THE UK ECONOMY.
Young, Garry
Garry Young [*]
Section I. Recent developments and summary of the forecast
After last year's very modest slowdown in growth, the UK
economy now appears to be on the brink of a period of much more rapid
expansion. Even those sectors, such as manufacturing and construction,
which had been stagnating, have picked up speed since the middle of last
year and there are signs that all sectors of the economy will grow
strongly this year.
A similar pattern is evident in the world economy. Growth is set to
pick up, with those countries like Germany, Italy and the emerging Asian
economies, that had been lagging behind the rest of the world, about to
expand more quickly.
A general, broadly-based expansion is welcome, but there is a clear
danger that it will be too rapid and jeopardise the outlook for
inflation. Perhaps the greatest risk is that the apparently benign outlook for inflation in the world economy deteriorates suddenly as the
global increase in demand takes effect. Policymakers are more likely to
be surprised by such global developments than by those emerging from
within their own economies which they monitor very closely. Our own
forecast, discussed in the world economy chapter of this Review, is that
consumer price inflation in the OECD economies will pick up this year to
just under 2 per cent from 11/4 per cent in 1999. There are clearly
upside risks to this forecast, although there is little evidence yet
from commodity prices of stronger inflationary pressure in the world
economy. Oil prices did rise sharply through 1999, but this appears to
have been largely due to supply restrictions rather than evidence of
rapidly increasing demand.
Even if global inflationary pressure were to strengthen, there
would be no need for it to feed through into domestic prices since it
can be offset by appreciation in the sterling exchange rate. Indeed the
very strong exchange rate of the past three years has helped to create
some disinflationary pressure in the UK. Domestically generated
inflationary pressure has also been subdued for a number of years, but
there is now a significant risk that it will pick up as economic
activity expands strongly.
It is useful to scan the various determinants of inflationary
pressure within the domestic economy and to consider the extent to which
they pose a present threat to the outlook. The main determinants of
inflation are generally reckoned to be aggregate demand and supply and
expectations of inflation itself: inflation will be at its expected rate
when aggregate demand and supply grow in line with each other.
The main component of aggregate demand is household consumption.
This is estimated to have grown by 31/2 per cent in 1999. Because this
is slightly faster than the growth in household incomes, the saving
ratio fell marginally to about 6 per cent of household incomes. The
factors underlying household spending are generally very positive.
Employment is at record levels and real wages have grown quite strongly
in the past year. With a cut in the rate of income tax in the pipeline,
households can feel confident that disposable income growth will
continue at a robust rate. Confidence is also supported by very buoyant asset prices which mean that household wealth (including housing) is now
sufficient to finance seven years' consumption.
House prices are estimated to have been rising at a rate of about
15 per cent p.a. at the end of last year. Clearly this is not
sustainable in a low inflation environment, but the momentum behind this
increase is likely to continue into 2000 at least. Increases in house
prices add to wealth and, to the extent that they lead to more property
transactions, also add to spending on consumer durables. Generally then,
the factors determining household spending are very positive, suggesting
that it will continue to grow at a fast rate in 2000. Anecdotal evidence indicates that spending was strong in the new year sales. But this also
draws attention to the widely-reported possibility that spending is now
much more price sensitive than it used to be. Certainly, there appears
to be such a wide variation in the prices of goods, both over time and
across stores, that shoppers have a strong incentive to search for the
lowest prices before making a purchase. This has encouraged many stores
to offer lowest price guarantees and the Internet revolution is also
having some influence in adding to the downward pressure on retail
prices. This indicates that fast growth in household spending may to
some extent be conditional on the continuation of low retail price
inflation.
The second largest component of aggregate demand is gross fixed
investment. This is estimated to have grown by about 4 per cent in 1999,
driven mainly by 12 1/2 per cent growth in investment in the
non-manufacturing business sector. As with household spending, the
underlying factors supporting capital spending are very strong; interest
rates and the cost of capital are relatively low, the stock market
offers a cheap source of equity capital, profitability is high,
corporate balance sheets are healthy and economic prospects are good.
Despite this, there are some negative influences. First, the recent
strong growth in investment might have raised the stock of capital to a
level at which firms have sufficient capacity that they do not need to
increase capital spending further. There is evidence of spare capacity
in manufacturing, but this is less clear in the rest of the economy.
Second, downward pressure on profit margins because of intensified competition will reduce the incentive to invest further.
The third largest component of aggregate demand is government
consumption. This is now on a sharp upward path as the priorities of the
Comprehensive Spending Review (CSR) are implemented. Total managed
expenditure is set to rise at an average annual rate of 5 1/2 per cent
over the three years starting in April 1999, about 3 per cent per annum in real terms. Government consumption is likely to rise a little more
than this, given that spending on debt interest and social benefits are
expected to be subdued. Government investment is also planned to rise
rapidly, with net investment doubling over the period covered by the
CSR. The public finances are discussed in more detail in the Fiscal
Report on p. 29. Thus the prospects for growth in each of the three main
sources of domestic demand are very good at present. The outlook for
external demand has also improved over the past three months. Latest
figures suggest that exports jumped by 10 per cent in the third quarter.
More importantly, the outlook for the world ec onomy has improved making
it easier for British exporters to sell abroad, despite the high
exchange rate.
This suggests that aggregate demand growth has the potential to be
very strong in 2000. By contrast, aggregate supply may have reached or
exceeded its sustainable level. The key factor here is the labour
market. Claimant unemployment fell to 1.164 million in December 1999,
its lowest level for twenty years. Unemployment on the ILO definition in
November was 1.726 million, the lowest level since the late 1970s and
almost 200 thousand below its trough in the first quarter of 1990.
While these indicators suggest that the labour market is very
tight, others provide a more comforting picture. In particular, the
proportion of the working age population who are without work is not
particularly low by historical standards. In the past this has proved as
reliable a guide to the degree of slack in the labour market as other
indicators. This is the measure of slack that is used within the
econometric equation that we use to forecast wages. The other
determinants of wages within this equation are prices, productivity,
taxes and the composition of unemployment to reflect the different
influence on wages of the short-term and long-term unemployed.
This particular version of the wage equation excludes a number of
factors which are thought to affect wage setting, but have either not
been found to be statistically significant in the relationships we have
estimated or have been difficult to measure accurately. These include
measures of union power, the level of unemployment-related benefits and
the toughness of the benefit system. All of these variables have changed
over time so as to put downward pressure on wages, but there is little
evidence that the omission of these factors has led us to over-predict
wages. According to our equation, wage rises were surprisingly low
between 1993 and 1996, but have behaved broadly as expected since then.
With labour market tightness measured by the proportion of the
working age population who are without work, this relationship suggests
that the labour market is close to equilibrium so a further market
tightening would tend to push up wage costs. In other words, economic
growth in excess of what can be delivered by increases in productivity
and the labour force will bid up wage costs beyond the rate consistent
with the inflation target. We broadly accept the Treasury's
analysis that this trend rate of growth is about 2 1/2 per cent per
annum.
In the short term, growth above the trend rate need not raise
inflationary pressure if it can be offset elsewhere. At present, the
combination of the high value of the exchange rate and competitive
forces in the product market are exerting some downward pressure on
import prices and profit margins. Provided growth does not accelerate
too fast, this should be sufficient to keep inflation on target despite
some slight inflationary pressure from the domestic labour market.
However, the most important factor in ensuring that inflation
remains under control is that it is expected to remain under control.
Since inflation is ultimately a monetary phenomenon this requires that
people continue to believe that monetary policy setting is credible.
Monetary conditions (Table I)
Interest rates are now widely expected to rise from their current
rate of 5 3/4 per cent as the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) seeks to
dampen down prospective inflationary pressure. The short-term money
markets are now expecting rates to reach 7 1/2 per cent in the early
part of next year. Given that rates were only reduced from that same
level towards the end of 1998 when the MPG became concerned about a
global economic slowdown, it is a reasonable guess that rates will be
raised to that level again now that world prospects have improved.
Indeed, the economic picture appears much more inflationary now than it
did eighteen months ago when growth was clearly slowing. Consistency would therefore suggest that the MPC raises rates to at least 7 1/2 per
cent.
However, there are grounds for believing that rates do not need to
be raised as far as that. It can be argued that it was never necessary
to raise interest rates to 7 1/2 per cent in 1998, a view borne out by
the subsequent behaviour of inflation which was below the target rate of
2 1/2 per cent throughout most of 1999 and is likely to remain so in the
early part of this year. In addition, this experience has helped to
embed the inflation target more firmly into price expectations as the
MPC has gained credibility and this has lowered the rate of interest
necessary to achieve a particular inflation target. Further, the removal
of automatic fuel and tobacco tax escalators as announced in the
Pre-Budget Report has reduced inflationary pressure. Finally, the
current very strong level of the pound is exerting further downward
pressure on inflation. In our view, an early interest rate rise to 6 1/2
per cent would be more than sufficient to keep inflation on target.
The strength of the exchange rate continues to surprise. Market
interest rate differentials imply that a fairly slender depreciation in
the sterling rate against the euro is expected and that by the end of
2003 the rate will have fallen to [epsilon]1.51. We have assumed that
sterling is fixed against the euro at this rate from this time. This
implies that the exchange rate against the dollar remains at around
$1.65 over the next two to three years.
Summary of the forecast
Our initial estimate is for growth in the fourth quarter of 1999 of
a little under 1 per cent, 2.8 per cent higher than a year earlier. This
gives an average growth rate over 1999 of around 2 per cent.
Our expectation is that growth will continue at an annual rate of
around 3 per cent per annum in 2000 before slowing marginally in 2001.
This is expected to be led by strong growth in domestic demand of a
little under 4 per cent with robust growth in all of the components.
Household consumption is expected to grow by 3 1/2 per cent, the same
rate as in 1999. As discussed above, the background to this is excellent
and the risks are clearly to the upside. Government consumption is
likely to be strong, growing by over 4 per cent with government
investment also projected to rise substantially. We are expecting growth
in private sector business investment to slow down to 2 per cent after
substantial capital spending over the past four years. However, the
risks are again on the upside.
There was a substantial gap between domestic demand growth and
output growth of almost 1 1/2 per cent in 1999 as net trade made a
negative contribution to growth. We expect this gap to narrow
substantially this year as export growth responds to the general
increase in world demand. Should domestic demand turn out to be much
stronger than expected, then it is likely that imports would take up
some of the slack and grow faster than the 8 per cent that we are
currently forecasting.
The goods deficit in the balance of payments is estimated to have
risen to [pounds]27 billion in 1999 partly due to the loss of
competitiveness experienced by UK firms in recent years. We are not
expecting this to worsen much further this year and the overall current
account deficit is expected to rise to [pounds]15 billion, a little over
1 1/2 per cent of GDP.
This projected deficit is a reflection of company sector borrowing
of 2 per cent of GDP offset by a government surplus of around 1/2 per
cent of GDP. Household sector lending is expected to fall to around zero
as the saving ratio declines to 6 per cent of household income. With
both company sector and household sector balance sheets in good shape,
the deficit is not problematic. However, it is fairly clear that should
spending turn out to be stronger than we are expecting that it will need
to be financed by greater private sector borrowing. An early indicator of stronger spending would be an increase in household or company
borrowing and a larger than expected rise in the external deficit.
While manufacturing output is now showing signs of recovery, this
is from a low level. We expect output growth in this sector of around 2
to 2 1/2 per cent in 2000 and 2001. With the exchange rate expected to
stay strong, the traded sector is expected to continue its relative
decline. The output of the private sector service industries is expected
to pick up and grow by around 3-4 per cent over the same period.
In recent years, output growth has been achieved by expanding
employment rather than by productivity gains. This has been achievable
because of spare capacity in the labour market. However, it is doubtful
that there is much more unused capacity to absorb. Consequently we
expect further growth in the demand for labour to bid up average
earnings. This will have two effects. First, it will encourage firms to
economise on labour and improve productivity. Second, it will add to
inflationary pressure.
Average earnings are now forecast to grow by about 5 per cent this
year and in 2001. Productivity growth in the whole economy is forecast
to rise from about 1 1/4 per cent in 1999 to around 2 per cent in 2000
and 2001. Manufacturing productivity growth is expected to exceed this
as those firms hit by the high exchange rate attempt to improve their
competitiveness by cutting costs.
Employment is set to grow at a relatively low rate, so that
unemployment stabilises at around current levels of around 1.7 million
on the ILO definition.
The increase in productivity growth is expected to exceed the
growth in average earnings, hence reducing the rate of growth of unit
labour costs from 4 1/2 per cent in 1999 to 3 1/2 per cent in 2000.
Continued weakness in import prices and a slight fall in profit margins
will contain retail price inflation with RPIX inflation forecast to
stabilise at just under the 2 1/2 per cent target. The path for the
headline RPI is expected to be more volatile, reflecting movements in
interest rates, rising from 1.4 per cent at the end of 1999 to over 4
per cent by the end of this year.
The uncertainty surrounding the forecast is not thought to be any
different from normal. In probabilistic terms, the likelihood of
inflation remaining within 1 per cent of the target at the end of this
year is 55 per cent, with a 34 per cent chance that it is in the same
range at the end of next year. The lower probability reflects the
greater difficulty in forecasting a longer period ahead rather than the
small difference in the point forecast.
With respect to growth, the probability of growth being below 2 per
cent this year is already fairly small at 14 per cent. There is
estimated to be a 54 per cent chance that it will exceed 3 per cent. For
2001, the odds are well spread with an 11 per cent chance of output
falling and a 16 per cent chance of it exceeding 4 per cent. The odds of
growth of between 1 and 3 per cent are 42 per cent.
Section II The forecast in detail
The components of expenditure (Table 2)
Economic growth in 2000 is again expected to be driven by rapid
expansion in domestic demand, offset partially by a further negative
contribution from net trade. Household expenditure is forecast to grow
by 31/2 per cent in 2000, around the same rate as in 1999. With fixed
investment expected to grow at a similar rate and with government
consumption projected to grow by 41/2 per cent, domestic demand is
forecast to rise by almost 4 per cent, slightly faster than in 1999. On
the trade side, export growth is expected to pick up sharply to 61/2 per
cent in 2000 following a strong performance in the second half of 1999.
But with imports forecast to grow by almost 8 per cent, net trade will
again have a dampening effect on economic growth.
Growth is expected to slow to a rate of around 2 1/4 per cent in
2001 and 2002, with a closer match between domestic demand and output
growth. This is accounted for by a slowdown in the growth of domestic
demand and by a better contribution from net trade as export price
competitiveness improves slightly. Household consumption growth is
expected to stabilise at about 2 1/2 per cent per annum while the growth
in fixed investment is expected to settle at about 3 to 4 per cent per
annum.
Household sector (Table 3)
It now appears that household spending grew by about 3 1/2 per cent
in 1999, similar to the growth rate seen in every year since 1995. This
is below our previous forecast when we had been expecting a growth rate
of 4.2 per cent for 1999. This mainly reflects revisions to official
estimates of household expenditure at the beginning of the year rather
than a change in our view of the prospects for spending. Looking
forward, we have revised upwards slightly our estimates of spending
growth for this year and next.
Household income has been more volatile than usual over the past
year as a consequence of sharp fluctuations in receipts of property
income, mainly the distributed income of corporations. This is
associated with changes in the timing of dividend payments due to the
abolition of Advance Corporation Tax from April 1999. Receipts of
property income fell from [pounds]30.1 billion in the last quarter of
1998 to [pounds]28.6 billion in the first quarter of 1999 before rising
to [pounds]32.2 billion in the second quarter. The large fall to
[pounds]27.5 billion in the third quarter more than accounts for a fall
of [pounds]1.5 billion in real household disposable income at the same
time. Since household consumption is relatively immune to quarterly
fluctuations in property income, these mainly affect measured saving.
The collapse in the saving ratio to 4.5 per cent in the third quarter is
a reflection of the fact that the propensity to save out of property
income is high, but property income itself was very low.
In order to focus more clearly on the income movements that affect
spending we have developed a measure of household income incorporating
only non-property income. This is expected to grow by around 3-3 1/2 per
cent over the next two years, driven principally by growth in real
earnings and employment.
In nominal terms, whole economy average earnings grew by 5.1 per
cent in October, but by 3.7 per cent when bonuses are excluded. This is
fairly consistent with other information indicating that median pay
settlements were growing at 3 per cent in October. With no evidence yet
of a pick-up in settlements, earnings are likely to continue to grow at
a rate of about 5 per cent over the coming months. At current rates of
price inflation this is consistent with real earnings growth of a little
under 3 per cent per annum. This is slightly higher than is sustainable
in the long run and we expect real earnings growth to slow down towards
2 1/4 per cent per annum in 2001. With the number of employees expected
to grow by 1 1/2 to 2 per cent over the coming two years (as
self-employment falls), real labour incomes are likely to show robust
growth.
One of the key risks to this forecast is that real earnings and
employment grow much more strongly in the short term as a consequence of
a tight labour market. Another risk is that households respond strongly
to the increases in wealth that they have enjoyed over recent years
through asset price inflation. Between the end of 1996 and 1999, the net
wealth of the household sector rose from [pounds]2,700 billion to
[pounds]4,000 billion, and is now enough to fund almost seven years
consumption. Given that annual household saving (defined to exclude
capital gains) over the past four years has averaged around [pounds]50
billion per annum, it would take about twenty years to achieve such an
increase in wealth simply by saving. Chart 4 compares the quarterly
increase in net financial wealth and housing wealth with household
saving since the end of 1994.
Increases in wealth of this magnitude are bound to add to spending
as households see that their future consumption needs can be met from
capital gains on their asset holdings rather than by giving up current
consumption. However, the increase in spending is likely to be spread
out over time rather than consumed immediately. Taking the long-run
propensity to consume out of wealth as 0.06 suggests that a sustained
increase in wealth of the magnitude seen since the end of 1996 would add
about [pounds]70 billion to household consumption. This is greater than
the total increase in annual consumption of about [pounds]50 billion
over this period, suggesting that much of the wealth effect is yet to
emerge in actual spending. This is partly accounted for by the fact that
much of the increased wealth is held indirectly in pension funds and
that increased housing wealth is not easily realised. One means of
achieving this is through the withdrawal of housing equity through
mortgage borrowing. There is some evidence that this is now increasing
as mortgage borrowing is outstripping overall investment in housing
assets, but it remains substantially less than in the 1980s.
There is little immediate prospect of a slowdown in house price
inflation. There is clearly considerable upward momentum in the market
and this is likely to fuel further growth in 2000. We are now
forecasting house price inflation of 131/2 per cent in the year as a
whole. House price inflation is then forecast to slow down as prices
resume a more normal relationship with general inflation. Past
instability in the housing market suggests that there is a significant
risk that prices turn out to be less well behaved than we expect and the
prospect of speculative profits encourages a more prolonged boom.
Our central forecast for household spending is for it to grow
broadly in line with real non property income, expanding by about 31/2
per cent in 2000 before slowing to just under 3 per cent in 2001.
However, the risks that we have identified are mainly on the upside.
Even without faster growth than we are expecting in real incomes or
house prices there is a risk that households are confident enough to
increase their spending sharply. But with additional upside risks to
both real incomes and house prices, there is potential for very strong
growth in consumption in the short term. The main downside risk is to
share prices, but this would be unlikely to affect spending much in the
short term since there is little clear evidence that consumption has
reacted significantly to their recent rise.
The relatively low level of household saving seen in 1998 and 1999
has meant that the net acquisition of financial assets by households has
been very low. It is likely that households will have been net borrowers
in 1999 for the first time since 1988. This pattern with approximate balance between household saving and investment is expected to continue
over 2000 and 2001 as the saving ratio remains broadly constant. In this
case the stock of consumer credit and mortgage debt outstanding would
grow at around 10 per cent as in 1999. However, more rapid growth in
consumption not fuelled by faster income growth would need to be
financed by stronger growth in household indebtedness. As such, a rapid
pick-up in household borrowing would be an early indicator of faster
spending growth than we are currently anticipating.
Fixed investment and stockbuilding (Tables 4 and 5)
After growth of 11.2 per cent in 1998, there was a deceleration in
fixed investment to a growth rate of about 4 per cent in 1999. This was
accounted for by estimated falls in manufacturing, general government
and private housing investment. Non manufacturing business investment is
estimated to have grown by 12 1/2 per cent reflecting the strong
performance of this sector more generally.
The prospects for capital spending in the business sector are quite
favourable with demand now clearly picking up. The incentives for
private investment are clearly very strong at present. The rate of
return on capital has been at historically high levels in recent years,
even in the manufacturing sector. This is reflected in the above average
share of corporate profits in the economy. The high rate of return in
relation to the cost of capital can be seen also in the high value of
the market value of private non-financial companies in relation to the
replacement cost of their capital stock.
Despite this, the non-manufacturing business sector is not expected
to sustain investment growth at above 10 per cent per annum for much
longer. There must soon come a time when its stock of capital has
reached a desirable level. From the end of this year, we expect
investment growth to slow to a more sustainable rate of about 4 per cent
per annum. Manufacturing industry is now growing again, creating a need
for extra capital, although the relatively low level of capacity
utilisation suggests that much of this is already in place. After a
period of stagnation, growth is expected to pick up to about 2 per cent
per annum in 2001. Overall business investment growth is forecast to
slow to 2 per cent in 2000 before picking up to 3 1/2 per cent in 2001.
But as with household consumption, the risks with respect to the
business investment forecast appear to be mainly positive.
Private sector housing investment is expected to grow by around 2
per cent this year, consistent with the relatively subdued rate of
housing starts last year. Our expectation is that increases in house
prices will encourage growth in housing investment of 4 1/2 per cent in
2000, but this will not be sustained. Public sector housing investment
is expected to pick up very sharply this year, rising by around 27 per
cent, albeit from a low level. Other general government investment is
expected to rise broadly in line with the government's plans. This
is estimated to have been weak in 1999, 3 per cent lower than in 1998.
More rapid growth from now on is expected to lead to growth of 22 per
cent this year from the low level reached last year and 10 per cent in
2001.
We now estimate that there was very modest stock-building in 1999
of [pounds]0.2 billion. A fall of [pounds]1.6 billion in
manufacturers' stocks was broadly offset in the rest of the
economy. We now expect stockbuilding of a little over [pounds]1 billion
in 2000 and 2001.
Saving by the private non-financial sector is estimated to have
fallen slightly in 1999. With higher levels of investment, companies
have needed to increase their borrowing. We are expecting net borrowing
by non-financial companies to grow to about [pounds]22 billion per annum
in 2000 adding to corporate indebtedness. However, with corporate
gearing levels relatively low at present, there is room in the corporate
balance sheet to absorb this.
Balance of payments (Tables 6 and 7)
In the first half of 1999, manufactured exports were running at
almost 2 per cent below their level in 1998. But trade in the third
quarter grew very sharply with the volume of manufactured exports up by
almost 10 per cent on the second quarter. Monthly figures indicate that
exports have continued at a high level in October, albeit a little lower
than in the third quarter, suggesting that this might be a turning
point. We are now expecting export growth to continue at a similar rate
to that of world trade despite the high level of the exchange rate.
The main impact of the higher exchange rate has been on export
prices and export profitablility. Export prices have fallen sharply as
firms have fought against the effect of the exchange rate on their price
competitiveness. We expect to see a modest improvement in price
competitiveness over the next few years and this should contribute to a
pick-up in the growth of export volumes. After a fairly flat year in
1999, we expect growth in exports of around 5 1/2 per cent in both 2000
and 2001.
Import prices have also fallen as a consequence of the higher
exchange rate leading to some increase in import penetration. The prices
of manufactured imports are expected to be fairly flat this year and to
rise by about 2 per cent next year, broadly in line with the price of
domestically manufactured goods.
As with exports, there was a sharp increase in the volume of
imports in the third quarter. We are expecting the growth of
manufactured imports to pick up to around 8 per cent this year, before
slowing slightly in 2001.
The deficit on the goods balance is forecast to grow slightly to
[pounds]28.5 billion in 2000 from [pounds]27 billion last year as the
rise in imports outstrips that in exports. The surplus on the balance on
services, transfers and income is expected to decline somewhat from
[pounds]15.4 billion in 1999 to [pounds]13.6 billion in 2001. The
overall current balance deficit is forecast to widen to just under
[pounds]15 billion in 2000 and [pounds]17 billion in 2001.
Even though we expect the current deficit to rise over the next two
years, it is likely to remain a relatively small proportion of national
income and will not have a substantial effect on the net foreign asset
position.
Output and employment (tables 8 and 9)
Growth in 1999 was not very well balanced with the private services
sector expanding at a faster rate than the manufacturing and
construction sectors. But the current outlook shows a much more
consistent picture across the main industrial sectors is in prospect for
2000.
Manufacturing output grew strongly in the third quarter of 1999 and
early indications are that the fourth quarter was also very good. This
suggests that manufacturing industry is now beginning to recover from
the exchange rate-induced slowdown witnessed in the second half of the
1990s.
Relatively speaking, manufacturing has lost a lot of ground in
recent years. We do not expect that it can make this up without
improving its competitiveness. Instead, our forecast is that growth this
year and for the next two years will be a little less than in the other
main sectors of the economy.
The lack of competitiveness of manufacturing is likely to lead to
downward pressure on employment and upward pressure on productivity
within the industry. It is estimated that manufacturing productivity
grew by 3.5 per cent in 1999. This is expected to accelerate into 2000
to almost 5 per cent as employment is reduced at the same time that
output is increased.
Productivity in the economy more widely is also expected to improve
as the economy picks up steam. The main reason for this is that there is
now little scope for further employment growth beyond that associated
with increases in the population of working age. Further increases in
the demand for labour are likely to bid up real wages, thus encouraging
firms to economise on the number of workers they employ. We anticipate
that employment will grow by a little under 1 per cent this year and by
about 1/2 per cent next year. The number of employee jobs is expected to
increase more quickly than this as the recent shift from self employment
continues.
The projected rise in employment is broadly equal to the increase
in the working age population. Unemployment will then remain broadly
steady over the next two years at about 53/4 per cent of the workforce
on the ILO definition and at just over 4 per cent on the claimant count
measure.
Earnings and prices (Tables 3 and 10)
After the recession of the early 1990s, the rate of unemployment
fell considerably from its peak of 10.3 per cent in 1993 without putting
any upward pressure on inflation. Few people would claim to know the
equilibrium rate of unemployment with any precision, but this experience
suggests that actual unemployment was substantially above its
equilibrium value in 1993 and is a good deal closer to it now. What the
exact position is now is very difficult to judge, but this forecast
suggests that unemployment has possibly fallen slightly below its
equilibrium value. Either way, wage costs now appear to be growing more
quickly than is consistent with the monetary authority's inflation
target. Unit labour costs are estimated to have grown by 4 1/2 per cent
in 1999, reflecting growth of just under 5 per cent in average earnings
and productivity growth of a little over 1 per cent (other influences on
unit labour costs are employer contributions made to the national
insurance scheme and other payments on behalf of emplo yees).
Growth in average earnings is expected to pick up very marginally
to 5 per cent this year and remain at this rate in 2001. With
productivity growth also improving slightly, this translates into a
slowdown in the growth of unit labour costs to around 3 1/2 per cent
over the coming two years. This rate of growth cannot be sustained if
the inflation target is to be met, but competitive pressures will
inhibit the extent to which the increase in costs can be passed on in
the form of higher prices. With the high exchange rate also exerting
downward pressure on import prices, this growth in earnings is easily
consistent with the inflation target over a two-year horizon. Our
forecast is for the target measure of inflation to remain a little under
2 1/2 per cent over the next two years.
National and sectoral saving (Table II)
The current account deficit of the economy as a whole is a
reflection, subject to a statistical residual, of the financial position
of the individual agents in the economy. Table 11 shows how the saving
and investment behaviour of the individual sectors of the economy is
financed. Ultimately, any investment that cannot be financed by domestic
saving needs to be financed abroad.
Household sector saving is expected to remain at about 4 1/2 per
cent of GDP, close to the rate of investment by the sector. This means
that the household sector will not be a net lender to other sectors as
is usually the case. Company sector saving is expected to fall sharply
such that the deficit of saving relative to investment is set to be of
the order of 2 per cent of GDP. The government sector is now meeting the
Golden Rule so that its saving is positive and is forecast to remain in
excess of its investment over the next four years or more.
The current account is expected to move into deficit this year and
in following years by about 1 1/2 per cent of GDP. It is fairly clear
that the movement into deficit of the current account of the balance of
payments is associated with the increased deficit of the company sector.
This can be traced back partly to the strength of the pound which has
encouraged spending to be switched away from domestic goods and towards
foreign goods, thereby reducing profits (from a high level) and company
saving. If this situation were to continue, then companies would at some
stage need to adjust their saving or investment to prevent their
indebtedness rising too quickly. This would feed through either
directly, through lower spending on foreign investment goods, or
indirectly through the effects of lower dividend payments on household
spending on imports, to the current account. The process of adjustment
would also affect prices in such a way that competitiveness is
eventually restored. Through these channels, a current a ccount deficit
is ultimately corrected.
The economy in the medium term (Table 12)
The way in which the economy behaves over the medium term is
determined partly by a range of shocks that are inherently
unpredictable. But there are other important influences on its
development that can be foreseen. These include trends in the size and
composition of the population, forthcoming changes in the policy
framework as well as adjustments to existing disequilibria. It can be
argued that the development of the British economy over the 1990s has
been largely shaped by the need to adjust to the recession of the early
part of the decade. The main problem for the economy over the past two
years or more has been its grossly over-valued exchange rate. The
adjustment to this will have a continuing effect on the economy over the
coming years. But in other ways the economy is well balanced with
inflation low and unemployment probably close to its sustainable rate.
Foremost among the policy influences is whether the UK decides to
adopt the euro. We have assumed that this will take place in 2003, but
that sterling will be stabilised at [epsilon]1.51 (equivalent to
DM2.95), a rate broadly consistent with market expectations, in advance
of EMU membership. Many would regard this rate as being too high and it
is certainly higher than our estimates of an equilibrium exchange rate.
But since the end of 1996 the economy does appear to have adjusted to a
high exchange rate. At first exports appeared not to be affected by the
strong pound, but these then weakened sharply both in 1998 and 1999. The
contraction in the manufacturing sector was also probably a consequence
of the high pound. But we now see grounds for expecting exports and
manufacturing output to recover without a substantial depreciation of
the nominal exchange rate. Partly this will be achieved by a
depreciation of the real exchange rate as manufacturers restore
competitiveness by keeping their export prices down.
Inflation is forecast to remain low over this period. This is based
on a view that the European Central Bank (ECB) will be as successful in
controlling inflation as the Bundesbank has been in recent years. With
the sterling exchange rate fixed, there will not be room for large
differences in inflation across the Euro Area. So long as this is
clearly understood, expectations, which are crucially important in the
inflationary process, should help anchor inflation itself.
The outlook for interest rates and inflation is consistent with
real interest rates of around 3 to 4 per cent. Short-term interest rates
are expected to rise slightly, reaching 6 1/2 per cent. They are then
protected to fall, converging on euro rates by the end of 2003.
Fiscal policy is assumed to be tight on average over the period in
line with the current government's targets. But if the UK adopts
the single currency, then fiscal policy will need to be used for
stabilisation purposes. To have sufficient flexibility for this purpose,
it will be necessary for the budget deficit to be small on average. In
keeping with this, government consumption is expected to grow by less
than GDP. This would allow some increased spending on transfer payments
as the proportion of pensioners in the population rises.
Unemployment, on the ILO definition, is forecast to settle at about
6 1/4 per cent of the working population. This is slightly higher than
is the case now, and is a reasonable estimate of the sustainable rate of
unemployment. The rate of real wage growth is sensitive to which
deflator is used. Using the GDP deflator at basic prices, the real wage
is forecast to grow at about 2 per cent per annum, similar to the rate
of growth of productivity.
The government has identified slow productivity growth as one of
the important problems of the UK economy and it is possible that policy
action over the coming years will be successful in raising it or that
there will be substantial benefits from the introduction of information
technology. However, we have made no special allowance for this. Our
forecast of productivity growth is consistent with past long-term trends
in the economy.
On this basis we would expect to see economic growth of between 2
to 2 1/2 per cent per annum over the next ten years following slightly
faster growth next year, with lower growth beyond that as the population
of working age slows down. Among the expenditure components, household
and government consumption are expected to grow by about 2 per cent per
annum with slightly faster growth in fixed investment.
The current account deficit is set to average about 1 per cent of
GDP throughout the period.
Forecast errors and probability distribution (Tables 13 and 14)
Table 13 provides a set of summary information as regards the
accuracy of forecasts that have been published in the January Review.
The latest complete National Accounts information available when these
forecasts are constructed is for the third quarter of the year.
A rule of thumb is that a 70 per cent confidence interval for a
variable of interest can be obtained by adding a range of one absolute
average error around our central forecast. Thus we can be 70 per cent
sure that GDP growth in 2000 will be between 2.2 and 4.2 per cent. The
size of the average errors indicates that some variables are easier to
forecast than others. For example, the errors in forecasting
consumers' expenditure are smaller than those in forecasting fixed
investment. It is also the case that the error in forecasting GDP growth
is smaller than that made in forecasting its components. This arises
because of offsetting movements among the components.
The probability distributions around the growth and inflation
forecasts have been calculated assuming that the distributions are
normal and are shown in table 14. The standard errors have been
calculated from the historical forecast errors underlying table 13.
These estimates of the probability distribution around our central
forecasts provide a quantitative assessment of the limits of our
forecasts.
Our estimates suggest that there is about a 68 per cent chance that
growth this year will turn our to be in the range of 2 to 4 per cent,
with only a 14 per cent chance of growth below 2 per cent. For next
year, growth prospects are much more uncertain. There is approximately a
one in ten chance that it will be negative and a one in four chance that
it will be less than 1 per cent. There is a 42 per cent chance that it
will be between 1 and 3 per cent and a one in three chance that it will
be above that.
For inflation, there is a more than evens chance that it will end
the year between 1.5 and 2.5 per cent. The risks are clearly larger
looking ahead. In two years time, there is a 46 per cent chance that
inflation will be above 2 1/2 per cent. However, the imprecision of the
forecast is shown by the fact that there is a one in three chance that
it will be below 1 1/2 per cent. The chances that it will be more than 1
per cent away from target in either direction is put at 66 per cent. The
fact that it has stayed within this fairly narrow bound over the past
two and a half years is an indication of either the skill of the
Monetary Policy Committee or their good fortune.
Exchange rates and interest rates
UK exchange rates Oil FT
Effective [a] $ Euro price [b] All-share
$ index
1996 86.3 1.56 1.22 19.5 1895
1997 100.5 1.64 1.45 18.6 2236
1998 103.9 1.66 1.49 12.4 2626
1999 103.6 1.63 1.52 17.4 2943
2000 106.9 1.65 1.59 21.3 3136
2001 104.9 1.65 1.55 20.9 3291
2002 103.5 1.65 1.52 21.3 3446
1999 I 101.1 1.63 1.49 11.2 2772
1999 II 104.1 1.61 1.51 15.3 2965
1999 III 103.8 1.60 1.53 20.1 2934
Forecast
1999 IV 105.4 1.67 1.55 23.1 3100
2000 I 107.7 1.65 1.60 22.2 3079
2000 II 107.2 1.65 1.59 21.4 3116
2000 III 106.6 1.65 1.58 20.7 3155
2000 IV 106.1 1.65 1.57 20.7 3194
2001 I 105.5 1.65 1.56 20.7 3232
2001 II 105.3 1.65 1.55 20.8 3272
2001 III 104.7 1.65 1.54 20.9 3310
2001 IV 104.1 1.65 1.53 21.0 3350
Percentage changes
1997/96 16.5 4.9 19.2 -4.5 18.0
1998/97 3.4 1.2 2.3 -33.3 17.5
1999/98 -0.3 -1.8 2.2 40.6 12.0
2000/99 3.2 1.6 4.3 21.9 6.6
2001/00 -1.9 -0.2 -2.3 -1.8 4.9
2002/01 -1.4 -0.2 -1.7 1.8 4.7
1999IV/98IV 4.8 -0.5 8.7 104.0 23.9
2000IV/99IV 0.7 -0.9 1.3 -10.6 3.0
2001IV/OOIV -1.9 -0.4 -2.3 1.5 4.9
Interest rates
UK base Mortgage 20-year World inter-
rate interest UK gilts [d] est rates [e]
1996 6.0 6.7 8.3 4.2
1997 6.6 7.2 7.1 4.0
1998 7.2 7.8 5.3 3.9
1999 5.3 6.5 4.7 3.3
2000 6.3 7.2 5.0 4.0
2001 6.5 7.5 5.0 4.6
2002 5.9 7.0 5.0 5.0
1999 I 5.7 6.8 4.4 3.3
1999 II 5.2 6.4 4.7 3.0
1999 III 5.1 6.3 4.8 3.1
Forecast
1999 IV 5.4 6.5 4.9 3.8
2000 I 6.0 7.0 5.0 3.7
2000 II 6.3 7.2 5.0 4.1
2000 III 6.5 7.4 5.0 4.2
2000 IV 6.5 7.4 5.0 4.2
2001 I 6.5 7.5 5.0 4.4
2001 II 6.5 7.5 5.0 4.5
2001 III 6.5 7.5 5.0 4.7
2001 IV 6.5 7.5 5.0 4.8
Percentage changes
1997/96
1998/97
1999/98
2000/99
2001/00
2002/01
1999IV/98IV
2000IV/99IV
2001IV/00IV
Monetary
aggregates [c]
M4 MO
([pounds] billion)
1996 682 25
1997 721 26
1998 780 28
1999 805 30
2000 886 32
2001 978 34
2002 1065 35
1999 I 786 28
1999 II 792 29
1999 III 791 29
Forecast
1999 IV 805 30
2000 I 823 30
2000 II 843 31
2000 III 864 31
2000 IV 886 32
2001 I 909 32
2001 II 932 33
2001 III 955 33
2001 IV 978 34
Percentage changes
1997/96 5.7 6.5
1998/97 8.2 5.7
1999/98 3.3 7.1
2000/99 10.1 6.6
2001/00 10.3 6.0
2002/01 9.0 5.2
1999IV/98IV 3.3 7.1
2000IV/99IV 10.1 6.6
2001IV/00IV 10.3 6.0
Source: Economic Trends; Financial Statistics; NIESR estimates.
(a.)1990=100.
(b.)Per barrel, OPEC average.
(c.)Seasonally adjusted, end quarter figures.
(d.)Nominal zero coupon yields.
(e.)Average 3-month rates in G7 countries (excluding UK)
Gross domestic product and components of expenditure
[pounds] billion, 1995 prices, seasonally adjusted
Final consumption Gross Capital
expenditure formation
Gross Change in
Households General fixed inventories
& NPISH [a] gov't investment [b]
1996 470.6 142.8 121.9 1.8
1997 488.9 140.8 131.3 3.8
1998 504.8 141.8 145.9 3.5
1999 522.8 147.1 151.9 0.2
2000 541.3 153.8 156.9 1.2
2001 555.7 157.5 162.4 1.1
2002 568.8 161.3 168.6 1.0
1999 I 129.2 36.2 37.8 0.9
1999 II 130.2 36.5 38.1 -0.6
1999 III 131.0 36.8 37.9 -0.5
Forecost
1999 IV 132.4 37.5 38.1 0.4
2000 I 133.8 38.1 38.7 0.3
2000 II 134.8 38.3 39.1 0.3
2000 III 135.9 38.6 39.4 0.3
2000 IV 136.8 38.8 39.7 0.3
2001 I 137.6 39.0 40.1 0.3
2001 II 138.5 39.3 40.4 0.3
2001 III 139.4 39.5 40.8 0.3
2001 IV 140.2 39.7 41.2 0.3
Percentage changes
1997/96 3.9 -1.4 7.7
1998/97 3.2 0.7 11.2
1999/98 3.6 3.7 4.1
2000/99 3.5 4.6 3.3
2001/100 2.7 2.4 3.5
2002/01 2.4 2.4 3.9
1999IV/98IV 4.1 4.6 0.9
2000IV/99IV 3.4 3.4 4.2
2001IV/00IV 2.5 2.4 3.6
Domestic Total Total Total Residual GDP
demand exports final imports at
expenditure market
prices
1996 737.1 217.6 954.7 224.0 0.0 730.8
1997 764.8 236.3 1001.1 244.6 0.0 756.4
1998 796.0 242.0 1038.0 266.2 1.0 772.8
1999 822.0 249.9 1071.9 284.9 0.7 787.7
2000 853.2 266.2 1119.3 307.4 0.7 812.6
2001 876.7 278.7 1155.5 324.9 0.7 831.3
2002 899.8 292.3 1192.1 341.4 0.2 851.5
1999 I 204.1 59.6 263.6 69.2 0.2 194.6
1999 II 204.2 61.1 265.4 69.5 0.2 196.1
1999 III 205.3 64.7 270.0 72.6 0.2 197.6
Forecost
1999 IV 208.4 64.5 272.9 73.7 0.2 199.4
2000 I 210.9 65.5 276.4 75.1 0.2 201.4
2000 II 212.6 66.1 278.7 76.3 0.2 202.6
2000 III 214.1 66.9 281.0 77.4 0.2 203.7
2000 IV 215.6 67.7 283.3 78.6 0.2 204.9
2001 I 217.0 68.5 285.5 79.6 0.2 206.0
2001 II 218.5 69.3 287.7 80.7 0.2 207.2
2001 III 219.9 70.1 290.0 81.8 0.2 208.4
2001 IV 221.4 70.9 292.3 82.8 0.2 209.7
Percentage changes
1997/96 3.8 8.6 4.9 9.2 3.5
1998/97 4.1 2.4 3.7 8.8 2.2
1999/98 3.3 3.3 3.3 7.0 1.9
2000/99 3.8 6.5 4.4 7.9 3.2
2001/100 2.8 4.7 3.2 5.7 2.3
2002/01 2.6 4.9 3.2 5.1 2.4
1999IV/98IV 3.4 7.1 4.2 8.2 2.8
2000IV/99IV 3.5 4.9 3.8 6.6 2.8
2001IV/00IV 2.7 4.8 3.2 5.4 2.3
Adjustment to Gross
basic value
prices added at
basic prices
1996 80.5 650.2
1997 84.5 671.9
1998 84.7 688.1
1999 86.1 701.6
2000 89.3 723.3
2001 91.9 739.4
2002 94.4 757.1
1999 I 21.3 173.3
1999 II 21.4 174.6
1999 III 21.6 176.0
Forecost
1999 IV 21.8 177.6
2000 I 22.1 179.4
2000 II 22.2 180.3
2000 III 22.4 181.3
2000 IV 22.6 182.3
2001 I 22.7 183.3
2001 II 22.9 184.3
2001 III 23.0 185.3
2001 IV 23.2 186.5
Percentage changes
1997/96 5.0 3.3
1998/97 0.2 2.4
1999/98 1.7 2.0
2000/99 3.6 3.1
2001/100 2.9 2.2
2002/01 2.7 2.4
1999IV/98IV 3.1 2.8
2000IV/99IV 3.6 2.7
2001IV/00IV 2.8 2.3
Source: Economic Trends; NIESR estimates.
(a.)Non-profit institutions serving households.
(b.)Including acquisitions less disposals of valuables.
Household income and expenditure
Seasonally adjusted
Compen- Gross
Average [a] Employees sation of disposable
earnings employ- income
ees [d]
1995=100 millions [pounds] billion,
current prices
1996 103.3 22.7 404.5 521.2
1997 107.9 23.3 432.4 554.6
1998 112.9 23.8 463.8 569.1
1999 118.3 24.1 494.5 601.3
2000 124.3 24.5 528.3 641.7
2001 130.4 24.7 557.8 673.6
2002 136.1 24.9 585.2 704.0
1999 I 116.8 24.0 121.1 145.0
1999 II 117.8 24.0 122.6 150.4
1999 III 118.4 24.2 124.1 149.0
Forecast
1999 IV 120.3 24.3 126.6 156.9
2000 I 121.9 24.4 129.0 158.9
2000 II 123.5 24.5 131.1 159.3
2000 III 125.1 24.6 133.1 160.9
2000 IV 126.6 24.6 135.0 162.7
2001 I 128.2 24.7 137.0 164.3
2001 II 129.7 24.7 138.4 167.9
2001 III 131.1 24.8 140.1 169.5
2001 IV 132.6 24.9 142.3 171.9
Percentage changes
1997/96 4.4 2.4 6.9 6.4
1998/97 4.6 2.4 7.3 2.6
1999/98 4.8 1.3 6.6 5.7
2000/99 5.0 1.6 6.8 6.7
2001/00 4.9 0.9 5.6 5.0
2002/01 4.3 0.6 4.9 4.5
1999IV/98IV 4.8 1.4 6.8 7.8
2000IV/99IV 5.3 1.3 6.6 3.7
2001IV/00IV 4.7 1.0 5.4 5.6
Real Real Final consumption
household non- expenditure
disposable property
income [b] income [f] Total Durable
[pounds] billion,
1995 prices
1996 505.4 371.1 470.6 42.7
1997 524.5 385.7 488.9 48.0
1998 524.9 390.6 504.8 51.1
1999 541.3 399.1 522.8 53.9
2000 565.3 413.1 541.3 57.1
2001 579.0 425.6 555.7 57.6
2002 591.6 436.9 568.8 58.6
1999 I 131.8 98.5 129.2 13.2
1999 II 135.4 98.2 130.2 13.4
1999 III 134.0 100.3 131.0 13.5
Forecast
1999 IV 140.1 102.1 132.4 13.8
2000 I 141.1 103.1 133.8 14.4
2000 II 140.7 102.8 134.8 14.3
2000 III 141.3 103.3 135.9 14.2
2000 IV 142.1 103.9 136.8 14.2
2001 I 142.6 104.3 137.6 14.2
2001 II 144.8 106.4 138.5 14.3
2001 III 145.3 106.9 139.4 14.5
2001 IV 146.4 107.9 140.2 14.6
Percentage changes
1997/96 3.8 3.9 3.9 12.3
1998/97 0.1 1.3 3.2 6.6
1999/98 3.1 2.2 3.6 5.5
2000/99 4.4 3.5 3.5 5.8
2001/00 2.4 3.0 2.7 0.9
2002/01 2.2 2.6 2.4 1.8
1999IV/98IV 5.5 2.8 4.1 7.3
2000IV/99IV 1.5 1.8 3.4 3.0
2001IV/00IV 3.0 3.9 2.5 2.5
Savings House
ratio [c] prices [e]
per cent 1995=100
1996 9.5 103.7
1997 9.3 112.8
1998 6.1 125.7
1999 6.0 139.7
2000 6.4 158.5
2001 6.2 168.5
2002 6.1 172.7
1999 I 5.1 130.3
1999 II 7.0 135.9
1999 III 4.5 143.8
Forecast
1999 IV 7.6 148.7
2000 I 7.4 152.7
2000 II 6.4 157.0
2000 III 6.1 160.8
2000 IV 5.9 163.6
2001 I 5.7 166.0
2001 II 6.5 168.0
2001 III 6.3 169.5
2001 IV 6.4 170.7
Percentage changes
1997/96 8.8
1998/97 11.5
1999/98 11.1
2000/99 13.5
2001/00 6.3
2002/01 2.5
1999IV/98IV 14.8
2000IV/99IV 10.0
2001IV/00IV 4.4
Source: Economic Trends; NIESR estimates.
(a.)Average earnings equal wages and salaries divided by the number
of employees in employment.
(b.)Deflated by consumers' expenditure deflator.
(c.)Ratio of savings to disposable income.
(d.)Includes employers' social contribution.
(e.)Department of Environment, mix adjusted.
(f.)Real non-property income is wages and salaries plus social
benefits received plus a share of the gross operating surplus less
social contributions paid by households less taxes paid on non-property
income.
Forecasts of fixed investment
[pounds] billion, 1995 prices, seasonally
adjusted
Business investment Housing
Manufacturing Non-manufacturing Total Private Public
1996 17.8 65.4 83.2 19.9 2.3
1997 19.8 73.2 93.0 20.8 1.8
1998 20.7 85.4 106.1 22.1 1.7
1999 17.6 96.1 113.7 21.6 1.7
2000 17.2 98.6 115.7 22.0 2.2
2001 17.6 102.3 119.8 21.7 2.5
2002 18.0 106.2 124.1 21.7 2.9
1999 I 4.7 23.4 28.0 5.5 0.4
1999 II 4.5 24.4 28.8 5.4 0.4
1999 III 4.3 24.3 28.6 5.4 0.4
Forecast
1999 IV 4.2 24.1 28.3 5.4 0.5
2000 I 4.3 24.3 28.6 5.5 0.5
2000 II 4.3 24.5 28.8 5.5 0.5
2000 III 4.3 24.8 29.1 5.5 0.5
2000 IV 4.3 25.0 29.3 5.5 0.6
2001 I 4.4 25.2 29.6 5.4 0.6
2001 II 4.4 25.4 29.8 5.4 0.6
2001 III 4.4 25.7 30.1 5.4 0.6
2001 IV 4.4 25.9 30.4 5.4 0.7
Percentage changes
1997/96 11.3 11.9 11.8 4.6 -18.0
1998/97 4.2 16.7 14.0 6.0 -7.3
1999/98 -14.7 12.5 7.2 -2.0 -0.9
2000/99 -2.5 2.6 1.8 1.9 27.4
2001/00 2.2 3.8 3.5 -1.6 15.8
2002/01 2.2 3.8 3.6 0.1 15.0
1999IV/98IV -18.9 6.0 1.3 0.6 21.1
2000IV/99IV 3.1 3.7 3.6 1.4 18.2
2001IV/00IV 2.2 3.8 3.6 -1.5 15.4
General Total Real Cost Corporate
government [a] of capital profit share
(excl. dwellings) (%) of GDP (%)
1996 10.3 121.9 4.3 27.1
1997 9.4 131.3 4.1 27.0
1998 10.2 145.9 3.8 25.8
1999 9.9 151.9 3.3 24.7
2000 12.0 156.9 3.2 25.0
2001 13.3 162.4 3.4 24.4
2002 14.7 168.6 3.3 24.3
1999 I 2.6 37.8 3.4 23.8
1999 II 2.1 38.1 3.5 24.5
1999 III 2.4 37.9 3.0 25.1
Forecast
1999 IV 2.8 38.1 3.3 25.4
2000 I 2.9 38.7 3.1 25.3
2000 II 3.0 39.1 3.3 25.0
2000 III 3.0 39.4 3.3 24.8
2000 IV 3.1 39.7 3.3 24.7
2001 I 3.2 40.1 3.3 24.5
2001 II 3.3 40.4 3.4 24.5
2001 III 3.4 40.8 3.4 24.5
2001 IV 3.4 41.2 3.4 24.2
Percentage changes
1997/96 -8.3 7.7
1998/97 7.9 11.2
1999/98 -2.9 4.1
2000/99 22.1 3.3
2001/00 10.4 3.5
2002/01 10.4 3.9
1999IV/98IV -0.9 0.9
2000IV/99IV 13.6 4.2
2001IV/00IV 10.4 3.6
Source: Economic Trends; NIESR estimates.
(a.)Includes public corporations not included within business investment.
Inventory accumulation
Change in inventories,
[pounds] billion 1995 prices
Manufacturing Distribution Other [a] Total
1996 -0.3 1.3 0.8 1.8
1997 -0.6 2.3 2.1 3.8
1998 0.7 0.8 2.0 3.5
Forecast
1999 -1.6 0.5 1.3 0.2
2000 -0.2 1.1 0.3 1.2
2001 -0.3 1.1 0.3 1.1
Stock-output ratios
(1995=100) Cost of
Manufacturing [b] Distribution [c] Other Stocks (%)
1996 100.8 101.0 100.2 5.8
1997 99.5 103.2 98.4 10.2
1998 97.5 104.5 105.0 9.4
Forecast
1999 96.1 104.1 106.7 1.0
2000 93.8 102.7 104.0 6.7
2001 91.4 101.7 104.3 6.4
Source: Economic Trends and NIESER estimates.
(a.)Includes National Accounts quarterly alignment adjustment.
(b.)Manufacturers' stocks to manufacturing production.
(c.)Distributors' stocks to distribution output.
Balance of payments: current account
Seasonally adjusted
Export volume Import volume Terms of
Total Total trade [b]
Manufactures goods Manufactures goods
([pounds] billion at
1995 prices) [a] 1995=100
1996 140.0 165.5 149.5 180.4 101.0
1997 152.9 179.1 165.0 196.8 103.7
1998 156.1 181.4 181.4 213.5 106.0
1999 161.5 185.0 194.4 227.9 107.3
2000 174.0 199.0 211.6 246.1 108.8
2001 183.4 209.7 223.8 258.4 109.2
2002 193.9 221.4 236.1 270.4 109.3
1999 I 38.2 43.9 46.8 54.8 106.3
1999 II 38.8 44.6 46.8 55.1 107.4
1999 III 42.5 48.5 50.0 58.6 106.9
Forecast
1999 IV 42.0 48.1 50.8 59.3 108.5
2000 I 42.7 48.9 51.7 60.3 108.6
2000 II 43.2 49.4 52.5 61.1 108.7
2000 III 43.8 50.1 53.3 61.9 108.9
2000 IV 44.3 50.7 54.1 62.7 109.0
2001 I 44.9 51.4 54.8 63.5 109.1
2001 II 45.5 52.1 55.6 64.2 109.3
2001 III 46.2 52.8 56.3 65.0 109.3
2001 IV 46.8 53.5 57.1 65.7 109.3
Percentage changes
1997/96 9.2 8.2 10.4 9.1 2.7
1998/1997 2.1 1.3 10.0 8.5 2.2
1999/1998 3.4 2.0 7.2 6.7 1.1
2000/1999 7.7 7.6 8.9 8.0 1.4
2001/2000 5.4 5.3 5.8 5.0 0.4
2002/2001 5.7 5.6 5.5 4.6 0.0
1999/V/98/V 8.4 7.2 9.4 9.3 1.6
2000/V/99/V 5.5 5.5 6.5 5.7 0.5
2001/V/00/V 5.6 5.5 5.6 4.8 0.2
Export Goods Services Current
price com- balance transfers & balance
etitiveness [c] income
([pounds] billion) [c] balance
1996 102.0 -13.1 13.2 0.1
1997 111.1 -11.9 19.3 7.4
1998 110.0 -20.8 20.8 0.0
1999 106.4 -27.0 15.4 -11.5
2000 105.9 -28.5 13.6 -14.9
2001 105.2 -29.1 12.2 -16.8
2002 104.5 -28.7 11.8 -16.9
1999 I 106.5 -7.4 3.8 -3.6
1999 II 107.2 -6.8 4.1 -2.6
1999 III 104.4 -6.2 3.6 -2.5
Forecast
1999 IV 107.2 -6.6 3.9 -2.7
2000 I 106.2 -6.9 3.6 -3.3
2000 II 106.0 -7.2 3.4 -3.7
2000 III 105.8 -7.2 3.3 -3.9
2000 IV 105.6 -7.3 3.3 -4.0
2001 I 105.4 -7.3 3.2 -4.1
2001 II 105.5 -7.2 3.1 -4.1
2001 III 105.1 -7.3 3.0 -4.3
2001 IV 104.8 -7.3 2.9 -4.3
Percentage changes
1997/96 9.0
1998/1997 -1.0
1999/1998 -3.3
2000/1999 -0.4
2001/2000 -0.7
2002/2001 -0.7
1999/V/98/V -0.3
2000/V/99/V -1.5
2001/V/00/V -0.8
World
trade [d]
1995=100
1996 105.3
1997 118.7
1998 126.7
1999 134.3
2000 145.1
2001 153.3
2002 161.5
1999 I 128.5
1999 II 132.9
1999 III 136.3
Forecast
1999 IV 139.4
2000 I 141.8
2000 II 144.0
2000 III 146.2
2000 IV 148.4
2001 I 150.3
2001 II 152.1
2001 III 154.4
2001 IV 156.5
Percentage changes
1997/96 12.7
1998/1997 6.8
1999/1998 6.0
2000/1999 8.1
2001/2000 5.7
2002/2001 5.3
1999IV/98IV 10.8
2000IV/99IV 6.4
2001IV/00IV 5.4
Source: Economic Trends; NIESR estimates.
(a.) Balance of payments basis.
(b.) Ratio of average value of exports of goods to imports of
goods.
(c.) Balance of payments basis.
(d.) UK export market weights.
(e.) A rise denotes a loss in UK competitiveness.
Financial account
[pounds] billion
Basic Current Net direct Net portfolio Other investment
balance [a] account investment [b] investment abroad [b,c]
1996 -47.4 0.1 -6.0 -41.6 -137.8
1997 -32.9 7.4 -16.3 -24.1 -169.7
1998 -47.9 0.0 -33.4 -14.5 -13.8
Forecast
1999 6.3 -11.5 -74.8 92.7 -140.0
2000 -9.9 -14.9 -22.3 27.3 -120.0
2001 -38.1 -16.8 -23.4 2.1 -120.0
Other investment Balancing
in the UK [b,c] item
1996 181.3 -3.9
1997 210.2 7.6
1998 79.9 18.2
Forecast
1999 133.7 0.0
2000 131.3 1.4
2001 158.1 0.1
Source: Economic Trends; NIESR estimates.
(a.)Current account plus net direct and portfolio investments.
(b.)A negative sign implies a capital outflow.
(c.)'Other' investment includes international bank loans
and deposits.
Output and productivity
Seasonally adjusted, 1995=100
Sectoral output [a]
Manufac- Public Distri- Business Construct-
turing bution services ion
(0.216) (0.225) (0.146) (0.138) (0.052)
1996 100.4 102.0 103.2 105.6 101.5
1997 101.7 103.5 106.5 114.7 104.7
1998 102.0 105.6 108.7 122.6 106.0
1999 101.8 107.5 110.4 126.5 106.3
2000 104.2 111.6 114.0 130.9 109.4
2001 106.4 113.9 117.9 135.4 111.9
2002 108.9 116.2 122.4 140.5 114.2
1999 I 100.9 106.7 109.6 124.2 105.5
1999 II 101.2 106.8 109.9 126.5 105.9
1999 III 102.4 107.2 110.8 127.2 106.5
Forecast
1999 IV 102.8 109.2 111.4 128.0 107.2
2000 I 103.4 110.8 112.6 129.3 108.4
2000 II 103.9 111.3 113.4 130.3 109.1
2000 III 104.5 111.9 114.4 131.4 109.8
2000 IV 105.0 112.5 115.4 132.5 110.4
2001 I 105.5 113.0 116.3 133.6 111.0
2001 II 106.1 113.6 117.4 134.8 111.6
2001 III 106.7 114.2 118.5 136.0 112.2
2001 IV 107.3 114.7 119.6 137.3 112.8
Percentage changes
1997/96 1.3 1.5 3.2 8.6 3.2
1998/97 0.3 2.1 2.0 6.9 1.2
1999/98 -0.2 1.7 1.6 3.1 0.2
2000/99 2.4 3.9 3.2 3.5 3.0
2001/00 2.1 2.0 3.5 3.5 2.2
2002/01 2.3 2.0 3.8 3.8 2.1
1999IV/98IV 1.5 2.6 2.3 2.5 2.2
2000IV/99IV 2.2 3.0 3.5 3.5 3.0
2001IV/00IV 2.2 2.0 3.6 3.6 2.1
GDP [b]
Oil Rest Total Per Manufact-
worker uring pro-
ductivity [c]
(0.021) (0.202)
1996 105.6 102.8 102.5 101.5 99.0
1997 104.8 107.3 106.0 103.1 100.0
1998 107.5 109.6 108.5 104.0 99.6
1999 112.5 113.7 110.6 105.3 103.1
2000 116.1 116.7 114.0 107.7 108.0
2001 118.5 117.5 116.6 109.6 112.2
2002 120.9 118.6 119.4 111.9 116.5
1999 I 109.0 111.7 109.3 104.3 100.8
1999 II 112.3 113.6 110.2 104.8 102.0
1999 III 114.1 114.3 111.0 105.7 104.2
Forecast
1999 IV 114.7 115.4 112.0 106.3 105.4
2000 I 115.2 116.3 113.1 107.0 106.4
2000 II 115.8 116.7 113.7 107.4 107.5
2000 III 116.4 116.9 114.3 107.9 108.6
2000 IV 117.0 117.1 115.0 108.4 109.7
2001 I 117.6 117.2 115.6 108.9 110.7
2001 II 118.2 117.4 116.2 109.4 111.8
2001 III 118.8 117.6 116.9 109.9 113.0
2001 IV 119.4 117.9 117.6 110.2 113.3
Percentage changes
1997/96 -0.7 4.4 3.3 1.6 1.0
1998/97 2.6 2.2 2.4 0.9 -0.4
1999/98 4.7 3.8 2.0 1.2 3.5
2000/99 3.2 2.6 3.1 2.3 4.8
2001/00 2.0 0.7 2.2 1.8 3.9
2002/01 2.0 0.9 2.4 2.1 3.8
1999IV/98IV 5.0 4.6 2.7 2.1 5.4
2000IV/99IV 2.0 1.4 2.7 1.9 4.0
2001IV/00IV 2.0 0.7 2.3 1.7 3.3
Source: Economic Trends; Labour Market Trends; NIESR estimates.
(a.)1995 share of output in parentheses.
(b.)Gross value added at constant 1995 basic prices.
(c.)Including self-employment.
The UK labour market
Seasonally adjusted, millions
Employment, Unemployment,
thousands [a] thousands
Self
employ- ILO
ment Training defin-
Employees Total schemes ition
1996 22723 3626 418 26767 2334
1997 23260 3592 381 27233 2020
1998 23822 3487 339 27648 1818
1999 24129 3433 282 27844 1752
2000 24518 3301 250 28069 1688
2001 24744 3199 250 28193 1713
2002 24901 3113 250 28263 1746
1999 I 23998 3451 317 27766 1822
1999 II 24046 3479 318 27843 1760
1999 III 24179 3421 245 27845 1728
Forecast
1999 IV 24292 3380 250 27921 1697
2000 I 24414 3347 250 28011 1683
2000 II 24492 3315 250 28056 1683
2000 III 24555 3285 250 28090 1689
2000 IV 24612 3257 250 28119 1697
2001 I 24661 3232 250 28142 1706
2001 II 24707 3208 250 28165 1715
2001 III 24751 3186 250 28186 1723
2001 IV 24859 3172 250 28281 1707
Percentage changes
1997/96 2.4 -0.9 -8.7 1.7 -13.5
1998/97 2.4 -2.9 -11.2 1.5 -10.0
1999/98 1.3 -1.6 -16.6 0.7 -3.6
2000/99 1.6 -3.8 -11.6 0.8 -3.6
2001/00 0.9 -3.1 0.0 0.4 1.5
2002/01 0.6 -2.7 0.0 0.2 2.0
1999IV/98IV 1.4 -2.3 -22.1 0.7 -5.7
2000IV/99IV 1.3 -3.6 0.0 0.7 0.0
2001IV/001IV 1.0 -2.6 0.0 0.6 0.6
Participation,
thousands
Popul-
Civilian ation
Long- work- of work-
Claimant term [c] force [d] Inactive ing age
1996 2103 1135 29101 5899 35001
1997 1586 776 29253 5879 35131
1998 1347 585 29466 5793 35259
1999 1246 523 29596 5786 35381
2000 1180 484 29757 5748 35505
2001 1212 497 29906 5750 35656
2002 1249 512 30010 5782 35791
1999 I 1311 566 29588 5748 35337
1999 II 1282 539 29603 5764 35367
1999 III 1210 500 29573 5824 35396
Forecast
1999 IV 1180 485 29618 5806 35425
2000 I 1171 481 29694 5760 35453
2000 II 1174 482 29739 5743 35482
2000 III 1182 485 29779 5743 35522
2000 IV 1192 489 29816 5746 35561
2001 I 1202 493 29848 5753 35601
2001 II 1213 497 29880 5761 35640
2001 III 1222 501 29909 5766 35675
2001 IV 1210 496 29988 5721 35709
Percentage changes
1997/96 -24.6 -31.7 0.5 -0.4 0.4
1998/97 -15.1 -24.6 0.7 -1.5 0.4
1999/98 -7.5 -10.7 0.4 -0.1 0.3
2000/99 -5.3 -7.4 0.5 -0.7 0.3
2001/00 2.7 2.7 0.5 0.0 0.4
2002/01 3.1 3.1 0.3 0.5 0.4
1999IV/98IV -10.6 -20.5 0.3 0.6 0.3
2000IV/99IV 1.0 0.8 0.7 -1.0 0.4
2001IV/001IV 1.6 1.6 0.6 -0.4 0.4
Underutilisation % [b]
ILO Claim- Popul-
unem- ant un- ation
ploy- employ- not em-
ment ment ployed
rate rate rate
1996 8.0 7.3 23.5
1997 6.9 5.5 22.5
1998 6.2 4.6 21.6
1999 5.9 4.3 21.3
2000 5.7 4.0 20.9
2001 5.7 4.1 20.9
2002 5.8 4.2 21.0
1999 I 6.2 4.5 21.4
1999 II 5.9 4.4 21.3
1999 III 5.8 4.2 21.3
Forecast
1999 IV 5.7 4.1 21.2
2000 I 5.7 4.0 21.0
2000 II 5.7 4.0 20.9
2000 III 5.7 4.0 20.9
2000 IV 5.7 4.1 20.9
2001 I 5.7 4.1 21.0
2001 II 5.7 4.1 21.0
2001 III 5.8 4.2 21.0
2001 IV 5.7 4.1 20.8
Percentage changes
1997/96
1998/97
1999/98
2000/99
2001/00
2002/01
1999IV/98IV
2000IV/99IV
2001IV/001IV
Source: Economic Trends; Employment Gazette; NIESR estimates.
(a.) Includes self-employed, excludes HM Forces. Average figure per
quarter.
(b.) The ILO unemployment rate is expressed as a percentage of the
civilian workforce. The claimant unemployment rate is expressed as a
percentage of employment plus training schemes and claimant
unemployment. The population not employed is expressed as a percentage
of the population of working age.
(c.) Over six months.
(d.) Employment plus training schemes and ILO unemployment.
Price indices
Seasonally adjusted, 1995=100
Whole- Harmonised
Unit sale Consumer index of
labour Imports price price consumer
costs deflator index [b] index prices
1996 102.5 100.3 102.0 103.1 102.5
1997 106.0 93.6 102.2 105.7 104.4
1998 111.0 87.7 102.1 108.4 106.0
1999 116.1 85.6 101.7 111.1 107.4
2000 120.3 85.2 103.2 113.5 109.3
2001 124.2 86.9 105.2 116.3 111.5
2002 127.3 89.0 107.0 119.0 113.5
1999 I 115.1 86.1 101.7 110.0 106.5
1999 II 115.7 85.6 101.5 111.1 107.7
1999 III 116.1 85.5 101.6 111.2 107.4
Forecast
1999 IV 117.4 84.9 102.0 112.0 107.9
2000 I 118.4 84.9 102.4 112.6 108.0
2000 II 119.7 85.1 102.9 113.2 109.6
2000 III 120.9 85.3 103.4 113.8 109.6
2000 IV 122.0 85.7 103.9 114.5 109.8
2001 I 123.1 86.1 104.4 115.2 110.1
2001 II 123.7 86.6 104.9 116.0 111.9
2001 III 124.5 87.1 105.4 116.7 112.0
2001 IV 125.7 87.7 105.9 117.4 112.0
Percentage changes
1997/96 3.4 -6.7 0.2 2.5 1.8
1998/97 4.8 -6.3 -0.1 2.5 1.5
1999/98 4.6 -2.5 -0.4 2.5 1.3
2000/99 3.6 -0.4 1.4 2.2 1.8
2001/00 3.3 1.9 1.9 2.5 2.1
2002/01 2.4 2.4 1.7 2.3 1.8
1999IV/98IV 3.9 -1.2 0.2 2.2 1.2
2000IV/99IV 3.9 0.9 1.9 2.2 1.8
2001IV/00IV 3.1 2.4 1.9 2.5 1.9
Retail price index [a]
Excluding
mortgage GDP
Excluding interest & deflator
All mortgage indirect (basic
items interest taxes prices)
1996 102.4 103.0 102.6 103.4
1997 105.6 105.8 104.8 106.2
1998 109.3 108.6 107.0 109.1
1999 110.9 111.1 108.7 111.8
2000 115.3 113.7 110.0 114.7
2001 119.0 116.5 112.1 117.7
2002 121.4 119.1 114.4 120.4
1999 I 109.8 109.8 107.7 110.6
1999 II 111.0 111.3 108.8 111.8
1999 III 111.0 111.3 108.8 112.1
Forecast
1999 IV 111.8 112.0 109.6 112.9
2000 I 112.9 112.2 108.9 113.6
2000 II 115.6 114.0 110.1 114.3
2000 III 116.1 114.1 110.1 115.1
2000 IV 116.6 114.5 111.1 115.9
2001 I 117.2 114.9 110.6 116.6
2001 II 119.3 116.9 112.1 117.4
2001 III 119.6 117.1 112.3 118.1
2001 IV 119.9 117.1 113.4 118.8
Percentage changes
1997/96 3.1 2.8 2.2 2.7
1998/97 3.4 2.7 2.0 2.7
1999/98 1.5 2.3 1.6 2.5
2000/99 4.0 2.3 1.2 2.6
2001/00 3.2 2.5 1.9 2.6
2002/01 2.0 2.2 2.0 2.2
1999IV/98IV 1.4 2.2 1.7 2.5
2000IV/99IV 4.3 2.2 1.3 2.7
2001IV/00IV 2.8 2.3 2.1 2.5
GDP Manufac-
deflator turing
(market capacity
prices) utilisation
1996 103.3 98.8
1997 106.3 98.3
1998 109.7 98.2
1999 112.8 96.0
2000 116.2 97.1
2001 119.2 97.9
2002 121.8 98.6
1999 I 111.3 95.4
1999 II 112.6 95.5
1999 III 112.9 96.5
Forecast
1999 IV 114.3 96.6
2000 I 115.0 96.8
2000 II 115.8 97.0
2000 III 116.5 97.2
2000 IV 117.3 97.4
2001 I 118.1 97.6
2001 II 118.8 97.8
2001 III 119.5 98.0
2001 IV 120.2 98.2
Percentage changes
1997/96 2.9 -0.5
1998/97 3.2 -0.1
1999/98 2.9 -2.3
2000/99 3.0 1.2
2001/00 2.6 0.7
2002/01 2.2 0.8
1999IV/98IV 3.0 2.0
2000IV/99IV 2.6 0.9
2001IV/00IV 2.5 0.7
Source: Economic Trends; NIESR estimates.
(a.)Not seasonally adjusted.
(b.)Excluding food, drink, tobacco and petroleum.
National and sectoral savings
As a percentage of GDP
Household sector Company sector
Saving Investment Saving Investment
1996 6.7 4.2 12.3 11.2
1997 6.6 4.2 11.8 11.8
1998 4.2 4.2 12.0 12.7
Forecast
1999 4.2 4.3 9.8 12.5
2000 4.5 4.4 9.9 12.0
2001 4.3 4.5 9.9 11.8
2002 4.2 4.5 10.0 11.8
2003 4.1 4.4 10.2 11.8
Government Sector Whole economy Finance
from
Saving Investment Saving Investment Overseas
1996 -2.2 1.5 16.8 16.9 0.0
1997 -0.4 1.2 18.1 17.2 -0.9
1998 1.9 1.2 18.1 18.1 0.0
Forecast
1999 2.6 1.1 16.6 17.9 1.3
2000 2.1 1.4 16.5 17.9 1.6
2001 2.1 1.5 16.3 17.8 1.7
2002 2.3 1.7 16.5 17.9 1.6
2003 2.4 1.8 16.8 18.1 1.5
Residual
1996 0.1
1997 0.1
1998 0.0
Forecast
1999 0.0
2000 -0.2
2001 -0.2
2002 -0.2
2003 -0.2
Medium-term projections
Seasonally adjusted
1998 1999 2000 2001
Growth rate of expenditure and output (per cent)
Household spending 3.2 3.6 3.5 2.7
Government spending 0.7 3.7 4.6 2.4
Fixed investment 11.2 4.1 3.3 3.5
Exports of goods and
services 2.4 3.3 6.5 4.7
Imports of goods and
services 8.8 7.0 7.9 5.7
GDP at market prices 2.2 1.9 3.2 2.3
Manufacturing output 0.3 -0.2 2.4 2.1
Growth rate of costs and prices (per cent)
Average earnings 4.6 4.8 5.0 4.9
RPI 3.4 1.5 4.0 3.2
RPIX 2.7 2.3 2.3 2.5
Consumer price index 2.5 2.5 2.2 2.5
GDP deflator (basic prices) 2.7 2.5 2.6 2.6
Productivity growth 0.9 1.2 2.3 1.8
ILO unemployment rate 6.2 5.9 5.7 5.7
Manufacturing capacity
utlisation 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9
Base rates 7.2 5.3 6.3 6.5
Effective exchange rate 103.9 103.6 106.9 104.9
Current account
(as % of GDP) 0.0 1.3 1.6 1.7
PSNCR (as a % of GDP) -0.9 -0.9 -0.4 -0.2
Government debt
(as % of GDP) 48.4 45.2 42.0 39.7
2002 2003 2004 2005
Growth rate of expenditure and output (per cent)
Household spending 2.4 2.1 2.1 2.1
Government spending 2.4 2.4 2.3 2.0
Fixed investment 3.9 4.0 3.6 3.0
Exports of goods and
services 4.9 4.9 4.8 4.7
Imports of goods and
services 5.1 4.7 4.4 4.1
GDP at market prices 2.4 2.5 2.4 2.4
Manufacturing output 2.3 2.5 2.5 2.4
Growth rate of costs and prices (per cent)
Average earnings 4.3 4.2 3.8 3.6
RPI 2.0 1.8 1.9 1.9
RPIX 2.2 1.8 1.6 1.5
Consumer price index 2.3 1.9 1.6 1.5
GDP deflator (basic prices) 2.2 1.9 1.6 1.5
Productivity growth 2.1 2.5 2.4 2.3
ILO unemployment rate 5.8 6.0 6.1 6.2
Manufacturing capacity
utlisation 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9
Base rates 5.9 5.5 5.5 5.5
Effective exchange rate 103.5 102.9 103.1 103.2
Current account
(as % of GDP) 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.2
PSNCR (as a % of GDP) -0.2 -0.2 -0.1 -0.1
Government debt
(as % of GDP) 37.7 35.9 34.4 33.0
2006 2007 2008
Growth rate of expenditure and output (per cent)
Household spending 2.2 2.1 2.2
Government spending 2.0 2.0 2.0
Fixed investment 3.1 3.1 3.1
Exports of goods and
services 4.7 4.7 4.7
Imports of goods and
services 4.1 4.1 4.1
GDP at market prices 2.5 2.5 2.5
Manufacturing output 2.3 2.1 2.0
Growth rate of costs and prices (per cent)
Average earnings 3.8 4.1 4.5
RPI 2.0 2.2 2.5
RPIX 1.6 1.8 2.1
Consumer price index 1.6 1.9 2.2
GDP deflator (basic prices) 1.5 1.8 2.2
Productivity growth 2.3 2.2 2.1
ILO unemployment rate 6.3 6.3 6.3
Manufacturing capacity
utlisation 0.9 0.9 0.9
Base rates 5.5 5.5 5.5
Effective exchange rate 103.4 103.6 103.8
Current account
(as % of GDP) 1.0 0.7 0.5
PSNCR (as a % of GDP) -0.2 -0.3 -0.4
Government debt
(as % of GDP) 31.6 30.0 28.3
Average absolute errors, NIESR forecasts made in January/February [*]
All figures per cent unless otherwise indicate
Current year
Average error Error range
Real GDP growth 1.0 0.1 - 2.3
Domestic demand growth 1.1 0.2 - 2.2
Consumers expenditure growth 1.4 0.0 - 4.2
Investment growth 3.0 0.2 - 8.7
Export volume growth 2.4 0.5 - 4.5
Import volume growth 2.7 0.3 - 4.9
Real personal disposable income growth 1.5 0.2 - 4.0
Current account ([pounds]bn) 5.1 0.1 - 12.7
Public sector borrowing requirement 7.3 0.1 - 24.0
([pounds]bn) [a]
Retail price inflation (Q4) 1.1 0.3 - 2.7
Year ahead Average
outturn
Average error Error range 1982-98
Real GDP growth 1.4 0.1 - 3.2 2.6
Domestic demand growth 1.9 0.2 - 5.6 2.9
Consumers expenditure growth 2.0 0.0 - 5.9 3.0
Investment growth 4.1 0.1 - 12.6 4.2
Export volume growth 2.3 0.1 - 5.6 4.7
Import volume growth 3.9 0.1 - 10.5 6.0
Real personal disposable income growth 1.9 0.3 - 6.3 2.9
Current account ([pounds]bn) 7.1 0.0 - 20.4 -5.8
Public sector borrowing requirement 11.1 0.0 - 27.1 11.5
([pounds]bn) [a]
Retail price inflation (Q4) 1.8 0.4 - 5.1 4.5
(*.)All errors defined by subtracting the forecast from the outturns for
1982-98.
(a.)Financial year.
Probability distribution of growth and
inflation forecasts
Inflation: probability of 12 month RPIX
inflation falling in the following ranges
2000Q4 2001Q4
less than 1.5 per cent 29 36
1.5 to 2.5 per cent 30 18
2.5 to 3.5 per cent 25 16
more than 3.5 per cent 16 30
100 100
Growth: probability of annual growth rate
falling in the following ranges
2000 2001
less than 0 per cent - 11
0 to 1 per cent 2 14
1 to 2 per cent 12 21
2 to 3 per cent 32 21
3 to 4 per cent 36 17
more than 4 per cent 18 16
100 100
FISCAL REPORT
The public finances were transformed in the second half of the
1990s as the economy recovered from recession, a range of fiscal
measures were implemented and there was unexpected buoyancy in revenues
from existing taxes. The budget surplus that this produced looks set to
continue for a number of years, provided that the economy does not
suffer any major unfavourable shocks. Indeed, the underlying budgetary
position is sufficiently strong that it would take a serious adverse
macroeconomic shock to raise the deficit to threatening levels.
A slightly different concern is whether the government's tax
and spending plans are themselves feasible. The complaints of many
interest groups suggest that tight control of public spending has been
achieved by impoverishing those with limited market power. For example,
the pay of university lecturers has fallen substantially in relative
terms over the past twenty years, while linking the state pension to
prices rather than earnings has had a serious effect on its purchasing
power. The announcement in the Pre-Budget Report that fuel and tobacco
escalators would from now on be applied on a discretionary basis
indicated the extent to which certain measures are not enforceable,
especially when they are against the interests of strong lobbies.
Similar questions apply to the government's departmental spending
plans and whether they can provide the level of services that people
expect. A topical case in point is the National Health Service (NHS).
There is a widespread perception that the NHS is under-funded and
does not deliver the level of service that people expect. Comparative
figures [1] for 1997 indicate that overall health spending in the UK is
lower than in most other industrial countries. For example, national
healthcare expenditure in the UK (including both private and public
sector spending) is 6.8 per cent of GDP, compared with 13.9 per cent in
the US, 10.7 per cent in Germany, 9.6 per cent in France and 8.0 per
cent in the EU as a whole.
The Prime Minister (16 January) has pledged to raise health
spending in Britain substantially over the coming years, aiming for it
to reach the European average by 2005. This will involve a substantial
increase in public spending, over and above that which is already
committed. In this Fiscal Report, we first examine the state of the
public finances as they appear on the basis of existing plans. We then
look at the implications of extra spending on the NHS for both the
public finances and the national economy.
Table 1 sets out our forecasts of public sector spending, receipts
and borrowing on a financial year basis. Government spending decisions
for the years 1999-2000 to 2001-2 were set out in the Comprehensive
Spending Review (CSR). We have assumed that these plans are adhered to.
Total Managed Expenditure (TME), the sum of current and capital
spending, is set to grow by an annual average rate of 5 per cent over
the next three fiscal years. This is a real terms increase of 21/2 per
cent per annum when deflated by the GDP deflator which is expected by
the government to grow at 21/2 per cent per annum over this period (our
own forecast of the GDP deflator is shown in the table). Within this
total, net capital spending is due to double to around [pounds]10
billion in 2001-2. This is a substantial percentage rise, but from a
very low base.
Total managed expenditure is expected to remain below 39 per cent
of GDP over the next three years. The government's spending plans
beyond 2001-2 are to be determined in the next CSR. In the absence of
other information, our main forecast assumes no significant change from
the trends implicit in the plans already announced. In particular we
assume government consumption rises by 2 to 2 1/2 per cent per annum for
the following ten years.
Our forecast of government receipts is based on announced tax
rates, together with our expectations about the development of the tax
base. Receipts rose by about 1 1/2 per cent of GDP between 1996-7 and
1998-9, but are expected to remain at just over 39 per cent of GDP in
the current fiscal year. Table 2 sets out in more detail our forecasts
for the components of revenue as shares of nominal income. Our forecast
shows the share remaining at this level in 2000-1 before falling back
slightly. This level is high by recent historical standards, having
risen from 36 per cent in 1993. We do not expect company taxes to be as
buoyant over the next three or four years. Partly this reflects our
forecast of a slight fall in the profit share, and because companies
have sizeable capital allowances to offset against profits. With the
corporate tax rate being reduced and Advance Corporation Tax (ACT)
having being abolished there are also structural reasons for there being
some fall in company tax payments. Personal tax rece ipts are expected
to remain high at over 11 per cent of GDP, having risen from 10 per cent
as recently as 1997-8.
On this basis, the government's fiscal plans are expected to
be easily met. The current surplus is expected to rise from this
year's estimate of [pounds]10 billion to about [pounds]11 billion
in 200 1-2. The overall budget is not expected to go into deficit over
this period despite the assumed rise in capital investment. Public
sector net lending is expected to fall from [pounds]8.7 billion in the
current fiscal year to about balance in 2001-2.
The outlook for the public finances described here is very similar
to that shown in the Pre-Budget Report for the years to 2001-2. Beyond
that the PBR shows public sector borrowing rising, whereas we foresee the continuation of small overall surpluses. This may partly reflect the
cautiousassumption in the PBR that growth will be 21/4 per cent, despite
the Treasury's belief that trend growth is actually 21/2 per cent
per annum. These diverse projections reflect quite small differences in
assumed spending and receipts totals. Both forecasts agree that the
overall budget will not be more than 1/2 per cent of GDP away from
balance. The current surplus, the extent to which the Golden Rule is
met, is expected to be in surplus by over 1 per cent of GDP at least
until 2005-6.
With projected surpluses of this magnitude it would appear that
there is scope for the government to increase current spending by an
average of [pounds]17 billion between the years 2001-2 and 2005-6 while
still meeting the Golden Rule. Is this sufficient to meet the Prime
Minister's aspiration with respect to NHS spending?
According to the OECD Health Database, spending on health in the UK
in 1997 was 6.8 per cent of GDP. In addition to government spending on
the NHS, worth 41/2 per cent of GDP, this also includes other government
spending on health, private spending on medicines, other health products
and private health care. This is 1.2 per cent of GDP less than the EU
average. Thus, at minimum, it will be necessary to raise NHS spending by
the equivalent of 1.2 per cent of GDP to bring UK spending up to the
European average. To the extent that much private spending on health is
carried out because of the deficiencies of the NHS, it is possible that
the increase will have to be bigger to make up for some drop-off in
private spending. But ignoring this possibility suggests that NHS
spending would need to rise to about 53/4 per cent of GDP by 2005-6. At
today's prices, this is equivalent to [pounds]52 billion, compared
with actual NHS spending of [pounds]41 billion.
Existing government spending plans show that more resources are
already being committed to the NHS. The plans set out in the CSR show
NHS current spending rising from [pounds]36,916 million in 1998-9 to
[pounds]44,509 million in 2001-2.2 This represents an annual percentage
increase of 6.4 per cent in nominal terms and 3.9 per cent in real
terms. Over the same period, capital spending by the Health Department
and NHS trusts is set to grow from [pounds]1,010 million to
[pounds]2,285 million, an annual percentage increase of 31.3 per cent in
nominal terms and 28.8 per cent in real terms. But the total change
represents only a small increase as a share of national income. With
money GDP forecast to rise from [pounds]857 billion in 1998-9 to
[pounds]1014.1 billion in 2001-2, total NHS spending is rising from 4.5
per cent of GDP in 199 8-9 to 4.6 per cent of GDP in 2001-2.
Given these increases in NHS spending as a share of GDP that are
already planned as part of the CSR, how much extra spending is necessary
to reach a target of 53/4 per cent of GDP by 2005-6? According to our
forecast, nominal GDP will be [pounds]1,180 billion in 2005-6, 50 NHS
spending would need to be [pounds]68 billion to meet the target. It is
already planned to reach [pounds]46.8 billion by 2001-2 and would reach
[pounds]56.1 billion by 2005-6 if NHS spending were to grow in line with
government consumption generally. Clearly there is a gap of about
[pounds]12 billion. Assuming that there is little flexibility to
increase spending before 2001-2, spending would need to rise at an
annual average nominal rate of 10.7 per cent, or 8.2 per cent per annum
in real terms from 2002-3 to 2005-6 to reach the EU average. Simply
raising spending by 5 per cent per annum in real terms from next
financial year, as the Prime Minister has pledged, would not be
sufficient to reach the target over this period. This would rai se NHS
spending only to 5 1/4 per cent of GDP.
Our projections of the budget surplus on current account suggest
that there is scope within the existing budget to increase NHS spending
substantially and still meet the Golden Rule. To meet such a target, we
have assumed that the volume of government consumption and investment
grow more quickly than in the main forecast, with additional spending
assumed to be on the NHS. In particular, we have assumed that the volume
of government consumption grows at an annual rate of 3.8 per cent for
three years from the beginning of 2002-3 rather than an average rate of
21/2 per cent as in the main forecast. Public investment is also assumed
to grow more quickly. By 2005-6, public sector current and capital
spending is higher by around [pounds]10 billion at 1995 prices,
equivalent to [pounds]12.2 billion at the prices prevailing in 2005-6 in
our main forecast. In table 3 this is shown as an increase in current
spending on the NHS of [pounds]10.2 billion and extra capital spending
of [pounds]2.2 billion relative to what is assumed in the main forecast.
With no change in prices or output elsewhere in the economy, this would
reduce the current surplus in 2005-6 to [pounds]8.9 billion and raise
public sector net borrowing to [pounds]11 billion, just under 1 per cent
of GDP.
However, an increase in spending of this magnitude would have a
range of macroeconomic implications. [3] To assess this, we have re-run
our main forecast with these revised assumptions for government
consumption and investment. We have maintained the same assumptions for
other variables as in the main forecast. In particular, sterling is
assumed to be fixed against the euro from the end of 2003 at
[epsilon]1.51 and UK interest rates are set at euro levels from this
time. While there would be scope for some adjustment of monetary policy
before EMU entry, we assume that this does not occur. In the very long
term we have assumed that public spending growth slows down to the same
level as in the main forecast.
The fiscal expansion raises demand in the economy, raising
employment and output in the short term and so putting upward pressure
on prices. This has a major effect on government spending and receipts
in nominal terms. Table 3 indicates the effect of the changed policy on
the public finances. This shows that by 2005-6, total current spending
would be [pounds]460 billion, compared with [pounds]420 billion in the
main forecast. The difference of around [pounds]40 billion is
predominantly due to the effect of higher inflation raising the cost of
public services by about 7 per cent by 2005-6. Public expenditure as a
share of GDP rises by 1 percentage point. This is in line with the
increased spending target, but allows for the fact that some items of
spending, such as debt interest, are less affected. Higher prices and
higher economic activity generally also raise government receipts so
that the current surplus is reduced only by [pounds]4 billion deficit.
However, higher investment spending means that overall pu blic sector
net borrowing goes up by [pounds]10 billion to [pounds]9.5 billion.
The effect of the policy on the economy more widely is shown in
Chart 2. RPI inflation is raised by 1 per cent per annum during the time
that government consumption is raised and the level of prices is 8 per
cent higher by 2009. Apart from the adverse effect on inflation, the
other main cost to this policy is that manufacturing output is reduced
sharply relative to what it would otherwise have been. It is clear that
some cost must be borne if resources are to be shifted into the public
sector. The mechanism by which this comes about is that prices are bid
up, so worsening the competitiveness of the traded sector and leading to
a fall in output in that sector. This is also apparent in a worsening of
the current account of the balance of payments by about 1 per cent of
GDP.
Another adverse factor is that government debt rises relative to
the level it would have reached in the absence of extra spending. In the
base case, government indebtedness is falling and the extra spending
merely slows down this process. Nevertheless, debt as a share of GDP is
3 per cent of GDP higher than it would otherwise have been by 2009.
Gradually this process raises debt interest payments in a cumulative
process that needs eventually to be stabilised by some policy adjustment
unless the rate of interest is less than the growth rate. Here we have
assumed that the increase in real spending is not sustained for ever and
that the rise in the deficit to GDP ratio is restricted to about 1
percentage point.
An alternative perspective can be gained by considering the
inter-generational consequences of this policy. This can be quantified
using the National Institute's generational accounts model. [4]
This requires that sustained changes in spending are eventually financed
by higher taxes. Governments have a choice as to when these taxes are
raised. To pay for a sustained rise in spending of 1 per cent of GDP,
tax receipts would have to rise by the same amount if levied
immediately, but by more than this if the increase is delayed. The model
indicates that total tax receipts would have to rise by 3 per cent if
implemented at the same time as spending is increased, with larger
increases needed if they are deferred. These options have different
implications for different generations. The net present value of the
lifetime taxes paid by a person born today would rise by about
[pounds]2000. By contrast, the old benefit by the policy. Today's
60 year-olds would gain approximately [pounds]5000 of lifetime
resources.
Another risk to the policy is that economic circumstances turn out
to be different from what we are now expecting. There is a vast range of
shocks that might hit the economy over the next decade, and not all of
these are bad. Nevetheless, in order to explore the risks of this
policy, we have added some shocks to world demand, consumer demand and
technological change such that the growth rate turns out to be about a
percentage point lower than we are currently forecasting. Clearly this
is significantly worse than the main case scenario, but not the worst
possible case. Chart 4 shows the effect on the public finances. The
deficit now reaches 31/2 per cent of GDP by 2010 and the debt stock
rises to 40 per cent of GDP, 14 percentage points above the main case.
This is only one example of the risks that the economy faces over
the next ten years. Even if the economy behaves broadly as expected,
substantial risks surround forecasts of the budgetary position.
Recently, the public finances have been much stronger than forecast as
income tax receipts have been surprisingly buoyant. There is every
chance that the public finances will suffer shocks in the opposite
direction in the next few years, in which case, extra spending of the
type considered here will turn out to be much less affordable than it
appears at present.
Summary and conclusions
The outlook for the public finances described here on the basis of
the government's existing spending plans is enviable. Spending
control has benefited from the excellent economic background as low
interest rates have reduced the government's debt interest bill and
high employment has contributed to savings on a range of social
benefits.
Total spending has now fallen below 40 per cent of GDP and is
expected to remain low despite a surge in government consumption and
capital investment.
With spending under control, the budgetary position is expected to
benefit from a period of sustained economic growth. This is projected to
generate sufficient income that the surplus on the current budget will
be above [pounds] 10 billion per annum over the next three years, with
prospects of bigger surpluses in the years beyond.
There are basically three ways in which such surpluses can be used.
First, they can be used to pay off debt. The public sector balance sheet
worsened dramatically in the early 1990s and there is a respectable case
to be made that the surpluses be used to replenish the balance sheet
now. With an ageing population, public sector saving now is likely to
find many uses in the future. However, the government's commitment
to the Golden Rule implies that it is comfortable with the overall state
of its balance sheet and has no wish to save up now for spending in the
future. The second possible use of the surpluses is to cut taxes. Medium
term current surpluses of around 1 per cent of GDP could be used to cut
the basic rate of income tax by 3p in the pound and the top rate by 5p
in the pound. Alternatively they could be used to make radical changes
to the personal income tax system so as to eliminate the tax liability
of the lowest paid altogether.
The third possible use of the surpluses is to raise spending.
Inevitably, projected surpluses of the size shown here create
expectations of further spending, especially when there is widespread
dissatisfaction with the existing provision of public sector services.
Although the government has stressed that education is its priority,
there is no shortage of competition for more resources, as demonstrated
by the Prime Minister's commitment of more spending on the NHS.
Our analysis of the Prime Minister's aspiration to raise
health spending in the UK to the European average shows that it appears
to be affordable within the existing budget with no need for higher
taxation to fund it. In effect, the unexpectedly high levels of tax
receipts seen recently would be used to fund extra NHS spending. Rather
than seeing a current surplus of [pounds] 19 billion and an overall
surplus of [pounds] 1.5 billion in 2005-6, the current surplus would be
reduced to [pounds] 15 billion and an overall deficit of [pounds] 9.5
billion would emerge when spending is raised by 1 per cent of GDP to
improve the health service. These figures are affected by the extra
economic activity and higher prices that would result from extra public
spending.
Not only can the Prime Minister's pledge be met, but there
would still be room within the current budget for additional spending on
other priorities. However, it would be wrong to suggest that it could be
achieved without cost. First, when there is little spare capacity in the
economy, the health service can only have more resources if other
activities have less. While extra public spending will raise economic
activity and output in the short term, in the longer term it will crowd
out other activity. The traded sector, especially manufacturing, would
be most adversely affected. In our analysis, manufacturing output would
be 2 per cent lower than it would otherwise have been by 2006 as a
consequence of higher public spending. Prices will also be raised, with
inflation about 1 per cent higher than otherwise for a number of years.
Second, extra spending on health or other public activities must
ultimately be financed by taxation higher than it would otherwise have
been. In the present case, the choice appears to be between more
spending and foregone tax cuts rather than actual tax increases. This
also transfers resources between the generations. Our figures suggest
that extra health spending of 1 per cent of GDP would benefit 60
year-olds by the equivalent of a lump sum of [pounds] 5000 and penalise those just born by [pounds] 2000. The young would have to forgo the
benefits of tax cuts to pay for extra health spending which mainly
benefits the old. Third, there are costs that would arise if the public
finances turn out to be in worse shape than we think. Relatively small
changes in the economic outlook or in tax yields can change the outlook
significantly. One of the main problems with the new system of setting
spending plans for three-year periods is that it allows very little
flexibility to change course when the unexpected occurs. As a
consequence, it may be difficult to reverse any extra spending granted
at a time when the outlook is favourable and this in turn could lead to
a return to very large deficits or e mergency tax increases in the
future.
Nevertheless, policy cannot always be set in fear of the worst. The
current outlook for the economy generally and for the public finances is
good. If the Prime Minister wants to commit more resources to the health
service, then this appears to be affordable within the existing budget.
Notes
(1.) Source: OECD Health Data 1999. Figures for 1997. Reported in
Financial Times, January 15/16, 2000.
(2.) Source: Public Expenditure 1999-2000. HM Treasury. March,
1999.
(3.) See Church et al. on page 107 of this Review for an
explanation of their effects in a range of different models.
(4.) Cardarelli, R., Sefton,J. and Kotlikoff, L.J. (1999),
'Generational accounting in the UK', NIESR Discussion paper
no. 147, www.generationalaccounting.com.
Public sector financial balance and borrowing requirement
[pounds] billion, fiscal years
1999-00 2000-1 2001-2
Current expenditure: Goods and services 166.0 177.6 186.6
Net social benefits paid 111.7 118.0 122.8
Debt interest 29.9 28.8 27.7
Subsidies 5.3 5.6 5.9
Other current expenditure 16.5 15.9 19.0
Total 329.4 346.0 362.0
Gross investment 20.4 22.5 25.4
Net investment 6.2 7.6 10.1
Total managed expenditure 349.7 368.5 387.4
(As a % of GDP) 38.7 38.6 38.2
Memo items: GDP deflator at
market prices 113.7 116.9 119.9
Money GDP 903.6 955.4 1014.1
Current receipts: Taxes on income and oil royalties 146.2 152.7 153.8
Taxes on expenditure 129.9 139.4 148.5
Social security contributions 67.7 72.2 73.6
Gross operating surplus 13.3 14.3 14.8
Other current receipts -3.7 -4.7 -2.9
Total current receipts 353.4 373.8 387.8
Public sector current balance 9.9 12.9 10.5
Public sector net borrowing -8.7 -5.3 -0.4
Financial transactions -4.0 0.0 0.0
Public sector net cash requirement -4.8 -5.3 -0.4
(As a % of GDP) -0.5 -0.6 0.0
Memo items (calendar years, per cent of GDP)
Govt deficit under Maastricht -1.1 -0.2 0.0
Govt debt under Maastricht 45.2 42.0 39.7
2002-3 2003-4 2004-5
Current expenditure: Goods and services 195.1 203.2 210.7
Net social benefits paid 127.9 133.5 139.6
Debt interest 26.8 25.9 25.2
Subsidies 6.2 6.5 6.7
Other current expenditure 23.0 24.0 24.9
Total 378.9 393.1 407.2
Gross investment 27.8 31.4 33.5
Net investment 12.2 15.4 17.1
Total managed expenditure 406.7 424.5 440.7
(As a % of GDP) 38.8 38.8 38.8
Memo items: GDP deflator at
market prices 122.4 124.5 126.4
Money GDP 1048.3 1093.0 1136.3
Current receipts: Taxes on income and oil royalties 163.0 169.5 175.6
Taxes on expenditure 155.4 161.7 167.7
Social security contributions 77.1 80.6 83.9
Gross operating surplus 15.1 15.4 15.8
Other current receipts -0.9 -1.0 -1.5
Total current receipts 409.6 426.2 441.5
Public sector current balance 15.1 17.1 17.9
Public sector net borrowing -2.9 -1.7 -0.8
Financial transactions 0.0 0.0 0.0
Public sector net cash requirement -2.9 -1.7 -0.8
(As a % of GDP) -0.3 -0.2 -0.1
Memo items (calendar years, per cent of GDP)
Govt deficit under Maastricht -0.1 -0.1 0.1
Govt debt under Maastricht 37.7 35.9 34.4
2005-6
Current expenditure: Goods and services 218.0
Net social benefits paid 145.4
Debt interest 24.6
Subsidies 7.0
Other current expenditure 25.9
Total 420.9
Gross investment 34.5
Net investment 17.6
Total managed expenditure 455.4
(As a % of GDP) 38.6
Memo items: GDP deflator at
market prices 128.2
Money GDP 1180.3
Current receipts: Taxes on income and oil royalties 181.7
Taxes on expenditure 174.0
Social security contributions 87.3
Gross operating surplus 16.2
Other current receipts -2.4
Total current receipts 456.9
Public sector current balance 19.1
Public sector net borrowing -1.5
Financial transactions 0.0
Public sector net cash requirement -1.5
(As a % of GDP) -0.1
Memo items (calendar years, per cent of GDP)
Govt deficit under Maastricht 0.0
Govt debt under Maastricht 33.0
Note: Public sector current balance is total current
receipts less total current expenditure and depreciation.
Depreciation is the difference between
gross and net investment.
Public sector receipts
% GDP
1996-7 1997-8 1998-9 1999-00 2000-1 2001-2
Taxes on company income 3.2 4.0 3.8 3.3 2.4 2.3
Personal income tax 10.2 10.0 10.9 11.2 11.9 11.3
Council tax 1.3 1.3 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.4
Taxes on income 14.9 15.4 16.3 16.2 16.0 15.3
VAT receipts 6.1 6.2 6.1 6.4 6.5 6.5
Other indirect taxes 7.7 7.8 8.0 7.9 8.1 8.3
Taxes on expenditure 13.8 14.0 14.1 14.4 14.6 14.8
Social security contributions 7.4 7.6 7.7 7.5 7.6 7.3
Gross operating surplus 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5 1.5
Other receipts -0.1 -0.1 -0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.3
As a share of GDP 37.6 38.4 39.2 39.1 39.1 38.7
2002-3 2003-4 2004-5 2005-6
Taxes on company income 2.5 2.5 2.4 2.4
Personal income tax 11.3 11.4 11.4 11.4
Council tax 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.4
Taxes on income 15.5 15.5 15.4 15.4
VAT receipts 6.5 6.5 6.5 6.4
Other indirect taxes 8.3 8.3 8.3 8.3
Taxes on expenditure 14.8 14.8 14.8 14.7
Social security contributions 7.4 7.4 7.4 7.4
Gross operating surplus 1.4 1.4 1.4 1.4
Other receipts -0.1 -0.1 -0.1 -0.2
As a share of GDP 39.1 39.0 38.9 38.7
NHS spending
[pounds] billion, fiscal years
1999-00 2000-01 2001-02
NHS spending plans CSR
Current 39.2 41.9 44.5
Capital 1.6 1.9 2.3
Total 40.8 43.8 46.8
(As a % of money GDP) 4.5 4.6 4.6
With 5% real growth from 1999-2000 40.8 44.0 47.4
(As of % of money GDP) 4.5 4.6 4.7
With extra 1% of GDP by 2005-06 40.8 43.8 46.8
Ex-ante budgetary effects of attempt to
raise spending by 1% of GDP
Additional spending on goods and services
Additional spending on gross investment
Revised current balance
Revised PSNB:
Revised public finance forecast incorporating
raised NHS spending
Current expenditure Goods and services 166.0 177.7 188.5
Net social benefits paid 111.7 118.0 123.3
Debt interest 29.9 28.8 27.6
Subsidies 5.3 5.6 6.0
Other current expenditure 16.5 15.8 16.7
Total 329.4 346.0 362.0
Gross investment 20.4 22.5 25.4
Net investment 6.2 7.6 9.9
Total managed expenditure 349.7 368.5 387.4
(As a % of GDP) 38.7 38.5 38.2
Memo items: GDP deflator at
market prices 113.7 117.0 121.1
Money GDP 903.6 956.2 1014.3
Current receipts: Taxes on income and oil
royalties 146.2 152.8 155.9
Taxes on expenditure 129.9 139.6 150.3
Social security contributions 67.7 72.2 74.5
Gross operating surplus 13.3 14.3 14.8
Other current receipts -3.7 -4.8 -5.8
Total current receipts 353.4 374.0 389.7
Public sector current balance 9.85 13.1 12.21
Public sector net borrowing -8.7 -5.5 -2.3
Financial transactions -4.0 0.0 0.0
Public sector net cash requirement -4.8 -5.5 -2.3
(As a % of GDP) -0.5 -0.6 -0.2
Govt deficit under Maastricht -1.1 -0.2 -0.02
Govt debt under Maastricht 45.2 42.0 39.2
2002-03 2003-04 2004-05
NHS spending plans projections
Current 46.5 48.5 50.4
Capital 2.6 2.9 3.2
Total 49.1 51.4 53.7
(As a % of money GDP) 4.7 4.7 4.7
With 5% real growth from 1999-2000 50.8 54.3 57.9
(As of % of money GDP) 4.8 5.0 5.1
With extra 1% of GDP by 2005-06 50.9 56.2 63.7
Ex-ante budgetary effects of attempt to 4.9 5.1 5.6
raise spending by 1% of GDP
Additional spending on goods and services +1.7 +4.7 +8.4
Additional spending on gross investment +0.1 +0.1 +1.6
Revised current balance 13.4 12.4 9.5
Revised PSNB: -1.1 3.1 9.2
Revised public finance forecast incorporating
raised NHS spending
Current expenditure Goods and services 201.8 216.5 231.6
Net social benefits paid 130.0 137.7 146.1
Debt interest 26.5 25.6 25.1
Subsidies 6.3 6.7 7.1
Other current expenditure 23.6 25.0 26.5
Total 388.3 411.5 436.3
Gross investment 28.3 32.5 37.3
Net investment 12.3 15.8 19.9
Total managed expenditure 416.6 444.1 473.7
(As a % of GDP) 38.7 38.9 39.3
Memo items: GDP deflator at
market prices 125.4 129.4 133.3
Money GDP 1077.6 1141.9 1206.3
Current receipts: Taxes on income and oil
royalties 167.9 177.7 187.2
Tax on expenditure 159.5 168.3 176.9
Social security contributions 79.5 84.5 89.7
Gross operating surplus 15.4 16.0 16.7
Other current receipts -1.3 -1.6 -1.7
Total current receipts 421.0 445.0 468.8
Public sector current balance 16.6 16.8 15.1
Public sector net borrowing -4.4 -0.9 4.9
Financial transactions 0.0 0.0 0.0
Public sector net cash requirement -4.4 -0.09 4.9
(As a % of GDP) -0.4 -0.1 0.4
Govt deficit under Maastricht -0.3 0.0 0.4
Govt debt under Maastricht 36.5 34.1 32.3
2005-06
NHS spending plans
Current 52.4
Capital 3.6
Total 56.1
(As a % of money GDP) 4.8
With 5% real growth from 1999-2000 61.7
(As of % of money GDP) 5.2
With extra 1% of GDP by 2005-06 68.3
Ex-ante budgetary effects of attempt to 5.8
raise spending by 1% of GDP
Additional spending on goods and services +10.2
Additional spending on gross investment +2.2
Revised current balance 8.9
Revised PSNB: 10.9
Revised public finance forecast incorporating
raised NHS spending
Current expenditure Goods and services 244.3
Net social benefits paid 154.2
Debt interest 25.0
Subsidies 7.4
Other current expenditure 27.8
Total 458.7
Gross investment 42.8
Net investment 24.6
Total managed expenditure 501.5
(As a % of GDP) 39.6
Memo items: GDP deflator at
market prices 136.8
Money GDP 1267.6
Current receipts: Taxes on income and oil
royalties 196.1
Tax on expenditure 185.4
Social security contributions 94.6
Gross operating surplus 17.4
Other current receipts -1.5
Total current receipts 492.0
Public sector current balance 15.1
Public sector net borrowing 9.5
Financial transactions 0.0
Public sector net cash requirement 9.5
(As a % of GDP) 0.7
Govt deficit under Maastricht 0.8
Govt debt under Maastricht 31.2
(*.)The forecast was compiled using the latest version of the
National Institute Domestic Econometric Model. I am grateful to Ray
Barrell, Richard Kneller, Nigel Pain, Rebecca Riley and Martin Weale for
comment and discussion.
AT A GLANCE
The UK economy
* The economy will grow by 3.2 per cent in 2000 and 2.3 per cent in
2001.
* Manufacturing will enjoy its best year since 1994, with output
expanding by 2.4 per cent in 2000.
* Inflation will stay just below the government's 2.5 per cent
target in 2000 and 2001.
* The current account deficit will widen to [pounds]17 billion in
2001.
* The Prime Minister's new objective to raise health spending
as a proportion of GDP to the EU average by 2005 can be met without
breaking the golden rule.
The economy is poised to grow strongly in 2000, powered by a brisk increase in domestic demand and a recovery in exports. The swift return
to buoyant economic conditions will push wage earnings growth to 5 per
cent. However, a rise in productivity growth, the strong pound and
rising competitive pressures in retail markets will keep inflation at
bay over the next two years. The inflation target can be met with a rise
in base rates to 6.5 per cent.
Domestic demand will rise by almost 4 per cent in 2000, somewhat
faster than in 1999. Household spending will grow at 3.5 per cent,
sustained by a healthy increase in real household disposable income and
the 50 per cent rise in household wealth since 1996. The drag from net
trade will be considerably less than in 1999, as exports stage a
recovery. Exports will increase by 6.5 per cent in 2000, double their
annual rate of growth in 1998 and 1999. Exporting firms will benefit
from the upturn in trade as the world economy picks up speed.
With economic growth above trend, the labour market will tighten
still further and average earnings growth will pick up to 5 per cent.
However, a rise in productivity growth should contain annual unit labour
cost growth to around 3.5 per cent over the next two years. With
continuing import price deflation in 2000 and keener price competition
in the retailing sector, this should be compatible with the inflation
target, but only with falling profit margins.
The medium-term outlook for the public finances is sufficiently
favourable to make affordable the Prime Minister's new objective
for health spending. On existing plans, we project a current account
surplus of [pound]19 billion by 2005/6. If health spending were to rise
by then to the EU average of 8 per cent of GDP, this would involve extra
expenditure of [pound]12 billion, so that the new goal can be attained without breaching the golden rule.
But the fiscal boost will push up annual inflation by almost 1 per
cent from 2001. GDP will be higher but the exporting sector of the
economy will suffer. And, taking into account the demographic structure
of the population, income tax revenues need to be 13 per cent higher
than would otherwise be the case in order to pay for the increase in
health spending. Given our budgetary projections this does not
necessarily mean that taxes need to rise, but it would leave standard
rate tax almost 3p and higher rate tax 5p higher than they would be
without the increased health spending.