COMPARATIVE PROPERTIES OF MODELS OF THE UK ECONOMY.
Church, Keith B. ; Sault, Joanne E. ; Sgherri, Silvia 等
Kenneth F. Wallis [*]
This article analyses the properties of five leading
macroeconometric models of the UK economy, as revealed in four
simulation experiments. These are carried out in a common operating
environment that reflects the broad objectives of current policy --
sound public finances and low inflation -- by using feedback rules for
income tax and interest rates. Developments in the structure of the
models as revealed by the series of such exercises carried out during
the lifetime of the ESRC Macroeconomic Modelling Bureau (1983-99) are
described. The development of the research methods through which
models' properties were elucidated and analysed is also reviewed.
Introduction
Comparative analysis of macroeconometric models took a significant
step forward in 1983 with the establishment of the ESRC Macroeconomic
Modelling Bureau. This was an important initiative by the Macroeconomic
Modelling Consortium, itself newly established to coordinate support for
a programme of research in macroeconomic modelling provided by the
Research Council, HM Treasury and the Bank of England, and to manage
this on a four-year cycle. Both developments resulted from the
acceptance in June 1981 by the then Social Science Research Council of
the recommendations of a subcommittee on macroeconomic research chaired
by Michael Posner (SSRC, 1981). In the course of its deliberations the
subcommittee had considered the case for setting up a new centre, to
undertake comparative research on existing models of the UK economy and
to help achieve greater openness and understanding of the models and
their associated forecasts and policy analysis. It was supported in this
by the House of Commons Select Committee on th e Treasury and Civil
Service which, in the course of its enquiry into monetary policy, was
"not satisfied that present arrangements produce the most useful
model-based evidence for the Committee, for Parliament, or for the
public" (Treasury and Civil Service Committee, Session 1980-81,
Ch.1O). The Bureau was funded by the Consortium in each of its four
four-year phases, until the research programme was discontinued in 1999,
and the Bureau closed on 30 September 1999.
Regular comparative studies of overall model properties gave a
first look at dynamic multipliers and policy ready-reckoners, and the
reasons for differences between them across different models. These
studies initially appeared as chapters in annual review volumes (Wallis
et al., 1984-87) and subsequently as articles in this Review, at first
annually and then biennially; the last exercise in this sequence appears
in the fourth section of the present article. These accounts of overall
model properties, based on standard simulation experiments, met the
initial demand for information about the models and the reasons for
differences between them, and also focussed Bureau research on specific
features of the models that might be responsible for these differences.
How these research methods developed is briefly reviewed in the
following section.
Macroeconomic models evolve, in response to developments in
economic theory and econometric methods, new statistical evidence,
changes in legislative and institutional arrangements and changes in the
economic policy questions asked of the models. A look back over the
Bureau's regular comparative studies gives a clear view of this
development process, and three major elements are described in the third
section. The models are now better grounded in economic theory, have
firmer econometric foundations, and are better suited to the analysis of
the current monetary and fiscal policy environment than was the case
sixteen years ago.
The general properties of the current versions of five models of
the UK economy are analysed in the fourth section. One is the model of
HM Treasury, while four received support from the Consortium. Two of
these modelling groups, namely those at the London Business School (LBS)
and the National Institute of Economic and Social Research (NIESR) were,
like the Bureau, supported in all four phases of the Consortium's
research programme, while the 'COMPACT' model group led by
Simon Wren-Lewis of the University of Exeter and the Cambridge
University Small UK Model (CUSUM), directed by Sean Holly, appeared in
the later phases of the programme. Our analysis is based on the versions
of these models deposited at the Bureau in late 1998-early 1999; for HM
Treasury this is the annual release of the public model. The final
section concludes.
Research methods
Empirical economics is commonly criticised for not paying enough
attention to discriminating between competing explanations of the same
phenomena. Macroeconomic modelling is the area where most comparative
work has been done, however, perhaps as a result of the high public
profile of the models and the forecasts and policy analyses based on
them. The model comparison literature extends back to the 1950s, and
covers all dimensions of the models and their uses, from the
specification of single equations to full-system responses, and from
forecasting and counterfactual analysis to policy optimisation. Most of
this literature is in the form of conference proceedings, with papers on
their models or the results of a specified model application contributed
by model proprietors, and commentary and related work contributed by
other researchers. In the United Kingdom, for example, a sequence of
such conferences was initiated by the Economics Committee of the Social
Science Research Council soon after it began work in 1 966, given that
in economic modelling it had decided to support a number of separate
projects rather than put all its eggs into one basket.
Comparison conferences seldom reach clear conclusions, however.
Differences among models are commonly observed, but there are few
serious attempts to explain them. It is often noted that part of the
observed differences may be due to differences in the way that different
modellers carried out the assigned exercise on their own model, but the
extent of this cannot be assessed in this framework. The opportunities
for comparative analysis by third parties are limited by their lack of
access to the models, and there is little testing of competing views and
little attempt to learn from one exercise to the next.
The establishment of the Bureau was an attempt to remedy these
deficiencies. As an independent third party with whom complete models
and associated databases were deposited, the Bureau was able to
undertake direct comparisons across models of the UK economy at all
stages of a comparative exercise -- design, execution, analysis and
testing. This was not without controversy. The US Model Comparison
Seminar, for example, had explicitly decided to leave matters in the
hands of the model proprietors (Fromm and Klein, 1976), although Christ,
in his classic commentary, was then unable to determine "which of
them are wrong...and which (if any) are right" (Christ, 1975,
p.54). Similar views had been expressed by UK modellers. In an important
precursor to the Bureau's comparative studies, also published in
this Review, Laury et al. (1978) looked forward to regular comparative
studies "by those most familiar with the operational complexities
of the various models".
The Bureau's first objective was to standardise comparisons of
overall model properties, and so eliminate differences in the results
that might have resulted from different model proprietors making
different side assumptions or setting up the fiscal and monetary policy
environment for the simulation experiment in different ways. The sources
of important differences that emerge in these standard simulation
exercises are then tracked down in the model structures, often using
diagnostic simulations in which the importance of a particular
transmission mechanism is assessed by means of a variant simulation in
which it is closed off. Such partial simulations -- or "response
dissections", introduced by Helliwell and Higgins (1976) -- are
difficult to specify ex ante and difficult to standardise across models,
hence scarcely feature in the comparison conference set-up. But their
main purpose is not directly comparative: they play an essential part in
detective work, and through their use differences in model properti es
often reduce to rather precise questions about particular model
equations or even a particular coefficient within an equation.
Econometric evaluation can then proceed, in an encompassing spirit
(Hendry, 1988). Although there are several UK models, there is only one
UK economy, to which the different models are simply different
approximations, and their adequacy for particular purposes can be
assessed statistically.
Sometimes comparative testing may lead to a preferred and/or
improved specification. The sensitivity of overall model properties can
then be checked by replacing the various original specifications by the
preferred specification and observing the impact of this change on the
comparative simulation results. Sometimes the available data cannot
discriminate between competing specifications, but at least the model
user is then clear about where the uncertainty lies, and can base a
choice on whatever other grounds may be appropriate to the particular
application. This combination of simulation analysis of overall model
properties and econometric analysis of individual model equations or
groups of equations in the context of cross-model comparisons proved to
be a productive methodological development, with applications covering
several sectors of the models. Although systematic econometric
evaluations of particular equations in the models had begun to appear
before the Bureau came into being (see Brooks, 1981, for example), and
indeed were continued by the Bureau, their relation to the full-system
behaviour of the models had not hitherto been developed.
Model evolution
In this section some important developments in the models are
described under three main headings -- their theoretical structure, the
treatment of expectations, and the modelling of policy variables.
Pervading all three topics and hence also an area of development is the
notion of the long-run or steady-state properties of a model. Important
parallel developments in time-series econometrics of considerable
influence in macroeconomic model-building concern the treatment of
integrated and cointegrated series and the connection with the popular
error correction model. This provides a convenient distinction between
the long-run implications of a dynamic equation and its short-run
adjustment process, and hence facilitates the analysis of the long-run
properties of a model. As with any econometric technique, however, it
may not automatically provide a complete answer, for example when
variables that feature in the economist's long-run relationship do
not appear in the statistician's cointegrating vector, for one re
ason or another.
The theoretical paradigm
Of the six models that appeared in the Bureau's first review
(Wallis et al., 1984), four -- the LBS, NIESR, HMT and Cambridge Growth
Project models -- could be described as 'mainstream', a
classification also used by Britton (1983) in introducing his edited
volume on the NIESR model. We focus on developments in the mainstream,
noting the influence of the other two models -- the City University
Business School (CUBS) and Liverpool models -- in passing.
The mainstream models were developed around the income-expenditure
framework for the determination of effective demand in real terms, thus
the level of output was determined through the components of the
national income identity: consumers' expenditure, fixed investment,
stockbuilding, government current expenditure, and exports minus
imports. With government expenditure predetermined, other components
were largely demand-driven: consumers' expenditure as a function of
real income, with an allowance for changes in credit conditions; fixed
investment as an accelerator relationship; stockbuilding with reference
to a target stock--output ratio; and exports and imports as functions of
aggregate demand, foreign or domestic, and relative prices or costs. The
implicit assumption was that the aggregate supply schedule was fairly
elastic up to the 'full employment' level of unemployment, but
this was not explicitly modelled. The labour market structure was
likewise incomplete, with no modelling of supply and employmen t
equations often based on inverted production functions. Like the
investment functions, these labour demand equations contained no factor
price effects.
This picture soon began to change, in response to internal and
external criticism, and modellers sought to achieve greater theoretical
consistency: in respect of a better articulated macroeconomic framework
incorporating both demand and supply; in respect of internal
consistency, for example in the joint determination of output, prices,
and the demand for factors of production; and paying attention to
stock-flow equilibria. Implicit criticism in some respects came from
within the modelling community, being provided by the contrasting
positions adopted by the CUBS and Liverpool models. The CUBS model
represented an attempt to implement the textbook economics of
demand-and-supply within a small macroeconomic system. It abandoned the
income-expenditure framework and explicitly determined the supply of
output via a production function. This identified four factors of
production -- capital, labour, energy and raw materials -- and factor
demands were based on an assumption of profit maximisation within a
perfectly competitive framework.
The Liverpool model was a practical attempt to use New Classical
ideas in building an empirical structural model. In the theoretical
models of the New Classical school deviations of output from trend are
the result of random disturbances of the price level from its expected
value in the structural form, or a consequence of unanticipated changes
in monetary and other policies in the reduced form. In these models the
aggregate supply schedule is constrained to be vertical in both the
short and the long run, so that anticipated demand shocks do not change
the levels of output and unemployment, but increase the price level (or
inflation). This happens quickly, thanks to the assumption of rational
expectations. The characteristic market clearing assumptions imply very
rapid relative price adjustment, so that only demand and supply
functions are required, with no need for a price adjustment equation.
However the Liverpool model departed from its theoretical counterparts
by allowing for real rigidities in adjustment , notably in the labour
market, where the convergence to market clearing was very slow.
Nevertheless, the eventual equilibrium or 'natural rate'
values of employment, output and real wages were now endogenous. Further
classical features were given by an emphasis on stocks rather than
flows, for example, the use of wealth rather than income in modelling
expenditure decisions.
Both the CUBS and Liverpool models had some influence in leading
other modellers to take the supply-side view seriously, but their
econometric credentials were often questioned and the major influence
was the supply-side model of Layard and Nickell (1986). This treats
goods and labour markets as imperfectly competitive, and was quickly
adopted by mainstream modellers. Prices are set by imperfectly
competitive firms, given the demand they face, and their demand for
labour depends on both the real product wage and the level of real
aggregate demand. Wages are determined in a bargaining process and if
firms have the 'right to manage' they set employment, given
the wage, although wage behaviour is relatively insensitive to the
particular specification of the bargaining model. Key questions about
the long-run properties of a large-scale model, such as whether the
aggregate supply schedule is vertical and what causes it to shift, can
then be addressed by analysing a core supply-side framework consisting
of the stea dy-state versions of the wage and price equations together
with, in an open-economy context, the response of the exchange rate, as
shown by Joyce and Wren-Lewis (1991) for the NIESR model and Turner
(1991) for the Treasury model. With various elaborations of detail this
remained the leading approach through the rest of the decade.
The prevailing paradigm is thus one in which a broadly neoclassical
view of macroeconomic equilibrium coexists with a new Keynesian view of
short-to-medium-term adjustment. In respect of the long-run equilibrium,
the level of real activity is found to be independent of the price level
and the steady-state inflation rate, whereas in the short run there is
considerable real and nominal inertia. Adjustment costs and contractual
arrangements imply that markets do not clear instantaneously and there
is a relatively slow process of dynamic adjustment to equilibrium. This
is by no means a full-employment equilibrium, however, and the questions
of whether a model possesses a non-accelerating- inflation rate of
unemployment (NAIRU) and, if so, what are its determinants, can be
analysed as described in the preceding paragraph. It is often found that
the NAIRU is independent of the steady-state inflation rate and so is
the 'natural' rate of unemployment, as a result of the dynamic
homogeneity or inflation neutrality of the price and wage equations. The
NAIRU may, however, depend on the rate of productivity growth.
Expectations
Expectations or anticipations of future values of endogenous
variables, such as exchange rates and inflation, are often important
determinants of current behaviour, and their influence has been
incorporated into macro-econometric models in various ways. One
possibility is to use direct observations on anticipations and
expectations, obtained by surveys, for example, but reliable
quantitative data on expectations are relatively rare. In any event, in
forecasting and policy analysis exercises these expectations have
themselves to be projected, hence modellers have turned to the use of
auxiliary hypotheses about the formation of expectations.
A traditional way of dealing with unobserved expectations variables
is to assume that they are functions of the current and lagged values of
a few observed variables, the simplest example being the adaptive
expectations hypothesis. The unobserved expectations variables are then
substituted out, giving a conventional backward-looking dynamic or
distributed lag model. This confounds the description of the
expectations-formation process with the description of economic
behaviour given expectations. It results in equations that are unlikely
to remain invariant across policy regimes and hence likely to give wrong
estimates of the macroeconomic consequences of a change in policy regime
-- this is the 'Lucas critique' of econometric policy
evaluation. One response was to question the relevance of the critique
by noting that model-based policy analysis often consisted of estimating
the consequences of changes in the settings of policy instruments,
rather than complete changes of regime. A more direct response was to
keep the description of the formation of expectations separate from the
model of economic behaviour given expectations, although the first way
in which this was done, by assuming that expectations are formed
'rationally', still gives the model an important role.
The rational expectations hypothesis is that expectations coincide
with the conditional expectations of the variable given 'all
available information', which includes knowledge of the underlying
economic system. Its foundation in optimising behaviour led to its
incorporation into equilibrium business cycle models and its advocacy as
part of New Classical macroeconomics, and hence its adoption by the
Liverpool model since its first appearance in 1980. The distinction
between the theoretical stance of the model in which expectations
variables appear and the theory of expectations which is adopted was
nevertheless appreciated, and the rational expectations hypothesis had
been incorporated into more mainstream models by the mid-1980s.
The practical solution of a model for the endogenous variable values over a forecast period now requires an internally consistent
forward-looking solution sequence to be calculated, in which each
period's future expectations variables coincide with the
model's forecasts for the future period. With this implementation
the approach is more accurately and perhaps less controversially termed
'model-consistent' expectations. In parallel to the
requirement for an initial condition when solving a conventional
difference equation, there is also a need for terminal or transversality conditions that specify forecast values and expectations at the forecast
horizon. If the steady-state properties of the model are known, as in
the Liverpool model, then the terminal conditions may explicitly
incorporate this knowledge. This may require a relatively long solution
period, however, to ensure that the model has reached an approximate
equilibrium. In the absence of such knowledge, or in a shorter solution
period, terminal condi tions are typically specified to approximate a
stable convergence to equilibrium by requiring constant growth rates of
relevant variables.
The full information assumption may be inappropriate or
unacceptable in some circumstances, and various hybrid ways of treating
expectations have resulted. Empirical analysis of observed expectations
or forecasts does not always find them to be unbiased and efficient, as
predicted by the rational expectations hypothesis, while 'all
available information' is clearly an extreme characterisation, and
modifications such as 'bounded rationality' or
'economically rational expectations' have appeared. A model
proprietor is typically uncertain about the model, not only due to
sampling error in its coefficient estimates but also due to available
choices of competing specifications. Moreover in some policy discussions
the question of the credibility of policy is a central concern. Thus
various kinds of learning mechanisms have been developed, sometimes with
respect to the model itself and sometimes with respect to its external
environment. In these exercises the rational expectations assumption
often continues to serve as a baseline, not only in the sense that many
of the learning schemes are designed to converge on the full information
scenario, but also as a comparator for the alternative solution
trajectory, allowing the gains from the full credibility of policy to be
evaluated, for example.
Fiscal and monetary policy
Traditional policy analysis with macroeconometric models consists
of 'what-if' exercises. These address the question of what
would be the macroeconomic consequences if policy settings, treated as
exogenous, were altered. In rational expectations models an accompanying
assumption about agents' anticipations of policy actions is needed,
and whether such actions are regarded as temporary or permanent. A
tendency in recent years has been a move away from an exogeneity
assumption towards an endogenisation of policy or 'closing' of
the model, with simple policy rules. To some extent the challenge of VAR
modellers, who from the beginning abandoned the endogenous/exogenous
distinction, provoked this response, but important stimuli were the
changes in practical policy-making in both fiscal and monetary policy,
which we discuss in turn.
The government expenditure simulation has over the years been the
simulation exercise which most modellers run first, to begin to study
the properties of their models. The classic article by Christ (1968)
drew attention to the importance of the government budget constraint and
the implication that the government expenditure multiplier cannot be
defined without an assumption about how the expenditure is to be
financed. The two polar side conditions that subsequently appeared were
unchanged interest rates and unchanged monetary aggregates, the first
representing an assumption of full accommodation of increases in money
demand, with the rest of the deficit financed by issuing bonds, the
second assuming pure bond finance. In the absence of complete stock-flow
accounting, however, the debt stock position was often not monitored,
and it was possible to remain blithely unaware of the debt explosion
that a simulation experiment might be causing. It is unrealistic to
assume that investors remain willing to purchase go vernment bonds
indefinitely in such circumstances, and more realistic to assume some
feedback from the state of the public finances onto fiscal policy. The
actual reality of the debt explosion in many countries in the 1980s also
placed the intertemporal government budget constraint, that the
government remain solvent or policy remain sustainable, onto the policy
modelling agenda.
Different ways of incorporating the constraint appear in several of
the multi-country models featuring in the model comparison projects
sponsored by the Brookings Institution (Bryant et al., 1988, 1993).
These are the models that also adopt a forward-looking treatment of
expectations, where a consistent treatment of the long run is essential.
One approach, adopted in models with a highly aggregate treatment of the
public sector accounts, is to incorporate financing assumptions that
maintain policy sustainability directly into the representation of the
accounts; this had also been done in the Liverpool model of the domestic
economy. An alternative approach, initiated by Paul Masson and
colleagues at the IMF, is to replace an exogeneity assumption for a
fiscal instrument with a closure rule describing its adjustment in
response to financial disequilibria. This has been the preferred
approach in models of the UK economy, motivated by the same combination
of modelling developments and policy objectives, and fisca l closure
rules first appeared in Bureau comparative studies in 1995.
The intertemporal government budget constraint is typically
represented as a stability condition for the debt/GDP ratio and/or
deficit/GDP ratio. The ratio form reflects both the definition of a
steady state in terms of constant growth rates for aggregate real and
nominal variables of the model (with constant inflation), and the
practical expression of the Masstricht Treaty's fiscal
requirements. The period-by-period government budget constraint is
silent on the question of which of the government's income and
expenditure variables should be adjusted in the face of a disequilibrium - it is an identity, not a behavioural equation. In practice,
model-based analyses take tax revenues or the average tax rate to be the
relevant policy instrument. Equally, the solvency requirement does not
specify the time path of any necessary adjustment, but simply that an
adjustment must occur, sooner or later. Again, in practice, adjustment
is assumed to take place continuously, by specifying a policy rule or
reaction function that describes how the instrument is altered
period-by-period in response to deviations of the target variable from
its desired value. Nevertheless different formulations appear in
different models - tax levels or first differences, debt or deficit
targets - resulting in the suspicion that these differences contribute
to observed differences in simulation results. Recent Bureau research
(Mitchell et al., 2000) has established equivalences between these
rules, in respect of both their long-run equilibria and their
disequilibrium dynamics, which will assist both the design of the rules
and the interpretation of results.
Monetary policy modelling has followed the changing fashions in
monetary policy-making, in turn targeting the money supply, the exchange
rate and finally, and directly, inflation, through the setting of
official interest rates. The explicit focus on the control of inflation
in several OECD countries was accompanied over the last decade by an
explosion of research on the design and evaluation of monetary policy
rules. While much of this research used theoretical models or simple
stylised empirical models as the research vehicle, the rules have also
been incorporated into large-scale models to improve their
representation of practical policy-making, and they also appeared in
Bureau comparative studies for the first time in 1995.
The rules considered, like the fiscal policy rules above, include
both change and level formulations. The former sets the change in the
short-term nominal interest rate as a function of deviations of
inflation from target and, possibly, output from potential output. The
latter sets the level of the interest rate as a function of similar
arguments; this includes the form known as the 'Taylor' rule,
found to provide a reasonable approximation to actual US policy-making.
A further development associated with the name of Svensson (1997) is the
inclusion of terms in the deviation of forecast future inflation from
target, such forward-looking rules probably being closer to central bank
practice. A first question concerns the circumstances in which the
target is achieved, for example, whether an exogenous change in the
target value produces the same change in actual inflation, with a
long-run change in the nominal interest rate also of the same amount,
leaving the real rate of interest unaltered, as in a standard Do rnbusch
model. After that there is an important shift in the main focus of
attention between the respective fiscal and monetary policy studies,
from first moments to second moments, statistically speaking. Neither
the small stylised models used in this research nor typical large-scale
models, as discussed above, admit a long-run trade-off between the
levels of output and inflation, and policies are evaluated in terms of
the variances of outcomes.
Long run and steady state
The notion of the long-run or steady-state properties of a model
provides motivation for and connections between the three topics
discussed in this section, as noted at the outset. The supply side of a
model determines its long-run properties, hence developments in one
imply developments in the other. Consistency with economic theory is
often sought in relation to a comparative static economy theory, in
terms of the long-run or equilibrium properties of a dynamic model,
neglecting its short-run adjustment properties. Attention to stock and
flow equilibria and a complete specification of the public sector
accounts raises the issue of the long-run sustainability of policy and
the use of fiscal closure rules.
In the present context of models used in short-to-medium-term
forecasting and policy analysis, 'long-run implications' means
the steady-state properties of a system of dynamic equations and so
represents only a subset of what economists more generally might wish to
consider as long-run issues. The nature of the long-run equilibrium is a
steady-state growth path, with the real growth rate equated to the
'natural' rate of growth of the standard neoclassical growth
model, given as the rate of (labour-augmenting) technical progress plus
the growth rate of the population. The models follow the neoclassical
growth model in treating both of these as exogenous, and do not address
a range of issues arising in a second generation of growth models, known
as endogenous growth models, such as the role of education, knowledge
and human capital. Nominal equilibrium is 'anchored' by
specifying a target, again exogenously, for a nominal variable such as
inflation, and a feedback rule for nominal interest rates seeks to
achiev e the target value.
In a model with consistent forward-looking expectations, the
long-run effects of exogenous shocks may influence short-run behaviour,
hence it is again important that these be properly modelled, even in a
context of short-to-medium-term analysis. The use of backward-looking
treatments of expectations may have contributed to the previous neglect
of asset stock equilibria, a debt explosion in the remote future having
no effect on projections two-to-five years ahead in this case.
Standard simulations
Four simulation experiments on the five models are analysed and
interpreted in this section. The first is a monetary policy simulation,
namely a change in the inflation target. Two fiscal policy experiments
follow, an increase in government expenditure and a reduction in the
basic rate of income tax. The final experiment, an increase in the level
of technical progress, is a supply-side shock. This is a newcomer to the
set of 'standard' simulations although it was used for
comparisons across three of these models in the course of a substantive
investigation of the role of technical progress in a previous article
(Church et al., 1998).
The macroeconomic responses to these shocks are estimated by
comparing the results of two solutions of a model, one a base run and
the other a perturbed run in which the indicated variable, treated as
exogenous, is perturbed from its base-run values. The responses may
include changes in inflation and the state of the public finances, and
the policy environment is one in which the interest rate and the basic
rate of income tax are used to target the inflation rate and to ensure
fiscal solvency. As noted above, this representation of the current
policy regime first appeared in our studies of model properties in 1995,
and a fuller discussion can be found in the two preceding comparative
properties articles (Church et al., 1995, 1997). To focus on model
properties we suspend the fiscal closure rule for the period of the
fiscal policy shocks -- five years in each case -- and reintroduce it
once the perturbation is removed, to ensure long-run sustainability. The
monetary policy and technical progress shocks are per manent, not
temporary.
General results on the main macroeconomic indicators for our four
experiments are presented in Tables A1-A4. For three of the models (LBS,
NIESR, CUSUM) the base run corresponds to a published forecast, although
it is typically extended well beyond the published forecast horizon. The
base run supplied by the COMPACT model proprietors is constructed for
simulation purposes and does not represent a published forecast. Results
for the inflation targeting, government expenditure and income tax
simulations on the HMT model relative to its own base, which is not
published, are kindly provided by the Treasury. While numerical results
are shown over the first ten years of the simulation, in all models
except HMT the base is longer than this, and our discussion sometimes
refers to the 'long-run' outcome that obtains at the end of
the simulation period.
Reduction in the inflation target
In this simulation the inflation target is set at half a percentage
point below the base-line values of inflation throughout the simulation
period. In the NIESR model, this led to non-convergence of the model
solution software. In this case we conduct a half a percentage point
increase in the target and reverse the sign of all the responses so that
comparisons can be made with the other models.
Taking the HMT, NIESR and COMPACT models first, the results in
Table A1 show that the inflation rate is initially reduced in all three
cases, and then settles down around the new target in the NIESR and
COMPACT models. The HMT model has clearly not reached equilibrium by the
end of the simulation, and this difference mainly reflects the
expectations regimes under which the models operate. The new inflation
target is reached quickly in the NIESR model, with inflation 0.5
percentage points below baseline during the third year of the
simulation. Adjustment is protracted in the COMPACT model, with
inflation only reaching the new target towards the end of the
seventy-year simulation horizon.
In each model the short-term interest rate is the policy instrument
that delivers the desired inflation target. This falls below baseline
values in the first year in the NIESR and COMPACT models, remaining
there for the entire simulation horizon. The long-run position for the
nominal rate, 0.5 percentage points below baseline, is achieved most
quickly in the NIESR model, corresponding to the speed with which the
long-run inflation position is reached in this model. The real interest
rate in the long run is unchanged in both COMPACT and NIESR models,
supporting the theoretical proposition that changing the steady-state
inflation rate leaves real variables unchanged in the long run. By
contrast, the short-term interest rate in the HMT model is above
baseline for two-thirds of the simulation period.
This need for different interest rate paths in order to generate
the same outcome for inflation can be explained by the different roles
of the exchange rate. Generating a permanent drop in the inflation rate
requires continuous appreciation of the nominal exchange rate. This then
feeds, via import prices, to domestic prices. In each model, the
differential between domestic and foreign interest rates is an important
determinant of the exchange rate response, via some form of uncovered
interest parity or open arbitrage condition. Generally, an increase in
domestic rates with foreign rates unchanged gives the appreciation that
drives prices down. The other important influence on the current level
of the exchange rate is the expected exchange rate one period ahead. In
both models where real interest rates are unchanged in the long run, the
expected future exchange rate is treated in an explicit forward-looking
manner, with the future expectation set equal to the actual solution
value for that period. The exchange rate jumps at the start of the
simulation in response to anticipated future events, in this case the
lower future rate of inflation. Here, it is the expectations term that
is driving the exchange rate appreciation. Interest rates, which play no
role in the rise in the exchange rate, are then free to fall to their
new long-run level, in a manner determined by the monetary policy rule,
although there is overshooting in the short-to-medium term because of
some sluggish behaviour in wages and prices.
The direction of the initial jump in the nominal exchange rate
differs between the NIESR and COMPACT models, because the key exchange
rate relationship in the COMPACT model is expressed in real terms,
whereas the variable that jumps in the NIESR model is the nominal
exchange rate. In COMPACT the real exchange rate immediately depreciates
by 2 per cent in the first year. The long-run outcome is tied down by
the equilibrium of the model and in this case the real exchange rate
must be back at base by the final period. The nominal exchange rate
moves in line with the real rate. In order to achieve the required
appreciation, the real exchange rate must therefore increase over time,
and the only way it can do this and return to base at the end of the
simulation is to jump down in the first period before gradually climbing
back. This real exchange rate trajectory drags the nominal rate some 1.7
per cent below base in the first quarter, with the subsequent
appreciation taking the rate above baseline values during the fourth
year.
In the exchange rate equation in the HMT model expectations are
backward looking, and the model relies on the interest rate to deliver
the required appreciation in the nominal exchange rate. Interest rates
immediately rise when the cut in the target is introduced, reaching 0.55
percentage points above base by the second year. This ensures that the
inflation rate hits its new target during the sixth year of the
simulation, but the subsequent overshooting of the target brings
interest rates down sharply, dipping below baseline values in years 7-9.
In the tenth and final year of the simulation, inflation is slightly
below target and interest rates 0.14 percentage points above and rising.
Inflation in the CUSUM and LBS models fails to settle down at the
new target. One feature of all the LBS results presented here is the
presence of large cycles in both nominal and real variables. Given that
the only major change to the model since our last comparative exercise
is the inclusion of a newly estimated supply-side block, it is likely
that this is at least partly responsible. Examination of the dynamic
characteristics of the equation for total costs reveals that it
generates an eight-year cycle in response to a shock. But this does not
explain the large amplitude of these cycles, and so other elements
within the new supply side, possibly interacting with the interest rate
reaction function, must also be important. In common with the HMT model,
expectations within the exchange rate equation are backward looking and
it is the interest rate that delivers the required exchange rate
appreciation. The inflation rate never settles at its desired long-run
position, instead it cycles around it for the full 27 years of the
simulation. The cycle does dampen over time, and it may be the case that
at some point in the future the steady-state outcome is achieved.
In CUSUM, inflation falls almost one percentage point by the second
year, following the large appreciation of the exchange rate in the first
year. However, despite modelling the nominal exchange rate in a similar
way to the NIESR and COMPACT models, the interest rate response is very
different, remaining above baseline throughout the whole simulation
horizon. The new inflation target is not achieved, and it is this
differential between actual and target rates that ensures that the
interest rate stays above base. As in our previous comparative exercise,
the wage and price equations in the CUSUM model lack dynamic
homogeneity, such that exchange rate movements are not passed on fully
to prices.
In the three models that deliver an increase in interest rates,
there is a loss of output in the short term, whereas in the NIESR and
COMPACT models lower interest rates help stimulate higher output.
However, even though their short-to-medium-term GDP responses are
similar, closer examination of consumption, investment and the trade
balance reveals different compositional effects. In Table Al, these
components are expressed in terms of their actual deviation as a
proportion of baseline GDP, so that when summed these effects should be
approximately equal to the GDP response as shown. Consumption is
permanently higher in the NIESR model, some 0.6 per cent of baseline GDP
higher after 31 years. In the COMPACT model, consumers'
expenditure, which is forward looking, immediately jumps down around
half a per cent of baseline GDP in the first year, before rising slowly
thereafter, settling around 0.2 per cent higher after the full 71 years
of the simulation. The investment response also differs, increasing by
0.1 per cent of baseline GDP in the NIESR model and remaining above
baseline, at 0.2 per cent of baseline GDP in the final year, whereas in
the COMPACT model investment hardly moves in the short-to-medium term,
but is slightly below base during the second half of the simulation
period. In the COMPACT model these responses are dictated by the real
post-tax interest rate, which increases as inflation and nominal
interest rates are both lower, in turn reducing both consumption and
investment; in this model it is net trade that lies behind the increase
in output. The fall in the real exchange rate described above improves
the trade balance in the short run, more than countering the consumption
and investment responses. Meanwhile, the real exchange rate appreciation
in the early years of the NIESR simulation worsens its trade balance.
Increase in government expenditure
The second simulation experiment is a five-year increase in
government spending of [pounds]2 billion (1995 prices) per annum, which
is approximately equal to a quarter of one per cent of baseline GDP. The
fiscal closure rules in the models are suppressed for the duration of
the expenditure increase, so that a 'live now, pay later'
approach is adopted. The rules are activated at the start of the sixth
year.
One consequence of adopting the prevailing theoretical paradigm
described above is the inability of the government to alter the
equilibrium level of output, this instead being determined by the growth
rates of technical progress and the working population. The absence of
non-neutralities in wages and prices explains why policy-makers cannot
shift the equilibrium level of activity by changing the inflation rate,
but in the short-to-medium term, the dynamics of wage and price
reactions are sluggish, giving the opportunity of a role for a
counter-cyclical government spending policy.
The results in Table A2 show that the impact government expenditure
multiplier is around unity in the NIESR model, with GDP 0.25 per cent
higher in the first year. This compares with a multiplier of around half
this size in the COMPACT model, where the initial response of GDP is an
increase of 0.13 per cent. Crowding out in both models reduces the
benefits of this early expansion over the next four years, although the
speed at which this happens differs. During the sixth year, GDP falls
below base in both models, but the reduction in the COMPACT model is far
less dramatic. This sudden unwinding of the GDP rise is a combination of
two factors. First, government spending returns to baseline values.
Second, the fiscal closure rules are introduced, tax rates increase, and
a fiscal contraction ensues. GDP does eventually recover and is
virtually back at baseline values after ten years in both models.
The difference in the impact GDP multiplier is explained by the
differing response of consumers' expenditure. Consumption rises by
a maximum 0.1 per cent of baseline GDP by the second year in the NIESR
model whereas the COMPACT results show a peak fall of over 0.2 per cent
at the same time, almost completely countering the increase in
government spending. However, the recovery in GDP during years 4 and 5
is a result of consumers' expenditure returning back towards
baseline values. This response can be traced to both increasing interest
rates and the modelling of consumer behaviour in the COMPACT model. The
majority of consumers in COMPACT are forward looking. They foresee the
higher taxes of the future and save at first, smoothing their
consumption: they do not always increase consumption in line with
increases in disposable income. Consumers in the NIESR model are less
forward looking and spend more of the gains, despite a similar rise in
interest rates.
This increase in nominal interest rates in both models is required
to control the inflation that results from the increased demand in the
economy. With real interest rates rising, there is initially an
appreciation in the real exchange rate, which worsens the trade balance,
with this effect strongest in the NIESR model. This exerts downward
pressure on GDP. As output is reduced inflation declines, and nominal
and real rates return to baseline.
There are short-term increases in output in the LBS, HMT and CUSUM
models, which in all cases diminish over time. The cycles present in the
inflation targeting simulation in the LBS model also appear here,
although once again it is possible that these are damped around a
sensible equilibrium. In the HMT model the government expenditure
multiplier is around a half. The increase in GDP that does occur is
entirely attributable to the impact of the higher government
expenditure, as the other main components of GDP drag the response down.
Although investment is slightly higher in the first year in reaction to
higher output, it starts to fall below base in the second year in
response to higher interest rates. This increase in rates, which is
required to keep inflation down, also hits consumers' expenditure
and the trade balance, the latter effect coming through the appreciation
in the real exchange rate. The nature of the long-run position in the
HMT model is unclear. The inflation rate is below base in the tenth y
ear, along with interest rates. Consequently output, consumers'
expenditure and investment are all rising in the final year. In the
CUSUM model, both nominal and real interest rates are permanently above
base, mirrored by investment and consumption responses that are
permanently lower. GDP has almost returned to baseline values in this
model by the sixteenth and final year of the simulation, as net trade
almost exactly offsets the negative influences of the other major GDP
components.
During the first five years of the simulation, tax rates are fixed.
The public finances worsen in each model during this period, with the
greatest deterioration in the COMPACT model. The tax rate then increases
by some 0.6 percentage points during year 6 in this model, and the rise
in the debt ratio is immediately reversed, but still takes 30 years to
get close to baseline values. The NIESR results give some indication of
how the choice of a less activist rule can influence simulation results.
The debt ratio continues to climb after the rule starts operating,
reaching 1.5 percentage points above base in the tenth year, remaining
0.5 percentage points above base in year 31. The income tax rate barely
changes throughout the simulation period; the maximum increase is only
slightly over 0.1 percentage points. The fiscal solvency rule in the HMT
model targets the PSNCR to GDP ratio to baseline values in each period.
Initially, the basic rate of income tax increases sharply, reinforcing
the fall in consumers' expen diture described above. Here, unlike
in the NIESR model, the operation of the tax rule ensures that the
deficit is maintained at baseline levels in every single period. In the
CUSUM model, there is a substantial increase in the tax rate, some 2.0
percentage points in the long run. But the debt ratio is still 0.6
percentage points above baseline at the end of the simulation with no
sign of diminishing.
Reduction in the basic rate of income tax
The results of a two-point reduction in the basic rate of income
tax, sustained for five years, are shown in Table A3. As with the
government spending simulation, the fiscal closure rules are suppressed
for the duration of the shock and then allowed to operate from the
beginning of the sixth year. Two main channels can be identified through
which the tax cut may affect the economy. The first is uncontroversial:
higher real personal disposable income will in turn increase
consumers' expenditure. The second is by changing the behaviour of
workers through its impact on wage bargaining, and here there is
disagreement across models.
This simulation illustrates clearly the extent of consumption
smoothing and the near Ricardian behaviour in the COMPACT model.
Consumption rises very little in the short term with a peak of 0.17 per
cent of baseline GDP above base in year 5, much less than the increase
in real disposable income. It is the fact that some consumers are
liquidity-constrained and do increase spending after the tax cut that
ensures that Ricardian equivalence is not complete. By contrast,
consumption in the NIESR model rises much more, reaching 1.4 per cent of
baseline GDP above base in the fourth year.
After five years of lower tax rates the basic rate reverts to the
control of the public finances and the reversal of any deterioration
that has occurred as a result of the tax cut. The tax rate in the
COMPACT model has to rise sharply, as in the previous experiment, here
increasing by 1.6 percentage points by year 6, before returning smoothly
back towards baseline. This need for a large increase reflects the
failure of the tax cut to boost employment and increase government
receipts. Consumers also anticipate future higher tax rates during the
first five years, saving more in the short term to compensate for the
future loss of disposable income. In the NIESR model, taxes are higher
once the solvency rule is implemented, although again the magnitude of
change is much smaller, as is the impact on the debt to GDP ratio.
Higher taxes help to drive consumption 0.8 per cent of baseline GDP
below base during the medium term.
The second channel through which the lower tax rate may have an
impact is through changes in wage bargaining. A lower tax rate reduces
the wedge between employers' real wage costs and employees'
real consumption wages, which may have an impact on the bargained wage
outcome and hence on the NAIRU. The HMT model is the only one of these
five to feature a tax wedge term in the long-run specification of the
wage equation; this does not appear in the other models, which conform
to the view that, in the long run, changes in the wedge are borne
entirely by labour. Short-run wedge effects may nevertheless be
important and rather persistent, and in the NIESR model the change in
the wedge appears in the error correction form of the wage equation.
Here the tax cut puts downwards pressure on real wages, causing the
numbers unemployed to fall by 29,000 by year 3, reinforcing the
demand-side impact of the tax cut described above.
In the HMT model the long-run wedge effect puts greater downward
pressure on the real wage, and unemployment is reduced by 132,000 by
year 6. However, at this point the temporary shock has ended and tax
increases are implemented to ensure that the PSNCR/GDP ratio is returned
to baseline values. The increase in the tax rate that follows has the
opposite impact on the labour market from the initial tax cut. The
reductions in unemployment are reversed, and with the tax rate 1.2
percentage points above base in year 10, the number of unemployed rises
to some 98,000 above baseline values. The presence of these effects in
the wage equation also has a short-lived effect on price inflation in
both models.
Increase in the level of technical progress
The final simulation is a permanent 1 per cent increase in the
level of technical progress. This shock is a supply-side shock and draws
attention to the determinants of equilibrium output in the models.
Technical progress increases the potential supply of output, and with
sufficiently flexible factor and product markets this potential is
realised, resulting in increased consumption, investment and real wages.
It is important to note that this is a domestic shock, with technical
progress in the rest of the world unchanged, hence exports might also be
expected to contribute to the realisation of the potential increase in
GDP. In the neoclassical growth model technical progress is assumed to
be Harrod-neutral or labour-augmenting, the model's steady state
then conforming to the stylised fact of a constant investment/output
ratio, and the same assumption is adopted in the empirical models.
The results in Table A4 show that the NIESR and COMPACT models
deliver increased output in the first ten years, and in both models GDP
does eventually rise by 1 per cent, as predicted by theory. But this
takes 20 years for the NIESR model and 24 years for the COMPACT model.
Neither the LBS or CUSUM models deliver the expected results.
Unemployment rises dramatically in the LBS model and shows little sign
of a return to base, remaining 170,000 higher after 24 years. Although
there is some technological unemployment created in the NIESR and
COMPACT models, it is only in the short-to-medium term. The NIESR
results show employment falling by 0.3 per cent by year 4 and then
increasing slowly in line with output, finally moving above base in year
26. In the COMPACT model the maximum difference in employment from base,
-0.4 per cent, does not occur until the tenth year, but employment
returns to its baseline values by the start of year 22. Given the
responses of output and employment described above, it follows that the
1 per cent increase in technical progress is fully reflected in the
level of productivity, although adjustment in both models is protracted.
In the COMPACT model this is due to the vintage or
'putty-clay' model of production in which, once a new vintage
of capital equipment is installed, there are no factor substitution possibilities. Thus the improvement in technical progress is only
gradually embodied into the capital stock through the acquisition of new
mach ines. In the NIESR model, which assumes that factor proportions are
continuously variable, the costs of adjustment of the capital stock that
appear in the investment functions prevent quick adjustment.
In both NIESR and COMPACT models, investment, consumption and the
trade balance are above baseline in equilibrium. The extra output
produced has to be consumed somewhere and in both cases much of it flows
abroad. In order to sell these goods overseas, the relative price faced
by foreign buyers has to fall, which is achieved by a depreciation of
the exchange rate. In the neoclassical growth model investment would be
expected to rise by 1 per cent along with output. This occurs in neither
model, however, as total investment includes components which are
unaffected by the increase in technical progress. In the COMPACT model,
investment in oil does not change, while investment in petroleum,
natural gas and public sector dwellings is unaffected by technical
progress in the NIESR model.
This model-based analysis of technical progress and its potential
relation to analysis of the 'New Paradigm' is bedevilled by
the same measurement problems that affect analysis of these issues at
any level. The measurement of real investment in the face of falling
prices of computer hardware and software and the measurement of real
output in parts of the public sector and the services sector where
output measurement is traditionally based on measures of labour input
are the leading problem areas. To improve the analysis of the
macroeconomic consequences of technical progress better data are
required, more than better economic theory or econometrics.
Conclusion
Macroeconometric models provide an internally consistent
quantitative account of the main macroeconomic responses to external
shocks and policy innovations. This internal consistency has a number of
dimensions, with respect to the national accounting system, for example,
increasingly viewed from an intertemporal perspective, and with respect
to prevailing macroeconomic theory. This article reviews the properties
of the current versions of five models of the UK economy, in the light
of their behaviour in simulation experiments and of their general
development over the lifetime of the ESRC Macroeconomic Modelling
Bureau, a unique model comparison project. Some models have been
everpresent in the Bureau's portfolio, and there have also been new
entries and exits. There have been remarkable developments in
macroeconometric models over this period, both in their theoretical
structures and in the econometric methods used to quantify those
structures. This is clearly evident in what can be identified as the
mainstre am throughout this period, and also with the appearance of new
models such as the COMPACT model, which is explicitly designed to embody recent macroeconomic theory.
Similar developments have occurred in models of the UK economy
outside the Bureau's portfolio, indeed in models of other national
economies and in multicountry models constructed and maintained both in
the UK and overseas. Research supported by the Macroeconomic Modelling
Consortium has clearly influenced modelling principles and practice on a
wider canvas. The Bank of England (1999), for example, explicitly places
its macroeconometric model in this new mainstream, and recent versions
of the models of the Federal Reserve Board, IMF, and OECD reflect the
same developments. A fully specified macroeconometric model is essential
for the quantitative assessment of policy options -- there is no
alternative, as the Bureau continuously maintained -- and policy
analysts have benefited from the considerable developments of the past
sixteen years.
(*.) This article concludes the series of surveys published in the
National Institute Economic Review by the ESRC Macroeconomic Modelling
Bureau at the University of Warwick. Editorial responsibility is taken
by the authors, not by the Editorial Board of the Review. Comments
should be addressed to the last-named author at Department of Economics,
University of Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL (K.F.Wallis@warwick.ac.uk).
References
Bank of England (1999), Economic Models at the Bank of England,
London, Bank of England.
Britton, A.J.C. (Ed.) (1983), Employment, Output and Inflation: The
National Institute Model of the British Economy, London, Heinemann.
Brooks, S. (1981), 'Systematic econometric comparisons:
exports of manufactured goods', National Institute Economic Review,
97, pp. 67-80.
Bryant, R.C., Henderson, D.W., Holtham, G., Hooper, P. and
Symansky, S. (Eds) (1988), Empirical Economics for Interdependent
Economies, Washington DC, Brookings Institution.
Bryant, R.C., Hooper, P. and Mann, C.L. (Eds) (1993), Evaluating
Policy Regimes: New Research in Empirical Macroeconomics, Washington DC,
Brookings Institution.
Christ, C.F. (1968), 'A simple macroeconomic model with a
government budget restraint', Journal of Political Economy, 76, pp.
53-67.
(1975), 'Judging the performance of econometric models of the
US economy', International Economic Review, 16, pp. 54-74.
Church, K.B., Mitchell, P.R., Smith, P.N. and Wallis, K.F. (1995),
'Comparative properties of models of the UK economy', National
Institute Economic Review, 153, pp. 59-72.
Church, K.B., Mitchell, P.R., Sault, J.E. and Wallis, K.F. (1997),
'Comparative properties of models of the UK economy', National
Institute Economic Review, 161, pp. 91-100.
(1998), 'Technical progress and the natural rate in models of
the UK economy', National Institute Economic Review, 164, pp.
80-89.
Fromm, G. and Klein, L.R. (1976), 'The NBER/NSF model
comparison seminar: an analysis of results', Annals of Economic and
Social Measurement, 5, pp. 1-28.
Helliwell, J.F. and Higgins, C.I. (1976), 'Macroeconomic
adjustment processes', European Economic Review, 7, pp. 221-38.
Hendry, D.F. (1988), 'Encompassing', National Institute
Economic Review, 125, pp. 88-92.
Joyce, M. and Wren-Lewis, S. (1991), 'The role of the real
exchange rate and capacity utilisation in convergence to the
NAIRU', Economic Journal, 101, pp. 497-507.
Laury, J.S.E., Lewis, G.R. and Ormerod, P.A. (1978),
'Properties of macroeconomic models of the UK economy: a
comparative study', National Institute Economic Review, 83, pp.
52-72.
Layard, P.R.G. and Nickell, S.J. (1986), 'Unemployment in
Britain', Economica, 53 (supplement), pp. 121-69.
Mitchell, P.R., Sault, J.E. and Wallis, K.F. (2000), 'Fiscal
policy rules in macroeconomic models: principles and practice',
Economic Modelling, 17 (forthcoming).
Social Science Research Council (1981), Macro-Economic Research in
the United Kingdom, London, SSRC.
Svensson, L.E.O (1997), 'Inflation forecast targeting:
implementing and monitoring inflation targets', European Economic
Review, 41, pp. 1111-46.
Treasury and Civil Service Committee (Session 1980-81), Third
Report, House of Commons Paper no. HC 163-1, London, HMSO.
Turner, D.S. (1991), 'The determinants of the NAIRU response
in simulations on the Treasury model', Oxford Bulletin of Economics
and Statistics, 53, pp. 225-42.
Wallis, K.F. (Ed.), Andrews, M.J., Bell, D.N.F., Fisher, P.G. and
Whitley, J.D. (1984), Models of the UK Economy: A Review by the ESRC
Macroeconomic Modelling Bureau, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
(1985), Models of the UK Economy: A Second Review by the ESRC
Macroeconomic Modelling Bureau, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Wallis, K.F. (Ed.), Andrews, M.J., Fisher, P.G., Longbottom, J.A.
and Whitley, J.D. (1986), Models of the UK Economy: A Third Review by
the ESRC Macroeconomic Modelling Bureau, Oxford, Oxford University
Press.
Wallis, K.F. (Ed.), Fisher, P.G., Longbottom, J.A., Turner, D.S.
and Whitley, J.D. (1987), Models of the UK Economy: A Fourth Review by
the ESRC Macroeconomic Modelling Bureau, Oxford, Oxford University
Press.
Inflation target simulation: reduction of
0.5 percentage points
Year LBS NIESR HMT COMPACT CUSUM
GDP [a] 1 -0.32 0.10 -0.10 -0.23 -0.01
3 -0.81 0.10 -0.40 0.10 -0.49
5 -0.73 0.11 -0.62 0.15 -0.57
7 -0.50 0.13 -0.56 0.19 -0.50
10 -0.90 0.19 0.21 0.24 -0.46
Consumers' expenditure [b] 1 -0.10 0.12 -0.19 -0.56 0.05
3 -0.46 0.29 -0.48 -0.29 -0.13
5 -0.13 0.35 -0.62 -0.21 -0.45
7 0.03 0.38 -0.46 -0.14 -0.46
10 -0.55 0.48 0.12 -0.03 -0.41
Investment [b] 1 -0.15 0.12 -0.24 0.00 0.00
3 -0.25 0.15 -0.96 -0.01 -0.06
5 -0.10 0.17 -1.35 -0.01 -0.16
7 0.03 0.19 -1.15 -0.01 -0.18
10 -0.21 0.22 -0.06 0.00 -0.17
Real trade balance [b] [c] 1 0.01 -0.15 -0.02 0.28 0.31
3 -0.09 -0.34 0.00 0.34 0.25
5 -0.54 -0.41 -0.01 0.34 0.30
7 -0.59 -0.44 -0.06 0.31 0.50
10 -0.12 -0.51 -0.25 0.27 0.83
Unemployment [d] 1 7 -1 3 0 2
3 62 -1 27 -10 53
5 109 0 64 -23 109
7 115 1 80 -38 94
10 109 1 -11 -58 68
Nominal interest rate [a] 1 1.28 -0.30 0.45 -0.37 0.16
3 0.12 -0.48 0.53 -0.59 0.90
5 -1.26 -0.50 0.26 -0.65 0.55
7 -1.15 -0.53 -0.08 -0.69 0.43
10 0.70 -0.57 0.14 -0.79 0.47
Inflation rate [e] 1 -0.08 -0.41 -0.01 -0.39 -0.18
3 -0.67 -0.51 -0.24 -0.57 -0.58
5 -1.05 -0.51 -0.47 -0.62 -0.07
7 -0.57 -0.51 -0.68 -0.64 -0.12
10 0.00 -0.51 -0.43 -0.71 -0.15
Price level [a] 1 -0.09 -0.40 -0.01 -0.37 -0.17
3 -1.12 -1.45 -0.37 -1.46 -1.53
5 -3.06 -2.47 -1.19 -2.61 -1.79
7 -4.38 -3.51 -2.46 -3.81 -1.97
10 -4.55 -5.09 -4.12 -5.74 -2.39
Nominal exchange rate [a] 1 0.81 1.39 0.26 -1.58 3.90
3 3.03 2.26 1.39 -0.54 4.34
5 4.77 3.18 2.27 0.65 3.06
7 4.98 4.14 2.56 1.96 3.12
10 5.43 5.64 1.74 4.15 3.87
Basic rate of income tax [e] 1 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.24 0.00
3 0.10 -0.07 0.50 0.25 -0.01
5 0.19 -0.15 0.63 0.15 -0.12
7 0.17 -0.23 0.25 0.07 0.04
10 0.20 -0.36 -1.10 -0.05 0.34
Deb/IGDP ratio [e] [f] 1 0.18 0.08 -3 0.61 0.00
3 1.17 0.27 -38 0.61 -0.17
5 1.71 0.33 105 0.38 0.20
7 1.31 0.35 155 0.18 0.28
10 1.84 0.28 -99 -0.11 0.19
Government expenditure simulation: increase of [pounds]2bn
(1995 prices) per annum for 5 years
Year LBS NIESR HMT COMPACT CUSUM
GDP [a] 1 0.24 0.25 0.12 0.13 0.28
3 0.23 0.12 0.01 0.03 -0.18
5 0.20 0.05 -0.21 0.12 -0.13
7 0.03 -0.25 -0.45 -0.06 0.00
10 0.15 -0.07 0.12 -0.04 0.07
Consumers' expenditure [b] 1 0.03 0.06 -0.03 -0.17 0.05
3 0.10 0.09 -0.15 -0.20 -0.07
5 0.20 0.02 -0.17 -0.05 -0.23
7 0.32 -0.15 -0.34 -0.04 -0.14
10 0.29 -0.08 0.12 -0.03 -0.03
Investment [b] 1 0.02 -0.02 0.04 -0.01 0.00
3 0.03 -0.05 -0.26 -0.04 -0.08
5 0.02 -0.06 -0.64 -0.04 -0.14
7 0.01 -0.07 -0.68 -0.02 -0.13
10 0.08 -0.02 0.85 -0.01 -0.09
Real trade balance [b][c] 1 -0.07 -0.05 -0.17 -0.04 0.12
3 -0.16 -0.16 -0.19 -0.05 0.00
5 -0.26 -0.14 -0.27 -0.07 -0.05
7 -0.31 -0.02 -0.04 -0.02 0.03
10 -0.22 0.04 -0.15 -0.01 0.12
Unemployment [d] 1 -9 -6 -13 -2 -30
3 -31 -12 -28 -7 28
5 -44 -12 -12 -12 63
7 -28 1 41 -6 45
10 -11 5 53 1 22
Nominal interest rate [e] 1 0.05 -0.02 0.24 0.25 0.14
3 0.29 0.16 0.58 0.36 0.74
5 0.23 0.20 0.56 0.21 0.34
7 -0.26 0.09 -0.03 0.02 0.21
10 -0.46 -0.01 -1.03 0.02 0.24
Inflation rate [e] 1 0.01 -0.01 0.04 0.23 -0.14
3 0.08 0.07 0.08 0.27 -0.42
5 0.00 0.02 0.03 0.11 0.04
7 -0.17 -0.05 -0.05 -0.02 -0.03
10 -0.03 -0.02 -0.15 0.00 -0.06
Price level [a] 1 0.01 -0.01 0.04 0.22 -0.14
3 0.16 0.11 0.19 0.77 -1.16
5 0.21 0.18 0.29 1.09 -1.20
7 -0.05 0.11 0.22 1.05 -1.20
10 -0.39 0.00 -0.26 1.09 -1.35
Nominal exchange rate [a] 1 0.01 0.70 -0.01 0.41 3.11
3 0.13 0.58 0.53 -0.27 2.94
5 0.46 0.20 1.21 -0.88 1.55
7 0.73 -0.10 1.08 -1.03 1.56
10 0.15 -0.19 -1.54 -1.13 2.02
Basic rate of income tax [e] 1 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
3 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
5 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00
7 0.00 0.02 0.53 0.50 0.33
10 -0.05 0.08 -0.13 0.31 0.95
Debt/GDP ratio [e][f] 1 0.03 -0.01 1520 0.05 0.18
3 0.48 0.30 1840 0.76 0.18
5 0.93 0.81 3124 1.41 0.49
7 0.99 1.29 11 1.25 0.54
10 0.35 1.47 -17 0.76 0.45
Income tax simulation: 2 percentage point
reduction in the basic rate
Years LBS NIESR HMT COMPACT CUSUM
GDP [a] 1 0.10 0.51 0.23 0.01 0.50
3 0.63 0.81 0.60 -0.01 0.62
5 0.61 0.35 0.64 0.04 0.78
7 0.07 -0.75 -0.13 -0.03 0.95
10 0.14 -0.68 -1.11 -0.03 1.06
Consumers' expenditure [b] 1 0.10 0.68 0.53 0.05 0.72
3 0.84 1.40 0.77 0.08 1.11
5 1.08 1.13 0.71 0.17 1.14
7 0.82 -0.32 -0.53 0.02 1.30
10 0.79 -0.76 -0.41 -0.01 1.49
Investment [b] 1 0.01 0.08 0.26 0.00 0.02
3 0.14 0.04 0.60 -0.02 0.17
5 0.11 -0.10 0.14 -0.03 0.21
7 -0.01 -0.24 -1.67 -0.02 0.29
10 0.16 -0.16 -1.24 -0.01 0.37
Real trade balance [b][c] 1 -0.02 -0.29 -0.08 -0.03 -0.11
3 -0.35 -0.67 -0.14 -0.06 -0.53
5 -0.56 -0.67 -0.20 -0.08 -0.81
7 -0.73 -0.13 0.07 -0.03 -0.98
10 -0.85 0.26 -0.29 -0.01 -1.25
Unemployment [d] 1 -2 -8 -6 0 -27
3 -49 -25 -59 0 -101
5 -108 -29 -119 -3 -113
7 -106 -5 -96 0 -119
10 -15 19.00 98 1 -123
Nominal interest rate [e] 1 0.01 -0.25 -0.56 0.08 0.14
3 0.32 -0.14 0.02 0.15 0.74
5 0.89 0.31 0.77 0.15 0.34
7 0.38 0.55 1.35 0.07 0.21
10 -1.86 0.16 0.07 0.05 0.24
Inflation rate [e] 1 0.00 -0.16 -0.08 0.07 -0.15
3 0.10 0.08 0.02 0.12 -0.24
5 0.22 0.20 0.08 0.10 0.25
7 -0.12 0.10 0.12 0.04 0.11
10 -0.59 -0.12 -0.04 0.03 0.01
Price level [a] 1 0.00 -0.16 -0.08 0.07 -0.14
3 0.14 -0.17 -0.09 0.28 -0.93
5 0.53 0.18 0.07 0.50 -0.55
7 0.48 0.48 0.46 0.59 -0.22
10 -1.09 0.23 0.42 0.69 -0.13
Nominal exchange rate [a] 1 0.00 0.78 -0.31 0.26 3.11
3 0.10 1.35 -1.21 0.02 2.94
5 0.60 1.24 -0.78 -0.30 1.55
7 1.62 0.33 1.81 -0.49 1.56
10 1.51 -0.76 2.04 -0.68 2.02
Basic rate of income tax [e] 1 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00
3 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00
5 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00 -2.00
7 0.01 0.01 0.45 1.44 -1.99
10 -0.04 0.26 1.20 0.85 -1.98
Debt/GDP ratio [e][f] 1 0.05 0.33 3955 0.59 0.58
3 0.48 1.11 3830 2.49 0.51
5 0.79 2.10 4809 4.41 0.79
7 0.98 2.98 -25 3.59 0.92
10 0.19 4.08 17 2.13 0.91
Increase of 1 per cent in the level of technical progress
Year LBS NIESR COMPACT CUSUM
GDP [a] 1 0.02 0.10 0.05 0.01
3 -0.06 0.35 0.02 -0.26
5 -0.10 0.59 0.06 0.00
7 -0.07 0.78 0.12 0.16
10 -0.05 0.89 0.23 0.22
Consumers' expenditure [b] 1 0.00 -0.06 0.11 0.06
3 -0.08 -0.06 0.08 0.03
5 -0.09 0.05 0.11 0.15
7 -0.11 0.20 0.14 0.27
10 -0.21 0.32 0.17 0.34
Investment [b] 1 0.01 0.07 0.00 0.00
3 0.02 0.09 0.02 -0.03
5 0.01 0.13 0.03 -0.05
7 0.02 0.15 0.06 0.02
10 0.01 0.15 0.10 0.06
Real trade balance [b] 1 0.00 0.07 -0.05 0.24
3 0.00 0.29 -0.07 0.10
5 -0.01 0.38 -0.07 -0.09
7 0.02 0.40 -0.05 -0.09
10 0.15 0.39 -0.02 -0.05
Unemployment [d] 1 32 8 4 1
3 184 19 24 36
5 202 21 47 51
7 193 19 74 33
10 188 13 99 14
Nominal interest rate [e] 1 -0.05 0.15 0.10 0.14
3 -0.15 0.07 0.21 0.74
5 -0.16 -0.03 0.24 0.34
7 -0.16 -0.05 0.30 0.21
10 0.04 -0.03 0.42 0.24
Inflation rate [e] 1 -0.02 0.10 0.10 -0.18
3 -0.04 -0.04 0.16 -0.46
5 -0.01 -0.04 0.17 0.09
7 0.00 -0.01 0.22 0.04
10 0.05 0.01 0.30 -0.04
Price level [a] 1 -0.02 0.09 0.09 -0.17
3 -0.08 0.09 0.39 -1.31
5 -0.11 0.00 0.72 -1.31
7 -0.12 -0.04 1.11 -1.15
10 0.00 -0.04 1.91 -1.23
Nominal exchange rate [a] 1 -0.01 -1.37 0.26 3.11
3 -0.07 -1.65 -0.07 2.94
5 -0.23 -1.69 -0.50 1.55
7 -0.47 -1.61 -1.00 1.56
10 -0.74 -1.48 -1.99 2.02
Basic rate of income tax [e] 1 0.00 0.00 -0.05 0.00
3 0.02 0.00 -0.03 -0.02
5 0.04 -0.04 -0.01 -0.17
7 0.07 -0.09 0.02 -0.17
10 0.12 -0.19 0.06 -0.11
Debt/GDP ratio [e] 1 -0.01 -0.02 -0.11 -0.01
3 0.18 -0.04 -0.09 -0.22
5 0.46 -0.19 -0.01 -0.01
7 0.71 -0.46 0.06 0.08
10 1.16 -0.94 0.15 -0.01
Notes: (a.)Percentage difference. (b.)Difference as proportion of
baseline GDP, except HMT which is percentage difference. (c.) Percentage
points difference from base of current account/GDP ratio for HMT model.
(d.) Difference from base ('000s). (e.) Percentage points
difference. (f.) Difference from base of PSNCR ([pounds] million) for
HMT model.