SHOULD THE UK JOIN EMU?
Artis, Michael
Michael Artis [*]
The Review is pleased to give hospitality to CLARE Group articles,
but is not necessarily in agreement with the views expressed. Members of
the CLARE Group are M.J. Artis, T. Besley, A.J.C. Britton, W.J. Carlin,
J.S. Flemming, C.A.E. Goodhart, J.A. Kay, R.C.O. Matthews, D.K. Miles,
M.H. Miller, P.M. Oppenheimer, M.V. Posner, W.B. Reddaway, J.R. Sargent,
M.Fg. Scott, P. Seabright, Z.A. Silberston, S. Wadhwani and M. Weale.
Drafts of this article have been discussed among members of the Group,
but responsibility for the views expressed rests with the author alone.
This article considers the economic case for UK membership of EMU.
Traditional optimum currency area (OCA) analysis provides only a weak
case for membership: the UK is located among the periphery and not in
the core. Considerations of the possible costs of isolation (the risks
of trade discrimination and the dangers of a volatile currency) together
with some pertinent qualifications of OCA analysis (the possible
endogeneity of the OCA criteria) serve to strengthen the case for
joining. Whilst it is not overwhelming, the final verdict is positive.
Introduction
The European Monetary Union (EMU) is up and running. The choice the
UK faces is whether to join and, if so, when. Public opinion, business
opinion and professional economists are divided on this issue, as are
the main political parties. It is clear that the decision is a political
one and that political arguments are critically important in this
debate. Monetary unions are usually, after all, preceded or accompanied
by political union. Nevertheless, monetary union is an economic issue
and economic analysis is vital.
In this article we attempt to set out such an analysis. The next
section begins with some factual background; what would have to be done
if the decision were taken that the UK should join; what the
constitutional situation is; what the state of public and business
opinion is; what the government's 'five tests' are; and
so on. Economic analysis offers 'optimal currency area' (OCA)
theory as a framework for the discussion of the pros and cons of
monetary union. So, in the next section, we go on to discuss what
optimal currency theory suggests. Finding, as we do, that the verdict to
be obtained from OCA theory is somewhat lukewarm, we proceed to probe
its possible weaknesses. This helps to reduce the negative quality of
traditional analysis -- but without, in our view, transforming the
picture completely. So we seem to be left with a balance sheet of
economic costs and benefits that is more or less neutral. But of course
it is one thing to evaluate the proposition for EMU, so to speak in the
abstract, and anothe r to evaluate the case for joining (or not) an
already existing organisation. It is the latter that is now the relevant
question. So, to complete the analysis, it is necessary to investigate
the pros and cons of a decision to stay out of EMU -- what we can term
'the Canada solution'. We do not find such a solution to be in
any way an infeasible nor clearly undesirable solution on economic
grounds -- as the title we have given it of course implies. Yet there
seem to be some risks in such a solution that help tip the balance of
advantage a little further towards joining. Something depends on whether
non-participation in EMU places the UK's participation in the
Single Market at risk. And a great deal depends, all round, on whether
exchange rate flexibility and monetary independence provide insurance
from external shocks or simply provide an additional route through which
destabilising forces can exert themselves. For large developed
countries, with well-managed financial systems, the balance of advantage
on this score is not obvious.
The background
The European Monetary Union came into being on 1 January 1999, with
an initial complement of 11 out of the 15 EU countries. Eligibility for
participation depended on satisfying a set of criteria laid out in the
Treaty of European Union (more commonly known as the Treaty of
Maastricht).
These criteria require that:
* the national central bank of the country concerned should be
independent;
* the country's currency should have participated in the
Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) for at least two years, without stress;
* the country's inflation rate should have been below a
reference value given by a range of 1 1/2 percentage points above that
of the best three inflation performers;
* its long-term interest rate should have been within 2 percentage
points of that of the three best inflation performers;
* the ratio of the budget deficit to GDP should not exceed 3 per
cent and its debt-to-GDP ratio should not exceed 60 per cent (with
exceptions that require infringements of the deficit criterion to be
"only exceptional and temporary" or where the ratio "has
declined substantially and continuously" whilst infringements of
the debt-to-GDP ratio are permitted only if "the ratio is
sufficiently diminishing ..."). [1]
In the event, one of these criteria -- that pertaining to the level
of the ratio of government debt to GDP -- was effectively ignored,
whilst neither Finland nor Italy fulfilled the letter of the criterion
pertaining to exchange rate performance. Greece failed to meet the
criteria, whilst the UK and Denmark exercised the opt-outs negotiated in
the Maastricht Treaty. Sweden, not yet a member of the EU at the time of
the Maastricht negotiations, was also judged to have failed the
criteria. Both Greece and Denmark are generally recognised as
'prein' countries, that is as countries simply waiting to join
the EMU (but in Denmark's case needing an affirmative referendum
result to do so), whilst the position of the UK, as that of Sweden, is
seen as less enthusiastic about making further progress towards joining.
The British government's position is that UK membership
depends on a positive referendum result in the next parliament (thus
most probably after 2001) and upon its five tests being satisfied (see
HM Treasury 1997). Those tests comprise the following:
* "whether there can be sustainable convergence between
Britain and the countries of the single currency;
* whether there is sufficient flexibility to cope with economic
change;
* the effect on investment;
* the impact on our financial services industry;
* (and) whether it is good for employment".
It has been remarked of all of these tests that they will be
satisfied when the government says so. Certainly they all require some
interpretation. The first two of the tests effectively coincide with the
concerns of OCA theory, which we discuss further below. The others, by
contrast, do not 'belong' to any particular framework of
economic analysis. The fourth, indeed, seems to be the reflection of the
power of a particular interest group, the City of London. It is hard to
see how an effect on investment can be verified before the event, and
much the same comment might apply to the employment 'test',
though this could be related to a concern about the exchange rate at
which entry occurs. Of these tests, the first and second are ones that
correspond to the concerns of OCA theory.
It seems clear that, at present, EMU is not an overwhelmingly
popular option. The Survey of British Social Attitudes has consistently
reported that less than a fifth of those polled since 1993 would
"replace the pound by a single currency", a result confirmed
in the latest (1999) release. [2] In response to related questions in
other surveys, some more favourable figures have been returned, but it
is clear that public opinion has some way to go before being convinced
about participation in the EMU. Of course it can be argued that the
balance of opinion could be significantly swayed by decisive action on
the part of government. It has also been argued that public opinion
could be favourably influenced by revelations of pro-EMU business
sentiment.
However, a recent survey of business opinion found business
sentiment to be very evenly divided on the issue. In a MORI poll of 1000
UK companies, conducted for the Financial Times and published in the
issue of that paper for 1 November, 1999, just 49 per cent (when
weighted by employment) expressed themselves in favour of joining the
euro. A recent survey of professional economists' opinions,
reported in The Economist of 17 April 1999 found 64 per cent of those
who returned the questionnaire to be in favour of switching from the
pound to the euro. The survey was aimed at academic economists and
specifically at professors in leading universities rather than those
working in business or finance. Among those professors declaring
themselves as macroeconomists, the proportion in favour was a little
higher than average, at 67 per cent; monetary economists polled
two-to-one against.
What would the UK need to do to participate in EMU? At the formal
level it would have to be seen to comply with the Maastricht Treaty
criteria. In 1998, when the composition of the present Euro-zone was
decided, the UK would have complied with nearly all of these criteria,
and still would do so today.[3] The exceptions were (and remain) the
criteria relating to Central Bank independence and to exchange rate
performance. The former can be easily satisfied. Participation in EMU
would of course imply in any case an end to the Bank of England's
new monetary policy-setting procedures, since responsibility for such
decisions would pass to the ECB.
The exchange rate criterion could pose more severe problems. The
Maastricht Treaty's formal requirement on exchange rate performance
involves membership of the ERM "within the normal fluctuation
margins . . . without severe tensions for at least the last two years
and "In particular, the Member State shall not have devalued its
currency's bilateral rate against any other Member State's
currency on its own initiative for the same period". The
"normal fluctuation margins" referred to of course meant at
the time of the Maastricht negotiations the [plus or minus] 2 1/2 per
cent margins, but by the time of the 1998 review the ERM had been
substantially changed with the adoption of [plus or minus] 15 per cent
margins after the 1993 crisis. In the 1998 review the Commission looked
for exchange rate stability defined as fluctuation within [plus or
minus] 2 1/2 per cent of the median currency in the ERM grid over the
period March 1996--February 1998. As already mentioned, neither
Italy's nor Finland's membership of th e ERM prior to the May
1998 examination satisfied the 'two years' requirement (the
Finnish markka joined the ERM for the first time in October 1996 and the
Italian lira re-entered in the following month), but emphasis was placed
on the stability of the lira and markka exchange rates rather than on
the need for continuous formal membership for the two-year period. What
would the UK position be? The British government has insisted so far
that membership of an 'ERM II' is not an option the UK would
accept, and that the change in the ERM arrangements following the 1993
crisis makes something of a nonsense of the Treaty's formal
requirements. The UK's prospective partners could probably accept
this, but would reasonably require some assurances about the rate at
which the UK would join the EMU (which would indeed have to be agreed);
and would probably feel compelled to insist that the UK should
demonstrate a period of exchange rate stability. In any case, there
would almost certainly be a period of transition betwe en the point at
which participation was agreed and the formal date of entry. In the case
of the existing Euro-zone countries there was a transition period of
some seven months, between the decision on participation in May 1998 and
the formal start of EMU on 1 January 1999. This period was remarkable
for its stability; the pre-announced cross rates of exchange between the
participating currencies were not seriously questioned by the markets
and none of the defence lines was tested. This reflected, inter alia,
that there was no serious threat of withdrawal by any member country;
whilst the commitments remained firm, speculation seemed pointless --
changing French francs for Deutschmarks would have been like swapping
pounds for pennies. The same assurance might not be so readily available
in the UK case, where the recollection of the crisis of 1992 might cause
the markets to question the arrangements arrived at, especially if
political conditions within the UK could be seen as falling well short
of consensus. Th e ultimate defence line would be a promise of unlimited
intervention in the foreign exchange markets on the part of the ECB, but
such a promise could not reasonably be expected if there were
substantial political uncertainty. This suggests that three things will
be particularly important for a successful transition to UK membership
of EMU: agreement with our potential partners on an entry rate that is
widely seen as sensible and so enlists market support; technical defence
lines involving conditional foreign exchange market intervention on a
large scale if necessary; a reasonably solid domestic consensus; and,
given the above, a short period of transition. [4] In contrast to the
other conditions of entry, this one could be difficult.
Optimal currency area theory
The traditional economic analysis of monetary unions, optimal
currency area theory, was shaped by the pioneering contributions of
Mundell (1961) and McKinnon (1963). Numerous subsequent contributions
have been made within the same framework. A recent review that
incorporates insights derived from different frameworks is available in
Tavlas (1993). OCA theory was created in the period of 'fix
price' macroeconomics and thus emphasises demand shocks as key,
whilst identifying nominal with real exchange rate changes -- reasonable
in the short run, not so in a longer run. Then the central argument of
OCA theory is that the costs of monetary union consist in resigning the
possibility of using an independent monetary policy, and appropriate
exchange rate changes, to deal with shocks that are asymmetric between
the potential partner countries. This cost can be mitigated if the
partners agree on a federal fiscal arrangement that cushions asymmetric
shocks, if labour mobility between the partners is sufficiently high, or
indeed if internal labour market flexibility is great enough.
It is generally agreed that EMU will not feature any federal fiscal
arrangements (such as do exist in the United States) for the foreseeable
future, [5] and it is also quite clear that intra-Union labour mobility
is rather low, again as compared to the United States. [6] Stimulating
internal labour market flexibility remains, however, a realistic policy
option for the European countries. Capital market integration may also
assist the process of adjusting for asymmetric shocks in so far as it
helps promote risk-sharing. One of the aims of EMU is to realise a more
integrated European Financial Area. Recent studies (Sorensen and Yosha,
1998) have shown that there is considerably more risk-sharing through
private capital and credit markets within the United States than there
is within Europe. This feature is presumably linked -- but not
exclusively so -- to the presence of a single currency in the former
case and its absence in the second. The benefits of monetary union are
primarily to be identified with the rem oval of transactions costs in
the exchange of one currency for another. It is popular to argue
nowadays that a single currency, through the transparency it lends to
the practice of discriminating monopoly, also helps to increase
effective competition. Krugman (1990) suggested that the OCA arguments
could be represented in a cost-benefit framework, with a corresponding
diagrammatic expression such as that in Chart 1.
The chart depicts the position of a country contemplating
participation in a monetary union with another country or group of
countries. Costs and benefits (say, as a proportion of GDP) are measured
on the vertical axis, and trade integration with the prospective partner
country or group of countries, along the horizontal. This might be
measured, in standard fashion, as {[M.sub.i] + [X.sub.i]}/[2Y.sub.i]
where [M.sub.i] is country i's imports from its potential partner,
[X.sub.i] its exports to the potential partner and [Y.sub.i] is GDP.
In the chart, the benefits schedule (BB) is drawn as upward
sloping. This expresses the idea that the greater the degree of trade
integration the greater is the benefit of the removal of transactions
costs in the exchange of currencies between the potential partners. The
cost schedule (CC) is drawn as downward-sloping, expressing the idea
that the greater the degree of integration the less effective will be a
nominal exchange rate change in inducing a change in the real exchange
rate. In a group of economies which are highly integrated, a large
proportion of consumers' expenditure in any one of them will
consist of goods imported from the others. Hence a devaluation of its
currency against theirs, and the ensuing rise in import prices, will
have a relatively large impact on the domestic price level, thus
generating money wage increases and nullifying the intended
'real' effects of the devaluation. To the right of the point
E, where the BB and CC schedules intersect, benefits exceed costs and
monetary union is worthwhile for the country under consideration. The
schedule C'C' indicates that costs will be higher for a
country that is especially prone to asymmetric shocks. For a country
that has a similar experience of shocks to the partner it wishes to
join, the costs of foregoing an independent monetary policy will be less
and a lower cost schedule -- like C''C'' -- would
prevail.
The chart is a useful summary of some of the leading issues here.
It suggests, for example, that as integration proceeds, monetary union
will become more desirable. It is also easy to appreciate that smaller
countries are likely to find monetary union more compelling than larger
ones (integration is likely to be higher). At the same time, the
cost--benefit framework used in the diagram is a reminder that there may
be non-economic costs and benefits that could indicate a decision to
join (or not) at an economic cost.
The diagram also suggests, however, what is not generally feasible
and that is that OCA theory can be operationalised in such a way as to
yield a clear calculation of net cost or benefit. Whilst such a
calculation cannot be carried out, it is nevertheless possible to get an
impression that for some countries monetary union is 'more
obvious' (trade integration is higher, the frequency of asymmetric
shocks lower) than for others. In the discussion of the shape of EMU, it
has indeed become popular to distinguish between a 'core'
group and one or more 'peripheries'. For the core group
monetary union seems more compelling, or less undesirable than for the
peripheral groups. In most such exercises the UK appears to rank among
the peripheral countries. We now turn to explain what kinds of
calculation can be made that lead to such a conclusion.
Operationalising OCA theory
The benefits of joining a monetary union can be proxied by the
amount of trade carried out with the countries with which a union is
under consideration. Table 1 conveys some basic data in this regard.
The table shows, on the left-hand side, for each of the EU-15
member countries, the amount of intra-EU trade as a percentage of GDP
('EU trade integration'), and the ratio of intra-EU to total
trade (EU trade intensity). [7] On the right-hand side of the table are
shown as ratios to total exports and imports of goods of each country,
the portion due to trade with Germany. As will be seen, in many of the
extant exercises in operationalising OCA theory in the EMU context,
Germany has been taken as the anchor or reference country. Clearly, some
conclusions which are reached on this basis might not hold as strongly
for an extended exercise in which the EU as a whole or the Euro-zone
sub-set of 11 EU countries is taken as the referent. The relative
figures shown for Ireland in Table 1, for example, are somewhat
different between the two alternative referents, due to the still large
dependence of Ireland on the UK in its trade. As far as these figures
go, it is important to note that the UK is not wildly out of lin e with
other EU countries. Among the larger countries its integration is
actually a little higher than most; its EU trade intensity is only a
fraction lower. On the Germany-centred data, likewise, the UK position
is not exceptional.
More difficult to illustrate, perhaps, have been the costs of EMU
membership, represented by the frequency of asymmetric shocks. Ideally,
what is required is an estimate of the asymmetry in shocks that a
country will experience in future compared with those that will impact
its prospective partner Ideally, one would like to have estimates of the
'no policy' shocks, since it is one of the tasks of policy
precisely to offset them. In practice, economists have had recourse to
two alternative approaches to get an estimate of the asymmetry of
shocks. One, following Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1993), isolates the
shocks as the error terms in an estimate of a two-variable (output and
prices) vector autoregression on which some simple identification
restrictions have been imposed. These restrictions serve to identify
supply and demand shocks separately, where demand shocks are estimated
subject to the restriction that they have no long-run effect on output,
but only on prices, whilst supply shocks may have such an effec t. In
the table (Table 2) we show the correlations of the demand shocks
identified this way with those of Germany. These seem worth more
emphasis than the correlations of supply shocks in that monetary policy
is more obviously capable of addressing them than it is of addressing
supply shocks. The table shows estimates for two periods: 1960-88 and
1960-95. A core-periphery distinction seems discernible in both
estimates, though the composition of the two groups is not fully robust
to the extension of the data period. In any event, the UK seems to
belong to the periphery and not the core, even though its correlation
noticeably strengthens with the addition of the later data.
The alternative approach has been to identify asymmetries in
business cycle phase as a signal of asymmetric shocks in the relevant
sense. Artis and Zhang (1997) reported that using this method,
implemented by measuring the cross-correlations of detrended output
series, gave an impression that the UK was more closely attached to the
US cycle than to the German one and that the ERM period had served to
strengthen the appearance of a 'European' business cycle
affiliation in the case of most other countries. The lengthier data
samples used in the estimates shown in Table 3 support these hypotheses,
albeit in slightly more muted form than in the original study. It
remains true that the UK'S affiliation seems stronger with respect
to the US than the German cycle; and it is true with only one exception
that ERM countries' 'German' affiliations strengthened
relatively to their US affiliation between the pre-ERM and the ERM
periods. However, on the more extended 'ERM' data sample
employed here, the German cross-correl ations of the ERM countries do
not all rise in absolute terms between the two periods.
Overall assessment
What do overall assessments, that seek to combine both benefits and
costs, look like? Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1997) offered one such
evaluation. They computed an OCA index based on the contribution of
various factors to the determination of bilateral exchange rates. These
included: a measure of business cycle synchronisation; a measure of
export composition; and measures of country size and output-weighted
trade intensity. On this basis they classified one group of countries as
"convergent", another as "converging" and a third as
showing little sign of convergence. This identification and the
composition of the three groups resembles quite strongly an
identification based on the use of cluster analysis by Artis and Zhang
(1998a, b), which we discuss below. [8]
Cluster analysis is based on the recognition of similarities
between data sets. The variables provided in the studies by Artis and
Zhang are inspired by OCA theory. They are centred on Germany, which is
taken as the anchor country and include the following six variables: a
country's bilateral trade intensity with Germany; the flexibility
of a country's labour market with respect to Germany's
(measured by the relative ranking of its employment protection
legislation); the synchronisation of a country's monetary policy
(measured by the real interest rate) with that of Germany; the
synchronisation of a country's business cycle with Germany's;
the volatility of its real DM exchange rate; and its inflation rate
relative to Germany's. The inclusion of the last of these measures
is a proxy for counter-inflationary commitment, a variable suggested by
later additions to OCA theory.
Tables 4 and 5 give the results of, respectively, hard and
'fuzzy' clustering analysis when applied to the six variables
mentioned above. The sample period for the data construction is April
1979 to Autumn 1995. Hard clustering operates on a step-wise basis,
forming an initial cluster based on the two countries having the least
distance between their respective vectors of characterisations, then
proceeding to form the next cluster on the same minimum distance
criterion between another pair of countries (or one of the countries and
the initial cluster formed) and so on. [9] Given the way that the
variables are constructed in this particular exercise, clusters are
formed on the basis of countries' similarity in respect of vectors
of characteristics which, in some sense, measure similarity to Germany.
In the case of Table 4, the set of countries includes all EU-15 members
(except for Luxembourg, not separately distinguished) together with the
US, Canada, Japan and Norway. The first cluster formed in the sequence
described is that between the US and Canada (alike, in effect, in being
distant from Germany), followed by a Southern Periphery Group, a core
group and a Northern Periphery Group. Japan is the last single country
to enter a cluster. Chart 2 illustrates the sequential process of the
clustering in a tree-diagram. The procedure of hard clustering can be
carried out in any one of several slightly different ways. In the study
referred to the principal results are robust to differences in the way
in which clusters are represented (the results quoted here are for
'group average' clustering) and to the introduction of a
weighting scheme that groups together the 'cost' items among
the six variables. In this last case bilateral trade and the inflation
differential were each assigned a weight of 0.33 whilst the cyclical and
monetary policy correlations, relative labour market performance and
exchange rate volatility were assigned a weight of 0.33/4 = 0.08 each.
The procedure of hard clustering can be claimed to be wasteful of
information, however. It requires that a country should be classified to
one or other cluster. This means that borderline cases may be
misrepresented. Fuzzy clustering, by contrast, assigns a
'membership coefficient' to each country, where these
coefficients add to 100 per cent. In this way the borderline cases are
clearly identified. Table 5 shows the results of fuzzy clustering
applied to the EU-15 countries, using the same six variables as listed
earlier. This confirms the existence of a similar set of three groups --
with a core and two peripheral groups. The UK is identified here as a
solid member of the Northern Periphery group, with rather little
inclination to belong to the core.
Carlin et al. (1999) provide evidence on another issue that helps
distinguish a core and a periphery. This is the sensitivity of a
country's trade to exchange rate changes. Carlin et al. find that
peripheral countries, especially the UK and Sweden, experience
considerably more sensitivity to unit labour costs in their export
performances than do the core countries. This could provide a reason for
scepticism about the merits of participation in EMU for the peripheral
countries in so far as the loss of an independent exchange rate is the
more costly for them.
The upshot of this review so far, then, is that according to OCA
principles the UK is a marginal candidate for EMU. At least, it is a
peripheral rather than a core country. This does not mean that the UK
should not participate in EMU; aside from other more frankly political
considerations, a number of weaknesses in the OCA analysis should be
emphasised. Some of these may be seen as tending to deliver a more
positive edge to the economic case for UK membership of EMU; but not
all. In the next sub-section we investigate some of these suggestions.
Making for a more positive verdict?
There are a number of reasons for questioning the verdict rendered
by OCA theory. It is convenient to group these under two heads: first,
there is a group of considerations which can be understood within the
framework of OCA theory itself. Then there are some considerations that
come from outside that framework.
Among the first group, an important issue is that of the
endogeneity of the OCA criteria themselves. This issue has been raised
directly by Frankel and Rose (1997, 1998); they argue, on the basis of
an extensive statistical examination of the issue that, as a matter of
fact, bilateral trade intensity and business cycle symmetry are highly
correlated. Thus, if monetary union creates further trade integration,
as seems likely, this will in itself promote greater cyclical symmetry.
Ex post, monetary union will seem easier to recommend than ex ante. It
is not clear, however, that the type of trade created by monetary union
will necessarily have this effect. One of the effects of monetary union
that studies have looked for is an effect on the location of industry;
with more complete certainty about relative costs, it is argued, plant
no longer needs to be scattered across the Union as an exchange-rate
hedge. Location decisions can more freely exploit economies of scale.
The resultant pattern of production, being m ore specialised, is liable
to promote greater asymmetry of shocks rather than the reverse. Krugman
(1993) has emphasised this possibility, pointing to the more
geographically specialised location of industry in the US as support.
Frankel and Rose's econometric evidence does not contradict this
possibility since the evidence is limited to the relationship between
bilateral trade and symmetry and does not touch the issue of the
particular quality of trade promoted by monetary union, which is at the
heart of the specialisation argument. It is worth noting that the
distinction involved goes beyond that of whether the trade created is
intra-industry trade or inter-industry trade. Even the former type of
trade may have asymmetry implications if the intra-trade in question is
in varieties (e.g. the exchange of high-grade motor cars for low-grade
motor cars rather than the exchange of, say, transmissions for engines).
[10] Another reason why the criteria might prove endogenous lies in the
notion that policy itself (o r the foreign exchange market) is a prime
source of shocks; then the adoption of a common policy and the
elimination of a foreign exchange market will ipso facto reduce the
evidence of asymmetric shocks. A suggestion to this effect might be
imputed to the evidence brought forward by Artis and Zhang (1997, 1999)
where ERM countries seem to have moved to a more common business cycle
than those outside. Here the UK evidence is awkward; the UK's
inability to stay within the ERM in the 1992 crisis can reasonably be
related to the fact that her business cycle was out of phase with that
of her partners. It was this that gave substance to the
speculators' insight that a raid should be successful. Thus the
line of causation is not clear. Being successful in the ERM may reflect
prior or coincident convergence as much as convergence reflects the
experience of the ERM.
It has also been argued that, because national monetary policy
transmissions differ, a common policy will necessarily produce shocks
which, if not asymmetrically signed, will be of quite different size.
Dornbusch et al. (1998) regard this as a problem, but the evidence is
mixed (see for example Ehrmann, 2000) and many of the differences
currently existing seem likely to be arbitraged away over a period of
time. Another line of argument is this, however: OCA theory imputes to
real exchange rate fluctuations the role of buffering asymmetric shocks.
Evidence that real exchange rate fluctuations effect this role, however,
is not overwhelming. [11] Further, it may be argued that the foreign
exchange market is an independent source of shocks. Buiter (1999b)
argues strongly in this direction. A calculation by IMF researchers
(Samiei et al., 1999) supports the view that the abnormally large
fluctuations in output in the UK are traceable to shocks arising
independently in the foreign exchange market and by implication in poor
monetary policy-making. Currently, of course, there is more generalised
scepticism abroad about the stabilising properties of foreign exchange
markets, due to the crises in South East Asia. However, it is not clear
that much of that scepticism should apply to the market for sterling, at
least in the presence of well-conducted policies. There is positive
evidence that exchange rate changes promoted in the presence of sensible
complementary policies can have desirable effects: some of it is
discussed in de Grauwe (1997).
A final issue that should be discussed is in fact that of the
policy-making institutions. The 'new' literature on monetary
unions (as summarised in Tavlas, 1993, for example) stresses that the
counter-inflationary commitment of the Union's Central Bank should
be of prime concern to participants. The leadership of the Bundesbank
proved a positive feature for the 'apprentice' monetary union
of the ERM; and its statutes provided a model for the constitution of
the European Central Bank. The overhaul of the monetary policymaking machinery in the UK, its currently low inflation rate and the
concomitant reform of fiscal policy are widely regarded as reassuring in
this regard. Indeed, if anything, the consolidation of these reforms
might be contrasted with the 'under construction' notices
still applicable to parts of the European design, especially, perhaps,
to the fiscal policy component. Nevertheless, there is no doubting the
proper intent of the European design nor the credentials and successful
achievements so f ar of its managers.
The 'Canada solution'
The impression is sometimes given that entry into EMU is, if not
exactly desirable, an inevitable 'pis aller'. The example of
Canada, however, suggests that it is feasible to maintain monetary
independence and to belong to a free trade area with a very large
partner country. The Canadian dollar/US dollar exchange rate is,
moreover, very much more stable than any bilateral DM exchange rate has
been inside the European Union over the past two decades. Since the UK
is roughly twice as big, in relative GDP terms, compared to the
Euro-zone as is Canada in relation to the United States, it would seem
that what Canada can do the UK could also expect to do. And, whilst
there has been some re-awakening of interest in Canada in the
possibility of a monetary union with the United States (for leading
references see Courchene and Harris, 1999, Laidler and Poschmann, 1998),
much of that awakening interest paradoxically is a reflection of what
has been happening in Europe. [12]
Free trade requires fixed exchange rates
The Canadian example serves to blunt, though not entirely to
negate, the force of some of the arguments that can be used to suggest
that the UK 'must' join the Euro-zone. One of these - an
important one - is that sustained membership of the Single Market
requires a means of stabilising competitiveness and insuring against
deviations due to shocks in the nominal exchange rate. In general terms,
it can be argued that a Single Market or free trade arrangement cannot
survive without some stability in nominal exchange rates between the
partners. Where competitiveness is subject to sudden and capricious change, affected partner countries will demand the reinstatement of
protective devices. Thus the achievements of liberalisation stand to be
unravelled in the absence of a parallel agreement on exchange-rate
stability. Some evidence in favour of this conception can be sought in
the complaints brought against the UK, in the aftermath of the 1992 ERM
crisis, that sterling had been the object of "competitive
devaluation ". Whilst this argument has a strong logic, it is
possible to overemphasise it: the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) -- to which Canada belongs (along with the US and Mexico) is not
paralleled by any explicit measures to maintain exchange-rate stability.
Further, the UK market is a large one for Euro-zone producers to sell
into; it follows that their interests would not necessarily be well
served by demanding protection against temporary movements in nominal
exchange rates. Nevertheless, exposure to some kind of risk of
discrimination is a feature of the isolationism that the Canada solution
implies, at least if that isolationism involves erratic exchange rate
changes.
Ensuring exchange rate stability
This brings us to another important argument. This is that
membership of the Euro-zone is the only way to provide British producers
with a desirable degree of exchange rate stability. The alternative --
that of adopting a 'go-it-alone' exchange-rate targeting
policy -- is not credible. Recent events in the world have increasingly
been read as implying that there is no stopping place between monetary
union (and closely equivalent arrangements) and completely free
floating. And the latter, even with a background of transparent and
well-directed monetary policy, is likely to imply some unwonted
volatility in exchange rates. Some of the force of this argument derives
from experience in economies that are unlike the UK's (e.g. the
South East Asian and Latin American crises), but it seems clear that
there is a residual risk of undue exchange rate volatility for a UK
which is outside the Euro-zone. [13]
Wait and see?
To some outsiders the present position of the UK could look like
the reflection of a rational decision to 'wait and see'. By
not joining immediately the UK has the opportunity to learn from the
experience of others and to assure itself on aspects of the Euro-zone
construction about which there are or were legitimate doubts. This is an
argument for the temporary and conditional adoption of the 'Canada
solution'. What are its merits? One aspect of the operation of the
Euro-zone about which legitimate doubts have been expressed is of course
the core-periphery question. For some countries, the adoption of the
single monetary policy seemed wholly inappropriate at the time. Ireland
is a notable case in point, where a relative boom has been sustained by
a laxer monetary policy and a more expansive fiscal stance. The costs of
'upside' deviation are not as obvious as those of a
'downside' deviation; and it is arguable that small countries
have some advantages in economic policy not available to larger
economies like t he UK's. Small countries can adopt tripartite policies and internalise adjustment strategies in a manner not open to
the UK. [14] They can also expect side-payments and a degree of
tolerance for exceptional behaviour from the rest of the EU which a
larger country cannot expect. For these reasons the UK cannot learn much
from the experience of small countries; it also cannot learn much, as
yet, from the experience of the larger economies in the Euro-zone.
These, by reason of their size, have pretty much the monetary policy
they would have given themselves independently and, so far at least,
share a somewhat similar conjunctural experience. Elsewhere -- where the
UK by standing outside might hope to learn something useful -- the news
is probably reassuring, even if the time elapsed so far is comparatively
short: the ECB has progressed considerably in clarifying its monetary
strategy and it has created a high degree of transparency for its
actions. The Stability Pact has also clearly gained credibility and
survi ved the first of its critical early years. But there is a cost to
standing aside temporarily. This is the cost of not being part of the
institutional framework, not participating in the setting-up of the
basic rules of operation. Whilst no potential damage is evident yet from
this exclusion, it is clearly a danger.
In sum, the example of Canada serves to reduce the force of some
arguments that are used to suggest the need for UK participation in EMU.
But there is a residual truth in these arguments, that remains.
Conclusions
EMU comes in a line of European opportunities for the UK which can
be typified as involving a cycle of disdain, obstruction and, finally,
reluctant consent on the British side. [15] First, the project is viewed
with disdain, as not in the British interest and probably not workable;
then, as the project seems to move ahead there is an attempt to stop or
divert it; finally, finding that the project is up and running the UK
eventually joins in. By leaving it late the UK may have lost something.
Switching attitudes from disdain to opposition to acquiescence is
psychologically and politically difficult. [16] The analysis appropriate
to the first stage -- viewing the project as a hypothesis -- is not the
one appropriate in the final stage.
In the present case, it is reasonably clear that, viewed as a
hypothetical project, EMU would not be a UK priority. But EMU is up and
running. Analysis must take account of the fact that the choice is to be
in EMU or out of it, not to decide whether it was a good idea in the
first place. This does tend to imply that some of the arguments for
joining in have a negative quality (being 'the costs of
isolation') which tends to blunt enthusiasm. Nevertheless, in the
present case, and on balance, the economic arguments do point in the
direction of a positive decision.
Joining almost certainly means being prepared to accept some
transitory cost, since the business cycle divergence is not likely to
disappear at all quickly. It also means being prepared to invest in some
policy research into tools that can be used in the worst cases to
substitute for the loss of an independent monetary policy. We have in
mind particularly refinements of fiscal and regional policy calculated
to relieve the worst of the deficiency that would be left by the
delegation of monetary policy to Frankfurt.
* European University Institute, Manchester University and CEPR.
Notes
(1.) Kenen (1995) provides the definitive account of the criteria
and much else of significance in the EMU enterprise.
(2.) In 1992, the percentage in favour of this option reached its
record, at 21 per cent. Curtice (1999) reviews this and other surveys of
public opinion.
(3.) The 1998 review (see the issue of The European Economy, no.
65) employed data through 1997 as the basis for the decisions made;
then, the UK's rate of inflation (measured by the Harmonised Index
of Consumer Prices) was below the reference value of 2.7 per cent; its
long-term interest rate, at 7.1 per cent, was below the reference value
of 7.8 per cent and the UK's deficit/GDP and debt/GDP ratios, at
1.9 and 54.3 per cent, were comfortably below the respective 3 and 60
per cent reference values.
(4.) Genberg (1999), in a review of the analogous transitional
problem that could face Sweden, comes to very similar conclusions.
(5.) Estimates of the smoothing effect of the US Federal
tax-and-expenditure system on intra-area shocks within the United States
have been progressively revised downwards. Initial estimates (e.g.
Sala-i-Martin and Sachs, 1992) suggested that the system buffered
"40 cents in the dollar" of primary income shocks. Later
estimates of the buffering effect have fallen as low as 10 cents (e.g.
Von Hagen, 1992).
(6.) See, e.g., Bayoumi and Prasad (1998).
(7.) Trade is imports plus exports, so in the calculations in which
GDP appears as the denominator it has been multiplied by 2. Direction of
trade data exist only for shipments of goods, so the data in Table 1
refer only to visible trade. In principle it would be desirable to
include also trade in services.
(8.) There are also a number of useful and informal studies
available -- a good example is Taylor (1995) -- which distinguish
similar categories.
(9.) In the exercise referred to, the variables are first
normalised with zero mean and unit variance before an unweighted root
mean square summation of the differences between countries is performed.
(10.) See Fontagne and Freudenberg (1999).
(11.) Canzoneri et al. (1996) examine the issue directly. The
conclusions they draw do not support the idea that real exchange rates
respond "correctly" to the appropriate stimuli.
(12.) As one Canadian colleague put it to me, "the European
experiment made Canadians worry whether they were missing
something". It is more than a little important, of course, to note
that monetary union for Canada with the US is not available on the same
terms as is monetary union with Europe for the UK. The best that Canada
might hope to do is to 'dollarise' itself completely. Buiter
(1999a) argues that this is a decisive reason for Canada to continue
with its present arrangements.
(13.) Of course it is a theoretical possibility that stabilising
the euro exchange rate for UK producers comes at the cost of
destabilising other exchange rates or passing on the erstwhile volatility in the exchange rate to other parts of the economy (e.g. to
interest rates). ERM experience does not lend these 'volatility
transfer' ideas any support, however.
(14.) Ireland has such a tripartite policy.
(15.) Young (1998) provides a good account of British European
policy, from which this caricature is drawn.
(16.) The polls of public and business opinion which report
lukewarm attitudes towards the euro also report majorities that believe
that the UK will nonetheless join. This seems to suggest that the EMU
decision will be a part of this same cycle.
References
Artis, M.J. (2000), 'The UK and EMU', EUI Working Papers,
RSC forthcoming.
Artis, M.J. and Zhang, W. (1997), 'International business
cycles and the ERM', International Journal of Finance and
Economics, 2, pp.1-16.
(1998a), 'Core and periphery in EMU: a cluster analysis',
EUI Working Papers, RSC No. 98/37.
(1998b), 'Membership of EMU: a fuzzy clustering analysis of
alternative criteria', EUI Working Papers, RSC No. 98/52.
(1999), 'Further evidence on international business cycles and
the ERM: is there a European Business Cycle?', Oxford Economic
Papers, January, 51, pp.120-32.
Bayoumi, T. and Eichengreen, B. (1993), 'Shocking aspects of
European Monetary Integration', in Torres, F. and Giavazzi, F.
(eds), Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary Union, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
(1997), 'Ever closer to heaven? An optimal currency index of
European countries', European Economic Review, 41, pp. 761-70.
Bayoumi, T. and Prasad, E. (1998), 'Currency unions, economic
fluctuations and adjustment: Some new empirical evidence', IMF
Staff Papers, 44, pp.36-58.
Buiter, W. (1999a), 'The EMU and the NAMU. What is the case
for North American Monetary Union?', CEPR Discussion Papers, No.
2181.
(1999b), 'Optimal currency areas: why does the exchange rate
regime matter?', Sixth Royal Bank of Scotland Scottish Economic
Society Annual Lecture, forthcoming.
Canzoneri, M., Valles, J. and Vinals, J. (1996), 'Do exchange
rates move to address international macroeconomic imbalances?',
CEPR Discussion Papers, 1498.
Carlin, W., Glyn, A. and Van Reenen, J. (1999), 'Export market
performance of OECD countries', Institute for Fiscal Studies
Working Paper No. W99/22.
Courchene, T. and Harris, R.G. (1999), From Fixing to Monetary
Union: Options for North American Currency Integration, Toronto, D. Howe
Institute.
Curtice J. (1999), 'Can Britain join the Euro? Political
opportunities and impediments', in Cobham D. and Zis, G. (eds),
From EMS to EMU, Basingstoke and London, Macmillan Press.
De Grauwe P. (1997), The Economics of Monetary Integration, Oxford,
Oxford University Press.
Dornbusch R., Favero C. and Giavazzi, F. (1998), 'Immediate
challenges for the European Central Bank', Economic Policy, 26,
April, pp.15-64.
Ehrmann, M. (2000), 'Will EMU generate asymmetry? Comparing
monetary policy transmission across Europe', forthcoming in
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv.
Fontagne, L. and Freudenberg, M. (1999), 'Endogenous symmetry
of shocks in a monetary union', Open Economies Review, 10, July,
pp.263-88.
Frankel, J. and Rose, A. (1997), 'Is EMU more justifiable
ex-post than ex-ante?', European Economic Review, 41, pp.753-60.
(1998), 'The endogeneity of the optimum currency area
criteria', Economic Journal, July, 108, pp.1009-25.
Genberg, H. (1999), 'EMU and the changing structure of macro
risks', Swedish Economic Policy Review, 6, 1, pp.7-33.
Goodhart, C.A.E. (1999), 'Recent developments in central
banking: some special features of the Monetary Policy Committee and of
the European system of Central Banks', Monnet Lecture, Dublin,
forthcoming.
H.M. Treasury (1997), UK Membership of the Single Currency - An
Assessment of the Five Economic Tests, London, HMSO, October.
Kenen, P.B. (1995), Economic and Monetary Union in Europe,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Krugman, P. (1990), 'Policy problems of a monetary
union', in De Grauwe, P. and Papademos, L. (eds.), The European
Monetary System in the 1990s, London and New York, Longman, CEPS and
Bank of Greece, pp.48-64.
(1993), 'Lessons from Massachusetts for EMU', in Torres,
F. and Giavazzi, F. (eds.), Adjustment and Growth in the European
Monetary Union, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
Laidler, D. and Poschmann, F. (1998), Birth of a New Currency: The
Policy Outlook after Monetary Union in Europe, Toronto, D. Howe
Institute.
McKinnon, R.I. (1963), 'Optimum currency areas', American
Economic Review, 53, September, pp.717-25.
Mundell, R.A. (1961), 'A theory of optimum currency
areas', American Economic Review, 51, September, pp.657-65.
Sala-i-Martin, X. and Sachs, J. (1992), 'Fiscal federalism and
optimum currency areas: evidence for Europe from the United
States', in Canzoneri, M., Grilli, V. and Masson, P. (eds),
Establishing a Central Bank: Issues in Europe and Lessons from the US,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp.195-219.
Samiei, H., Martijn, J.K., Kontolemis, Z. and Bartolini, S. (1999),
'The United Kingdom - selected issues', UK Country Report,
99/44, Washington, International Monetary Fund.
Sorensen, B. and Yosha, O. (1998), 'International risk-sharing
and European monetary unification', Journal of International
Economics, 45, pp.211-38.
Tavlas, G. (1993), 'The 'new' theory of optimum
currency areas', World Economy, 16, pp.663-85.
Taylor, C. (1995), 'EMU 2000? Prospects for European Monetary
Union', Chatham House Paper, 1995.
Von Hagen, J. (1992), 'Fiscal arrangements in a monetary
union: some evidence from the US', in Fair D. and de Boissieux, C.
(eds), Fiscal Policy, Taxes and the Financial Systems in an Increasingly
Integrated Europe, Deventer, Kluwer Academic.
Young, H. (1998), This Blessed Plot: Britain and Europe from
Churchill to Blair, Macmillan.
Trade integration and trade intensity in the EU
EU trade EU trade
Integration (%) [a,d] Intensity (%) [a,f]
Belgium/Luxembourg 41.35 73.06
Denmark 16.45 63.15
Germany 11.80 56.73
Greece 10.90 68.55
Spain 12.95 68.52
France 11.40 62.81
Ireland 36.75 62.77
Italy 10.50 56.91
Netherlands 28.50 66.82
Austria 17.95 76.87
Portugal 22.45 77.68
Finland 15.60 55.03
Sweden 17.70 61.03
UK 13.05 55.18
EU-15 14.35 61.19
German trade intensity
Exports (%) [b,f] Imports (%) [b,f]
Belgium/Luxembourg 20.8 18.9
Denmark 23.0 21.8
Germany -- --
Greece 21.1 16.4
Spain 13.4 15.3
France 17.7 20.4
Ireland 14.1 7.0
Italy 19.0 19.2
Netherlands 28.6 20.9
Austria n.a. n.a.
Portugal 18.7 14.0
Finland n.a. n.a.
Sweden n.a. n.a.
UK 12.9 14.2
EU-15 13.6 [c] 13.4 [c]
Note: the data refer only to trade in goods.
(a.)Data are for 1996.
(b.)Data are for 1994.
(c.)Data are for EU-12.
(d.)Trade integration is measured as {[M.sub.i] + [X.sub.i]}/2[Y.sub.1]
-- see text.
(f.)Trade intensity is measured as the share of total trade (exports, imports)
performed with the EU (Germany).
Core and periphery: demand shock correlations w.r.t. Germany
1960-88 1960-95
EU-15 0-32 0-57
Germany 1.00 1.00
France 0.28 0.28
Denmark 0.30 0.25
UK 0.07 0.14
Italy 0.14 0.29
Netherlands 0.17 0.18
Belgium 0.38 0.28
Austria 0.30 0.32
Spain -0.07 -0.03
Portugal 0.20 0.16
Greece 0.18 0.09
US -0.21 -0.22
Canada -0.05 0.03
Norway 0.28 0.22
Sweden 0.07 0.19
Finland 0.16 0.02
Source: Artis (2000).
Business cyclecross-correlations with Germany and the US [a]
Germany US
Pre-ERM [b] ERM [b] Pre-ERM [b] ERM [b]
France 0.65 0.69 0.72 0.34
Italy 0.37 0.43 0.58 0.30
Netherlands 0.79 0.48 0.43 0.31
Austria 0.63 0.73 0.44 0.22
Belgium 0.69 0.56 0.63 0.18
Spain 0.48 0.38 0.64 0.17
Portugal 0.41 0.30 0.52 -0.18
UK 0.64 0.16 0.75 0.35
Source: Artis (2000)
Notes:
(a.)The cross correlations are between the cyclical components of
monthly industrial production figures, after filtering (with [gamma] =
50,000) through the Hodrick-Prescott filter.
(b.)'Pre-ERM' is 1965:5-1979:3 'ERM' is
1979:3-1997:6.
Clusters detected under hard clustering
1. Core group: (France. Netherlands, RMS: 0.56
Belgium, Austria)
2. Northern periphery: (Denmark, Ireland, RMS: 0.81
Switzerland, Sweden,
Norway, Finland, UK)
3. Southern periphery: (Italy, Spain, Portugal, RMS: 0.47
Greece)
4. North America: (US, Canada) RMS: 0.18
5. Japan (Japan)
Source: Artis and Zhang (1998a).
Fuzzy clustering: membership coefficients
Group I Group II Group III
(Core) (Northern) (Southern)
France 62.7 19.9 17.4
Italy 11.6 18.5 69.9
Netherlands 87.3 7.0 5.7
Belgium 87.9 6.1 6.0
Denmark 22.8 58.7 18.5
Austria 66.7 16.2 17.1
Ireland 8.4 75.8 15.8
Spain 8.1 28.7 63.2
Portugal 2.1 4.9 93.0
Sweden 3.2 86.8 10.0
Finland 6.1 82.5 11.4
Greece 8.1 15.5 76.4
UK 5.3 82.9 11.8
Source: Artis and Zhang (1998b)