) the dating algorithm should be applied. For example, it
would seem desirable to eliminate seasonal fluctuations, and possibly
what appear to be outlier observations (preferably, where these can be
identified with a causal event, like a strike, or a bad harvest). This
removes the possibility of confusing cyclical with merely seasonal
fluctuation, or confounding the reaction to a strike with a cyclical
phenomenon. No sooner are these things said than some cautions come to
mind: for example, some cyclical phenomena are plainly initiated by
shocks that might look like outliers at the time, whilst the
difficulties of detecting and removing seasonality are well-known. Here,
although the original data are in principle seasonally adjusted,
experiment suggested that a mild degree of smoothing would be advisable;
the HP filter (Hodrick and Prescott, 1997), with [lambda] = 0.52 being
applied for this purpose. (1)
Chart 1 shows the original series, the filtered series and the
dates of the troughs and peaks selected. When the dating algorithm was
applied to the raw data series, many more cycles were identified --
fully twice as many. A glance at the chart will show the reader why and
should convince her that a degree of smoothing is needed. The procedure
leading to the identification of the turning points in GDP can easily be
replicated for the component series and the 'stylized facts'
(Pagan, 2002) calculated: these results are shown in table 1. The
display prompts a number of observations. Virtually three complete
cycles in GDP are detected in the period. They are highly asymmetrical,
as should be expected of a growth economy - the average amount of time
spent in the expansion phase (that is, from trough to peak) is nearly
seven times as large as the amount of time spent in recession (that is
from peak to trough) -- as indicated by the average probability
statistics shown in the third and fourth rows of the table. The same
asymmetry is again expressed in the difference between the average
monthly duration of expansions (row 5) and the average monthly duration
of recessions (row 6). Amplitude is measured as the average of the
percentage increase in GDP in expansion and (decline in) recession
phases, whilst 'steepness' is the quotient of the amplitude
and duration. It can be seen that the two phases are in fact about
equally steep, the larger expansion amplitudes being offset by their
greater duration. A notable feature is the unusually long expansion
phase that set in after the last identified trough, some ten years ago.
All the calculations can be replicated for components of GDP as shown in
the table. It is noticeable that construction and industrial production
are about equally cyclical, judged by the number of cycles identified in
the period, and are much more cyclical than the service sectors or GDP
as a whole. Interestingly, agriculture is shown as the most cyclical of
all sectors; but this sector is of little import ance in the make-up of
GDP as a whole in the UK and the monthly series is purely interpolated
from quarterly data.
Because the Economic Cyclical Research Institute (ECRI) has been
producing monthly turning points in the UK classical cycle for some time
now, without benefit of the NIESR's monthly GDP, it is interesting
to compare the ECRI chronology with our own. ECRI's procedures
depend on their identification of a coincident indicator series; their
description of their dating procedure can be quoted from their website
as follows: "In line with the procedure used to determine the
official US recession and expansion dates, the business cycle peak and
trough dates for each country are chosen on the basis of the best
consensus among the dates of the turning points in the coincident index
and its components, i.e., the key measures of output, income, employment
and sales."
The comparison of the dates identified by ECRI and ourselves is
given in table 2. This shows in general quite a good correspondence. The
same number of cycles is identified in the period in question and the
turning points identified are generally within three months of each
other (and in one case coincident). Only the dating of the last trough
is more discrepant (with a difference of seven months). It is noticeable
that, with the exception of the one coincident dating, our dating tends
to lead ECRI's. It is conceivable -- though this can only remain a
speculation in the absence of more detailed knowledge of ECRI's
procedures -- that the reason for this is that employment is counted by
ECRI among the components of the coincident indicator, whereas it is
known to lag output. More generally, the chronologies should be noted as
encouragingly similar. A comparison with the chronology suggested by
Krolzig and Toro (2001) offers less close correspondence: the
Krolzig-Toro dating is carried out on quarterly GDP, and five cycles are
identified over the period for which we have selected only three. Those
three, however, find a close correspondence with the Krolzig-Toro dates.
(2)
The deviation cycle
The deviation or growth cycle takes off from a definition of the
upper turning point as one which is marked by a decline in the growth
rate, with the lower turning point symmetrically defined as being marked
by an increase in the growth rate. Such a definition could lead to a
peak (trough) being identified even when the observation in question was
below (above) trend and needs to be supplemented to avoid this
contingency: alternatively we can define a cycle as a growth rate cycle
in the absence of the additional stipulation about the relative level of
the growth rate variable. Again, as with the classical cycle, it is
standard to specify minimum duration restrictions both for the
individual phases and for the cycle as a whole (here, 5, 5 and 15 months
respectively). It is the growth or deviation cycle that has occupied
centre stage in postwar business cycle studies until recently and
analysts have used many different methods for detrending or filtering
the series. The most popular in recent years have been th e
Hodrick-Prescott filter (Hodrick and Prescott, 1997) and the Baxter-King
filter (Baxter and King, 1999). The H-P filter is normally treated as a
variant on the linear filter in which the user is able to allow for a
flexible trend to appear by setting the dampening parameter [lambda] at
an appropriate value (e.g. Ravn and Uhlig, 1997). The Baxter-King filter
-- or almost-ideal band-pass filter -- has gained in popularity recently
perhaps because it promises to be less arbitrary. The filter relies on
eliminating frequencies higher and lower than those pertaining to the
business cycle and only some assumption needs to be made about what
those are, where there is a high degree of agreement that the cycle is
around 1.5 to 8 or 10 years in length. The method of computation,
however, involves a relatively severe loss of data points at either end
of the sample; sometimes this can be made good by relying on forecast
data to supplement the sample. However, as explained at greater length
in Artis et al. (2002), the Ba xter-King filter can be closely
replicated by using the difference between two H-P filters , the
relevant values of [lambda] being chosen to isolate to periodicities
between (here) 15 and 96 months. (3) The resultant series contains just
the business cycle periodicities that we wish to entertain.
Chart 2 shows the H-P bandpass filtered series. The dating
algorithm is applied to the transformed series to detect the turning
points and characteristics of the cycles identified. The turning point
dates and the resultant stylized facts are shown, respectively, in chart
2 and table 3; again the procedure has been mechanically replicated for
the component series of monthly GDP.
The table shows a number of items of interest. First, the number of
cycles identified is larger than in the case of the classical cycle -
about twice as many in this sample period. Second, the data shown on the
relative frequency, duration and amplitude now indicate a high degree of
symmetry in the cycles identified, as opposed to the case with the
classical cycle. Chart 2 suggests a trend towards diminishing
volatility, or declining amplitude, in the cycle. A comparison with the
identification made by ECRI is given in table 4: however, it should be
noted immediately that the ECRI growth cycle is in fact defined as a
growth rate cycle, and this may have led to some of the discrepancies
between the dating suggested in this paper and theirs. At any rate, the
correspondence is less than we saw in the case of the classical cycle;
even so, of the nine peaks identified in this paper, no less than four
appear in the ECRI chronology within a month or at the same time; of the
eight troughs identified, four appear in t he ECRI chronology within two
months of the dates identified here. Still, there is plainly a certain
amount of disagreement. Krolzig and Toro (2001) do not provide a
deviation cycle dating, and whilst there are many papers dealing with
the growth cycle on quarterly and annual UK data (Artis, Marcellino and
Proietti (2002) is a recent example), not many provide a chronology of
turning points; at the same time, the methods of detrending used differ
considerably, as do the data vintages and frequencies used, so that it
appeared comparatively uninformative to attempt further comparisons
here.
Conclusions
The UK monthly GDP series is unique in representing a carefully
constructed estimate of GDP at a high frequency. Sufficient genuine
monthly information is incorporated in the estimate to make it
reasonable to choose it as the monthly proxy for the general level of
economic activity on which cyclical analysis is focussed. However, this
is not the end of the matter. In order to use the series for the
identification of cyclical turning points, a dating algorithm is needed
and some degree of smoothing appears necessary. The algorithm will
contain restrictions to ensure that it is a cycle which is being
identified and not some other more short-lived phenomenon; smoothing
performs a similar function.4 These stages involve judgment and
discretion, even if they are ultimately written down as rules. Matters
become more complicated when it is desired to investigate the growth or
deviation cycle. The particular selections made in the rules used in
this paper to isolate the classical cycle turn out to produce results
qui te close (but generally with a short lead) to those already
established by ECRI, which embodies the NBER tradition in business cycle
dating. For the case of the deviation cycle the correspondence is not so
close as, in general, might be expected.
[GRAPH 1 OMITTED]
[GRAPH 2 OMITTED]
Table 1
The classical cycle: cycle characteristics, UK monthly GDP series
Components Industry Agriculture Construction
Number of cycles P-P: 7 11 7
Number of cycles T-T: 6 10 8
Average expansion probability 0.73 0.51 0.56
Average recession probability 0.25 0.47 0.43
Average duration of expansions 35.39 15.79 26.86
Average duration of recessions 14.33 15.80 18.00
Average amplitude of expansions 0.11 0.10 0.13
Average amplitude of recessions -0.076 -0.087 -0.075
Steepness of expansions 0.003 0.006 0.005
Steepness of recessions -0.005 -0.005 -0.004
Components Private services Public services
Number of cycles P-P: 4 2
Number of cycles T-T: 4 2
Average expansion probability 0.83 0.89
Average recession probability 0.16 0.11
Average duration of expansions 70.18 149.87
Average duration of recessions 13.50 18.00
Average amplitude of expansions 0.25 0.23
Average amplitude of recessions -0.025 -0.014
Steepness of expansions 0.003 0.001
Steepness of recessions -0.002 -0.001
Components GDP
Number of cycles P-P: 3
Number of cycles T-T: 3
Average expansion probability 0.85
Average recession probability 0.14
Average duration of expansions 95.91
Average duration of recessions 15.67
Average amplitude of expansions 0.23
Average amplitude of recessions -0.036
Steepness of expansions 0.002
Steepness of recessions -0.002
Note: Seasonally adjusted monthly series were additonally smoothed with
Butterworth Filter (2, 1.25*12), and then the dating algorithm was
applied (BBM).
Table 2
Comparative dating of the classical cycle
ECRI This paper
Peaks Troughs Peaks Troughs
Sept 74 Aug 75 July 74 May 75
June 79 May 81 June 79 Feb 81
May 90 Mar 92 Mar 90 Aug 91
Table 3
Characteristic of the deviation cycle in UK monthly GDP
Series Industry Agriculture Construction
Number of cycles P-P 7 10 7
Number of cycles T-T 7 9 7
Average expansion probability 0.54 0.51 0.53
Average recession probability 0.46 0.49 0.47
Average duration of expansions 26.29 17.10 25.57
Average duration of recessions 22 18.56 22.71
Average amplitude of expansions 0.06 0.07 0.07
Average amplitude of recessions -0.06 -0.08 -0.08
Steepness of expansions 0.002 0.004 0.004
Steepness of recessions -0.003 -0.004 -0.004
Private
Series services Public Services GDP
Number of cycles P-P 7 7 9
Number of cycles T-T 6 8 8
Average expansion probability 0.59 0.60 0.57
Average recession probability 0.41 0.40 0.43
Average duration of expansions 28.43 29.00 21.33
Average duration of recessions 23.17 16.87 18.25
Average amplitude of expansions 0.03 0.01 0.02
Average amplitude of recessions -0.03 -0.01 -0.02
Steepness of expansions 0.001 0.0005 0.001
Steepness of recessions -0.001 -0.001 -0.001
Note: Seasonally adjusted monthly series were smoothed with the HP
Bandpass filter ([p.sub.1] = 1.25 * 12; i.e. lower bc period 15 months,
[p.sub.2] = 8 * 12, i.e. upper bc period 8 years; lambda, = 33.4476,
[lambda.sub.2] =.54535). No threshold was used. Then, a monthly dating
algorithm BCDatingMDevCycle was applied, based on BBM.
Table 4
Comparative dating of the deviation cycle
ECRI This paper
Peaks Troughs Peaks Troughs
Jan 73 May 75 July 74 June 75
July 76 Apr 77 Jan 77 June 77
June 79 May 80 May 79 Mar 81
Oct 83 Aug 84 Oct 83 Aug 84
May 85 Dec 85 Apr 85 Feb 86
Jan 88 Apr 91 Sept 88 June 92
July 94 Aug 95 Sept 94 July 96
July 97 Feb 99 Apr 98 Mar 99
Jan 00 Oct 00
NOTES
(1.) The data are in principle already seasonally adjusted at
source; the idea is simply to remove outliers and any excess seasonality
that may remain.
(2.) The dates of peaks identified by Krolzig and Toro in the
period covered by the present study are: Q3, 74; Q4, 76; Q2, 79; QI 84;
Q2, 80. For troughs the dates are: Q3, 75; Q3, 77; Q2, 81: Q3, 84; Q2,
92.
(3.) Kaiser and Maravall (1999) show how the H-P filter can be
treated as a low pass filter, leading to the idea of a subtraction of
one from another as a bandpass filter.
(4.) Although not demonstrated here, in related work (Artis et al.,
2002) it has been found that light smoothing is a good substitute for
restrictions on amplitude.
REFERENCES
Artis, M.J., Kontomelis, Z, and Osborn, D. (1997), 'Business
cycles for G7 and European countries, Journal of Business, 70, pp.
249-79.
Artis, M.J., Marcellino, M. and Proietti, T. (2002), 'Dating
the Euro Area business cycle', mimeo. EUI, Florence, September.
Artis, M.J., and Toro, J. (2000), 'Testing for common patterns
in European business cycle chronologies', Greek Economic Review,
20, Autumn, pp. 77-92.
Baxter, M. and King, R.G. (1999), 'Measuring business cycles:
approximate band-pass filters for economic time series', Review of
Economics and Statistics, 81, pp. 575-93
Bry, G. and Boschan, C. (1971), 'Cyclical aspects of time
series: selected procedures and computer programs', National Bureau
of Economic Research, Technical Paper No 20.
Canova, F. (1998), 'De-trending and business cycle
facts', Journal of Monetary Economics, 41, pp. 475-512.
Chow, G.C. and Lin, A.L. (1971), 'Best linear unbiased
interpolation, distribution and extrapolation of time series by related
series', Review of Economics and Statistics, 53, pp. 372-75.
Hodrick, R.J. and Prescott, E.C. (1997), 'Post-war US business
cycles: an empirical investigation', Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 29, pp. 1-16.
Kaiser, R. and Maravall, A. (1999), Estimation of the Business
Cycle: A Modified Hodrick-Prescott Filter, Madrid, Banco de Espana.
Krolzig, H.-M. and Toro, J. (2001), 'Classical and modern
business cycle measurement the European case', University of
Oxford, Discussion Papers in Economics, 60.
Osborn, D.R. (1995), 'Moving average detrending and the
analysis of business cycles', Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, 57, pp. 547-58.
Pagan, A. (2002), 'Lectures on the business cycle',
mimeo, EUI, Florence, April.
Ravn, M.O. and Uhlig, H. (1997). 'On adjusting the hp-filter
for the frequency of observations', Center Discussion Papers, 50.
Salazar, E., Smith, R., Weale, M. and Wright, S. (1997), 'A
monthly indicator of GDP', National Institute Economic Review, 161,
July, pp. 84-90.
Michael Artis *
* EUI, Florence, University of Manchester and CEPR. The author is
grateful to Ekaterina Vostroknoutova for research assistance and to
Tommaso Proietti for his BB(M) progammes.