COMMENTARY.
Barrell, Ray ; Weale, Martin ; Young, Garry 等
The debate over the euro
The main macroeconomic debate over the past few months has
concerned the euro and the question whether and when Britain should join
the European Monetary Union. Related to this is the concern people feel
over the current level of the exchange rate. We present a summary of a
meeting that the National Institute held on this important issue on page
8 of this Review.
Inevitably the debate on monetary union focuses on the five
questions drawn up by the Government in October 1997. The five questions
are [1]
1. Would joining EMU create better conditions for firms making
long-term decisions to invest in the United Kingdom?
2. How would adopting the single currency affect our financial
services?
3. Are business cycles and economic structures compatible so that
we and others in Europe could live comfortably with euro interest rates
on a permanent basis?
4. If problems do emerge, is there sufficient flexibility to deal
with them?
5. Will joining EMU help to promote higher growth, stability and a
lasting increase in jobs?
and the Government has said that it intends to hold a referendum on
membership of the monetary union once it is clear that the five
questions can be answered favourably.
There is an obvious difficulty with these questions. While the
government is looking for affirmative answers to questions 1, 3, 4 and 5
and an answer of 'favourably' to question 2, it says neither
how it proposes to answer the questions nor what degree of confidence it
requires in its answers. To accept answers on a balance of probabilities
could lead to membership in a fairly short time, while to require
positive answers beyond all reasonable doubt would be a recipe for never
joining. The absence of any real information on the basis for reaching a
decision means, in turn, that it is difficult for commentators to assess
how close the questions are to receiving the answers needed for
membership. However, the nature of economic research and its capacity to
answer questions means that, if the questions are to be of any use, then
the answers have to be accepted on the balance of probabilities. The
following discussion should be read with that in mind.
Investment decisions
The first question can be read with particular reference to foreign
investment but also in the context of the overall business environment.
A range of studies by the National Institute suggests that the answer to
the first question is yes, in that a part of the foreign investment in
Britain appears to take place because Britain offers a gateway to the
European Union. If the United Kingdom remains outside the monetary
union, then other countries are likely to offer a more attractive
gateway. The profitability of foreign investment in Britain will be
affected by changes to the value of the euro altering costs set in
sterling relative to sales prices fixed in euros; this may deter foreign
investment in Britain. These findings are not contradicted by the fact
that foreign investment in Britain reached an all-time peak last year.
When those investment plans were struck there were certainly many people
who believed that Britain would be a late entrant rather than a
permanent non-participant.
The more general question concerns the overall business
environment. A recent study from the National Institute (Barrell and
Dury, 2000) suggests that, inside the monetary union, Britain will face
an inflation rate which is less volatile and a level of output which is
more volatile than those we have at present. We expect such
circumstances to be more favourable for firms investing in the UK
because inflation volatility leads to prices becoming increasingly
uncertain in the indefinite future while output uncertainty has only
short-term effects. We are not at present able to quantify the
importance of such effects but they provide a focus for the discussion
which should also take into account the fact that an active fiscal
policy could be used to mitigate the increased volatility of output.
Financial services
The second question is usually interpreted as how would joining
affect our financial services industry rather than the nature of
financial services supplied to end users. One can think of all sorts of
reasons why, if the UK decides not to join the monetary union, the
financial services industry will gradually ebb away to the continent.
There is only one obvious reason why membership would have an adverse
effect on our financial services industry. That would be if the monetary
union imposed uniform regulations, such as minimum reserve requirements,
on all banking operations in the union. Such arrangements amount to a
tax on the banking system and, whatever the fiscal equity of these
arrangements, they would lead to banking moving to places where there
are no reserve requirements. The skill with which Mr Brown fought off
similarly damaging proposals for a witholding tax on interest payments
suggests it would also be possible to resist this, at least if Britain
seems likely to join the monetary union at an early stage. Obviously it
would be much harder if Britain were to join after minimum reserve
requirements were already in place. But without such a system, it is
difficult to see why membership should worsen the position of the
financial services industry. In terms of financial services themselves,
it is to be hoped that eventually it will be possible to pay in a cheque
drawn on a German bank in London as easily as that can already be done
with a cheque drawn on a Scottish bank; this is unlikely to happen if
Britain stays outside the monetary union.
Cyclical compatibility and the entry rate
The remaining questions are rather harder to address precisely.
Much has been made of a recent report by OECD (2000) suggesting that
next year Britain's 'output gap', the difference between
actual output and long-term sustainable output, will be close to that of
the Euro Area as a whole and less that than of some of the existing
members of the Euro Area. On this basis then, Britain's economic
cycle has converged with that of the Euro Area. One can reasonably ask
what will happen beyond next year, but the truth is that, given the
uncertainty associated with economic forecasts for two years ahead, it
is very difficult to say. There is no basis for saying that Britain is
bound to diverge again (like two ships passing in opposite directions)
any more than there is any reason to say that Britain's cycle will
remain coordinated with that of the Euro Area. In any case, the degree
of cyclical cohesion of the Euro Area has increased over the last five
years or so, and one would expect that, if Britain joins the moneta ry
union, that in itself will promote cyclical cohesion.
A much greater worry is the fact that the convergence observed by
OECD has been achieved with short-term interest rates which are much
higher than those of the Euro Area and with an exchange rate many people
regard as high. One ground for concern about the exchange rate (Barrell
and Pain, 1998) lies outside the scope of our existing economic models.
The current level of the exchange rate may have the effect of
discouraging the inflow of foreign investment over and above the effects
of exchange rate volatility discussed earlier. There is no reason why
this should affect employment, but, because foreign investment has been
a factor helping productivity growth, it may, in the end, lead to a
lower level of productivity and thus a lower income level than might
otherwise be achieved.
This aside, one can ask whether there are any more traditional
signs of an overvaluation. Conventionally it would be argued that a high
real exchange rate would be associated with either a depressed economy
or one that was propped up by a large budget deficit. A budget deficit
would be associated with a balance of payments deficit. Neither of these
would be sustainable in the long run, because an increasing deficit
results in increasing interest payments. In the end, without some
corrective action, the consequences of cumulated interest payments would
create a situation where there was no obvious means of servicing
external or public debt.
The British economy does not show these characteristics. It is not
depressed and, far from there being a budget deficit, there is a large
budget surplus. There is, it is true, an external deficit but, at about
1 1/4 per cent of GDP it is not likely to become unsustainable for many
years. In the light of this, why might one believe that the exchange
rate is too high?
We can identify two concerns. First of all, the effects of the
exchange rate may be larger and take longer to appear than our model
suggests. If this is the case the exchange rate will start to have an
undesirably depressing effect on the economy. Secondly we note that high
exchange rates may be associated with and can be caused by low levels of
saving. Private sector gross saving has fallen from 18 per cent of GDP
in 1997 to 13.4 per cent of GDP last year, although the rise in public
saving means that the fall in national saving from 17.7 per cent to 16.2
per cent of GDP is much smaller. A full recovery of private saving,
rather than the more modest rise we expect, would be likely at
today's exchange rate to lead to a budget deficit and a period of
slow growth. Thus, in either of these cases, it could turn out that the
exchange rate is much too high, as it seemed to be in the early 1990s.
There is, however, an important difference from the situation in
the early 1990s. Then the high exchange rate was combined with high
interest rates, while now the Euro Area has low interest rates. This
means that, if Britain were to join the euro today at the current
exchange rate, the result would be an expansionary stimulus. The effect
would be all the greater if we were to join at a lower exchange rate.
This expansion might well lead to renewed inflation which would drive
the real exchange up.
Our forecast draws attention to another factor in addition to the
level of interest rates which leads us to think the exchange rate is not
badly overvalued. Productivity growth has been slow since 1995, although
manufacturing productivity growth accelerated last year. We regard this
low productivity growth as a counterpart of the rise in employment;
people with low productivity were taken into the labour force,
depressing the overall rate of productivity growth. In the nature of
things, as the newly employed gain experience of work, their
productivity is likely to rise. We expect the British economy to start
to benefit from this process in the years ahead. This will generate, for
the next five years or so, productivity growth rates which are closer to
3 per cent per annum than to the traditional 2 per cent per annum and
will go some way to restoring the competitiveness of the British
economy. This small-scale productivity miracle makes it possible to
consider joining the Euro Area at the exchange rate of [pou nd]1 =
[epsilon]1.55, as set out in our forecast, despite the fact that this
seems high compared with past experience.
Flexibility
The question whether the monetary union will be able to cope with
problems as they arise cannot easily be answered by direct observation
if the country wants to be able to join in reasonable time. But perhaps
it is reasonable to observe that most members of the monetary union
have, for the last forty years, done better than the United Kingdom at
coping with economic problems. To the extent that the question amounts
to whether the UK is able to deal with shocks which affect mainly the UK
it becomes necessary to ask what arrangements HM Treasury is making. A
part of the flexibility required to deal with shocks can be provided by
the sort of flexible fiscal policy to which we have alluded earlier.
This might be needed if, for example, UK labour markets are more
responsive to changes in the economic environment than are those
elsewhere. There are many instruments available to the Chancellor for
this purpose. For example, the 1961 Finance Act allows him to adjust
some taxes in the same way that the Monetary Policy Committee now
adjusts the interest rate.
Growth, stability and jobs
The last question suggests an air of confusion. The level of
employment is determined by the working of the labour market and its
interaction with the social security system. A lasting increase in jobs
requires a lasting increase in incentives to work or permanent removal
of obstacles to employing new staff. One might construct an argument
that long-run employment would be adversely affected by very rapid
inflation, or inflation volatility and in that sense the matter is
related to the question of stability. The latter cannot be answered
without raising the question stability of what?
We have already noted that we expect EMU membership to lead to a
more stable inflation rate and that fiscal policy could be used to deal
with the greater output volatility which might emerge. The favourable
impact we expect this to have on investment is also more likely to be
helpful than unhelpful for economic growth. Insofar as the question can
be answered, our analysis suggests that EMU membership will be
favourable for the economy, but it would be foolish to argue that it is
bound to lead to a further reduction of unemployment or increase in
economic growth.
The fiscal position and the Comprehensive Spending Review
Looking at more immediate issues, the Government recently announced
its spending plans in a new Comprehensive Spending Review. The overall
totals have not changed very much since those announced in the Budget,
although it has become apparent that spending was lower than planned
last year, and a part of this is to be 'made up' by increasing
the spending this year and next year. However, within the total managed
expenditure debt interest is expected to be lower, mainly because the
government has received [pound]22 billion from auctioning the broad band
spectrum. This is to be used to repay debt, saving [pound]1 billion per
year of interest payments. There have been a number of other minor
reallocations, with the result that, within the overall figures for
total managed expenditure, expenditure on goods and services will rise
at the expense of interest and transfer payments.
The Spending Review does not discuss tax revenues. These, however,
continue to be buoyant. If oil prices stay close to current levels and
if revenues from other taxes remain high, then the fiscal position is
likely to be more favourable than the Government's budget
projection suggested. Our own projection is still more favourable
because we expect growth to be faster than the rate of 2 1/4 per cent
assumed in the Government's calculations, resulting in still higher
tax receipts. We expect the public sector current balance to remain at
about [pound]20 billion, with rising levels of net investment reducing
public sector financial saving from around [pound]10 billion in the
current year to close to zero in 2003-4 with small deficits emerging
beyond then. The precise figures for public borrowing depend on the way
in which the proceeds from the broad band auction are described. The
appropriate accounting treatment of this is discussed on page 40. It is
worth noting here that, because the licences are valid for onl y twenty
years rather than for ever, the overall impact on income is considerably
larger than the saving on interest payments alone.
The economic outlook
In large part because of the prospective favourable productivity
growth mentioned above, our forecast suggests that the British economy
is set for a period of stable and relatively rapid growth. We expect
growth at over 3 per cent per annum both this year and next. Although
earnings growth is likely to accelerate, the faster productivity growth
makes this consistent with the in-flation target. We see an interest
rate peak of 6 1/2 per cent per annum reached next year to be followed
by gradual convergence with Euro Area rates. Our interpretation (see
page 13) of financial market prices is that markets are now expecting
the UK to join the euro at around [pound]1 = [epsilon]1.55 with the rate
stable from 2002 as a prelude to entry; as noted above, we have used
this in our projection. If this increase in productivity growth does not
materialise, then the economy will face more acute problems (see page
15). In particular, the rise in productivity is important in restraining unit labour costs while the exchange rat e falls modestly from current
levels. If productivity does not grow as hoped, we expect inflationary
pressures to be greater, resulting in a further increase in interest
rates.
The favourable outlook is, however, conditional on a second
important factor in addition to an improvement in productivity. We
forecast a gradual recovery of the household savings ratio from the low
value of 3.8 per cent of income in the first quarter of this year to an
average of 6 per cent in 2002. This in turn im-plies that consumption
growth will be relatively restrained. If the savings ratio does not
recover, then the inflationary pressures in the economy will become more
acute and the Monetary Policy Committee will be likely to raise interest
rates above the 6 1/2 per cent per annum we have assumed. Similarly, of
course, if productivity does not rise as fast as we forecast, then
interest rates will have to be higher than we project. These
observations mean that inflation is likely to remain firmly under
control with the inflation rate excluding mortgage payments ending the
current year at just under 2 per cent per annum and then rising very
slightly looking further ahead.
Note
(1.) http://www.euro.gov.uk/will/govt.html
References
Barrell, R. and Dury, K. (2000), 'Choosing the regime:
macroeconomic effects of UK entry into EMU', National Institute
Discussion Paper No. 168.
Barrell, R. and Pain, N. (1998), 'Real exchange rates,
agglomerations and irreversibilities: macroeconomic policy and
FDI', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 14, 3.
OECD (2000), EMU one year on, Paris, OECD.