THE UK ECONOMY.
Young, Garry
Garry Young [*]
Section I. Recent developments and summary of the forecast
The government's plans for public sector spending set out in
its recent spending review caused relatively little surprise as they
mainly confirmed what had already been announced in Budget 2000. This
was that overall spending, Total Managed Expenditure (TME), would rise
by 4 per cent per annum in real terms over the four years to 2003-4.
More detail did emerge on how this overall increase would be allocated
among the individual government departments. Falling debt interest
payments and the effects of lower unemployment on welfare payments and
tax receipts will allow departmental spending to rise by an average of 6
per cent per annum in real terms over the same period. A substantial
part of this increase is earmarked for capital projects, with the
capital budget more than doubling over the four-year period. This means
that departmental current spending will rise at the slower rate of about
3 per cent per annum in real terms.
The announcement of these plans has raised a number of concerns
about the effect of large increases in departmental spending on the
public finances and the economy more widely. Our assessment of the
implications for the public finances is contained in the Fiscal Report
beginning on page 32. In brief, there appears to be ample scope to
finance these spending increases within the existing tax structure and
our central forecast is for the overall budget to be in broad balance in
the medium term.
Of more concern is the effect on the economy. As the government has
itself emphasised, fiscal policy appears to have been tightened sharply
in recent years. In Budget 2000, the government took credit for a
cumulative fiscal tightening of 4.2 per cent of GDP since 1996-7,
measured by the fall in cyclically-adjusted net borrowing by the public
sector as a percentage of GDP. In the Fiscal Report, we argue that this
overstates the tightening because some of the reduction in government
demand has been offset directly by lower private saving due to the
changes in public spending and taxation. Nevertheless, there is little
doubt that fiscal policy is now being loosened when the economy is
closer to full capacity than it was when policy was tightened. This must
pose a threat to the outlook for inflation and interest rates.
There are two possible reasons why sharp increases in interest
rates might be unnecessary. First, the growth of private sector spending
might fall back to accommodate the increase in public spending and so
keep the trend in overall spending in line with the trend in output.
Second, productivity growth might pick up and allow the economy to
sustain a faster growth rate for a number of years. This could of course
be helped by the increase in infrastructure investment included in the
spending plans.
In our view, a case can be made for each of these possibilities.
Household spending has grown strongly over the past three years and more
quickly than the growth of income. This has meant that the household
saving ratio has fallen from over 9 per cent of disposable income in
1996 and 1997 to 3.8 per cent in the first quarter of this year. This is
the lowest rate of saving since the late 1980s, driven partly by fast
growth in asset prices but also because higher taxes have been paid for
by lower private saving. Having reached such a low level, it is
plausible to expect household saving now to increase somewhat,
especially if asset price inflation is slowing.
Moreover, over time there has been a clear inverse relationship between the saving of households and government. While such a
relationship comes about partly through changes in inflation and
interest rates, there are other reasons to expect that the savings
decisions of households and government are connected. These range from
Ricardian ideas of government saving being a substitute for household
saving to the more straightforward notion that taxes that support
government saving are often paid out of household saving rather than
consumption. While such relationships cannot necessarily be relied on,
this pattern suggests that any reduction in saving by government might
help to bring about a rise in saving by households.
Business investment growth outside the manufacturing sector has
also been very strong recently, growing by over 10 per cent per annum in
each year since 1997. As with consumption growth, this rate of expansion
is unsustainable and will drop off once the capital stock has been
brought up to its desired level. It is quite possible that this will
occur this year, although this is very uncertain at present.
Taken together, there is a distinct possibility of some slowdown in
private sector spending to offset an increase in public spending growth.
It is also possible that productivity growth will increase. This could
reflect so-called 'new economy' considerations, but it can
also be argued that productivity growth has fallen behind its trend in
recent years as employment has expanded rapidly. This is due partly to
unusually slow growth in manufacturing productivity since 1995 when the
industry as a whole has been affected by the strength of sterling. By
the end of 1998, the level of manufacturing productivity was no higher
than it had been in 1995. While it grew by 3.6 per cent last year, the
pressures on profitability within the industry make it likely that
productivity growth will accelerate once sales and output start to
expand.
We have built an increase in productivity growth into our forecast.
This is not for 'new economy' reasons but because
manufacturing industry in particular is assumed to be making up for lost
time. Thus after growing by 1 1/2 per cent per annum in each year
between 1997 and 1999, we are expecting overall productivity growth to
rise to 2 1/2 per cent this year and 3 per cent in 2001 and 2002 before
slowing down gradually over time. In the hard-pressed manufacturing
sector, we see fast productivity growth as the only reliable way for
firms to raise their profit margins. We are expecting manufacturing
productivity growth to rise to 4 per cent this year and 5 per cent in
2001 and 2002. In the accompanying box, we discuss some of the possible
consequences for the economy if productivity growth does not expand as
quickly.
The expected pick-up in productivity growth, together with some
slowdown in the growth of private spending, means that the economy can
accommodate increased public spending without provoking a large rise in
interest rates. However, we do not believe that interest rates have
peaked at 6 per cent. There is little evidence of spare resources in the
economy at present and while there is also little inflationary pressure,
the risks to inflation appear to be on the upside. We would expect the
Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) to raise interest rates to 6 1/4 per
cent at the end of the summer, and to raise them again to 6 1/2 per cent
by the beginning of next year. We are predicting that rates then stay at
this level for three years, before gradually converging on European
levels of around 5 per cent at the beginning of 2005 when the UK is
assumed to adopt the euro.
The forecast is based around a rate of entry to the euro at
[epsilon]1.55 at the beginning of 2005. This is only slightly below the
rate of [epsilon]1.59 that is assumed for the average of the current
quarter in the forecast. This projected entry rate is based on market
exchange rates and yield curves as of 17 July. If it is assumed that
arbitrage equalises the expected rate of return that investors can
obtain on bonds denominated in different currencies then it is possible
to infer future market interest and exchange rate expectations from
current market prices. With short-term interest rates in the UK higher
than those in the rest of Europe, the market appears to be expecting
sterling to decline to about [epsilon]1.57 in 2002 and remain at that
level for three or four years. But with long-term rates of interest in
the UK at 4.6 per cent and those in Germany at 5.5 per cent, the market
also appears to be expecting short-term interest rates in the UK to fall
below those in the Euro Area in the long term. If t his is correct then
investors must also be expecting sterling to rise in the long term to
offset the lower interest rate obtainable on UK stock. In fact, we doubt
that long-term interest rates in the UK are currently a true reflection
of market expectations. It is likely that they are distorted by an
excess demand for government stock caused by a combination of falling
debt and regulations imposed on financial institutions which require
them to hold this stock. As a consequence, we have used market prices
only as a guide to the rate at which sterling might enter the euro
rather than a hard and fast measure of market expectations.
Thus we are not expecting any substantial change in the exchange
rate in the medium term, although this remains a strong possibility. The
actual and forecast exchange rate is now about 3 per cent lower in
effective terms than in our last forecast and 5 per cent lower against
the dollar. Perhaps more importantly, the exchange rate has fallen
significantly from the temporarily very high levels reached three months
ago when it rose above [epsilon]1.70. This caused much consternation
among manufacturing firms who felt that the rate was a threat to their
continued presence in the UK. Anecdotal information suggests that they
would settle for a rate of [epsilon]1.55 and are now basing their
longer-term decisions on the exchange rate remaining at around this sort
of level, while hoping that it will fall further.
Summary of forecast
The slight fall in the effective exchange rate and more substantial
fall in the rate against the dollar, together with a stronger outlook
for world demand have changed the outlook a little since our last
forecast. In particular the prospects for growth in 2001 now look better
and, while this is expected to add to inflationary pressure, other new
information suggests the economy's ability to generate
non-inflationary growth may have improved. For example, revisions to the
national accounts have raised the measured level of output while
reducing estimates of some prices. In addition average earnings growth
has dropped back more quickly than many expected.
The official preliminary estimate of GDP growth in the second
quarter has been put at 0.9 per cent. This suggests that the relatively
weak first quarter represented a pause after fast growth in the second
half of last year rather than a reduction in the underlying rate of
growth. We are expecting growth to continue at a slightly faster rate
over the remainder of the year to give a rate of just over 3 per cent
for the year as a whole.
Domestic demand is set to expand by just under 4 per cent this
year, similar to the rate seen in 1999. This will be offset by a smaller
negative contribution from net trade with import growth of 8 per cent
outstripping export growth of around 7 per cent.
Given the level of sterling, it is likely that the service sectors
will continue to grow more quickly than manufacturing in 2000, although
we do not expect that the contraction in manufacturing output in the
first quarter will be repeated this year. Manufacturing is expected to
grow by about 1 1/2 per cent in the year as a whole. Growth in public
sector output is expected to pick up to over 3 per cent as increased
public spending feeds through.
Faster economic growth cannot reduce unemployment much more without
generating excessive inflationary pressure. Instead, with little slack in the labour market, much of the expected growth in output has to be
met by increases in productivity. Productivity growth is expected to be
particularly strong in manufacturing where it reached 3.5 per cent in
1999 in difficult trading conditions. We expect to see productivity
growth in manufacturing of about 4 per cent this year, in line with its
average over the 1980s and first half of the 1990s. This will contribute
to an increase in productivity growth in the whole economy of around 2
1/2 per cent, the fastest growth rate since 1994.
The combination of increasing aggregate demand and a relatively
tight labour market is expected to put some upward pressure on wages. We
are expecting earnings growth of around 5 per cent this year. With price
inflation expected to remain subdued, this represents an increase in
real wages of around 3 per cent.
Household incomes, which fell in the first quarter because of
higher tax payments, are forecast to grow by 3 per cent in 2000, driven
mainly by the growth in labour incomes. With household consumption
forecast to grow at a similar rate, the saving ratio is projected to
remain quite low at around 4 1/2 per cent in 2000, down from 5 per cent
in 1999.
The various influences on household spending, including financial
and housing wealth, interest rates and unemployment, are all supportive
of a relatively low saving ratio, but it is unlikely that they will
change in such a way as to encourage it to fall significantly in 2001.
We are expecting the growth in household consumption to slow from 3 1/2
per cent in 2000 to 3 per cent in 2001 as the growth in household
non-property income slows.
Although household consumption growth is slowing, the growth in
domestic demand is forecast to remain at around 3 1/2 per cent per annum
over the coming three years. This is partly driven by increased public
spending. Government consumption is expected to grow by 41/2 per cent in
2001, and government investment is set to rise by almost 20 per cent.
With the negative contribution from net trade waning, the overall growth
rate is forecast to rise to 3 1/2 per cent in 2001.
On the basis of this central forecast, we calculate that there is
only a slim chance of output declining in 2001. Indeed, we estimate that
the chances of growth being below 2 per cent are only about 20 per cent.
Most of the risks are for growth being very strong with a probability of
it exceeding 4 per cent being put at about 40 per cent.
We expect that the sectoral pattern of output growth in 2001 will
be similar to this year with manufacturing remaining fairly weak.
Continued pressure on profit margins is expected to lead to further
productivity growth in manufacturing of about 5 per cent in 2001. Job
losses in this sector will be more than made up for by employment gains
in the rest of the economy. With productivity growth rising to around 3
per cent per annum, aggregate employment is projected to rise at around
the same rate as the workforce and this will reduce unemployment only
modestly from current levels to about 5 1/2 per cent on the ILO definition by the end of next year.
Against this background, inflationary pressures are expected to
begin to build up. We are expecting RPIX inflation to remain at around 2
1/2 per cent until the end of 2001, with an expectation that it will
fall below 2 per cent in the short term. The probability of inflation
being above target at the end of 2001 is put at 48 per cent, with a 28
per cent chance that it is above 3 1/2 per cent. However, by the
beginning of 2002 there is a clear danger that it will rise above the
target. There is a one-in-three chance that it will exceed 3 1/2 per
cent in two years' time.
Section II The forecast in detail
The components of expenditure (Table 2)
After slowing at the turn of the year, GDP growth rose to 0.9 per
cent in the second quarter. This estimate was published after our
forecast was completed. We had estimated growth of 0.8 per cent. Using
this estimate, GDP in the year to the second quarter was 2.8 per cent
higher than it had been a year earlier. This was driven by continuing
strong growth in domestic demand of 3.6 per cent, with net trade making
a negative contribution of -0.8 per cent.
There are no clear signs of any easing in private domestic demand
growth and with public spending set to expand quickly at the same time
as a synchronised upturn in the world economy, the prospects for
aggregate demand are worryingly strong.
Household spending has been the main factor driving domestic
demand. But with the saving ratio now at a low level, this is forecast
to slow slightly over the coming two years to a rate of around 3 per
cent per annum. Businesses outside the manufacturing sector have spent
heavily on investment goods recently. This is believed partly to reflect
the installation of infrastructure associated with mobile telephones and
other forms of information technology. We are expecting this also to
slow down after recent rapid growth. However, fixed investment by the
public sector is planned to grow strongly. While there is a good deal of
uncertainty about its timing, it is likely that this will boost overall
fixed investment in the coming years. We are expecting growth in total
investment of more than 5 per cent in 2001 and 2002 after an increase of
3 1/2 per cent this year.
Government consumption has been less expansionary than departmental
budgets allowed and in the first quarter it returned to a level
marginally lower than it had been a year earlier. The under-spend partly
reflects the new spending control regime which allows departments to
carry over their allocations from one year to the next, when in the past
there would have been an incentive to use them up before the year-end.
The relatively low outturn for the first quarter means that the growth
rate in the year as a whole is likely to be around 2 per cent. But
growth is set to accelerate next year to around 4 1/2 per cent.
The overall growth rate of domestic demand is set to remain at
around 3 1/2 per cent per annum over the coming two or three years as
slowing growth in household consumption is offset by accelerating
government spending.
While net trade has continued to make a negative contribution to
GDP growth, this has waned considerably since the beginning of 1999 when
it was reducing the annual growth rate by about 2 percentage points. We
expect that its negative contribution will have disappeared completely
by the end of next year. There are three main reasons for this. First,
the effect of a high exchange rate is to reduce the level of net exports
and is unlikely to have a permanent effect on the growth rate. Second,
the synchronised upturn in the world economy is increasing the size of
UK export markets. Third, the shift in the composition of domestic
demand growth from private to government consumption is likely to reduce
import penetration. Overall we expect export growth to pick up to about
7 per cent per annum from 3.3 per cent last year. Import growth is
expected to rise to over 8 per cent this year, before falling back to
around 7 per cent per annum in 2001 and 2002.
Household sector (Table 3)
The financial position of the household sector as a whole continues
to be very strong and this is providing firm support for consumption.
Spending in the first quarter was 4 per cent higher than a year earlier,
with purchases of consumer durables other than vehicles up by 16 per
cent, clothing and footwear up by 6.5 per cent and spending on transport
and communications up by 5.5 per cent. In each of these cases, there was
a fall in prices over the same period emphasising the competitiveness of
the market for consumer goods. The weakness of household spending on
vehicles, which was broadly flat over the year, reflects a general view
that car prices are due to fall significantly in the near future.
In value terms, spending on services outstripped that on goods, but
this was due to faster growth in prices than in the volume of services
brought.
The combination of intensely competitive product markets and a
tightening labour market is helping households to benefit from strong
growth in real incomes. Total pay is currently growing at a little over
6 per cent per annum, but gross disposable income is expanding more
slowly at 5 per cent per annum, partly reflecting the impact of higher
tax payments and lower benefit receipts as the movement from welfare to
work continues.
With consumer prices growing by around 2 per cent per annum, this
is equivalent to an annual increase in real household disposable income
of around 3 per cent.
Household income is likely to continue to grow strongly as
increasing aggregate demand causes the labour market to tighten further.
This is not necessarily unsustainable as there would appear to be room
for productivity improvements that would allow household income to grow
at an above trend rate for a few years. We expect that real household
disposable income will grow by 3 per cent this year, rising to 3 1/2 per
cent in 2001 and 2002.
Over the past three years household spending has grown more
strongly than income as increased tax payments appear to have been paid
our of saving rather than consumption. This has had the effect of
reducing the saving ratio from over 9 per cent of household resources in
1997 to 3.8 per cent in the first quarter of this year. Despite this,
household wealth has grown strongly, driven by capital gains on equity
and housing. In real terms, household net wealth has risen by about 40
per cent since the end of 1995. This also provides a strong background
to household spending. Of course, the gains to asset price inflation are
not evenly distributed and the high level of house prices in London and
some other parts of the country will do little to boost the spending of
those who have recently financed their purchases by borrowing.
Nevertheless, with nominal interest rates continuing at a low level by
recent historical standards, the amount of income that has to be given
up to finance house purchase is still relatively low.
While very uncertain, the balance of probabilities suggests that
asset price inflation will be relatively subdued in the short term. Many
commentators believe that equity markets are overvalued and there are
now signs that the housing market is slowing. The perception that the
market is slowing is often sufficient to bring it about and we expect
house price growth to slow slightly through the year. Our forecast that
house prices will be about 10 per cent higher at the end of this year
compared with a year earlier is broadly in line with the expectations of
other forecasters.
We expect there to be a modest slowdown in household consumption
growth this year to around 3 1/2 per cent, with a further fall in the
growth rate to 3 per cent in 2001. This will bring spending growth
broadly into line with income growth and the saving ratio will remain at
around S per cent of household resources.
The relatively low level of saving seen recently has meant that
households in aggregate have been borrowing from other sectors over the
past two years. Given the very strong balance sheet of the sector as a
whole, we do not see this as a problem.
Fixed investment and stockbuilding (Tables 4 and 5)
Fixed investment growth in the non-manufacturing business sector
has been very strong over the past three years, growing by 50 per cent
since 1996. This reflects a number of factors, including low business
taxes, low real interest rates, robust growth in demand, substantial
falls in equipment prices and the effect of a strong stock market in
reducing the cost of capital. In addition to this, there have been a
number of areas where business growth has required the installation of
substantial new capital. This includes mobile phone and cable networks.
Unfortunately, there is hardly any published evidence that allows us to
measure their contribution to overall investment growth. This makes it
difficult to predict likely future levels of investment in this sector.
On the one hand, it might be thought that once large private
infrastructure projects have been installed, capital spending can be
reduced substantially. This would suggest that the level of investment
might be about to fall. On the other hand, the recen t pace of
technological change in information and communications technology suggests that further growth is likely. Our forecast builds in modest
growth of 2 per cent in this sector this year, with growth of just over
4 per cent in 2001 and 2002. But the link between investment growth and
technological change, which is very difficult to predict, makes this one
of the more uncertain areas of the overall forecast.
While similar factors are affecting the manufacturing sector, the
main influence on investment growth here has been the generally
depressed level of activity. This has meant that product demand could be
met through existing capacity. Investment fell by 14 per cent in 1999,
albeit from a high level, but picked up in the first quarter to a level
3.2 per cent higher than a year earlier. This mainly reflected capital
spending 13.5 per cent higher than a year earlier in the chemicals and
engineering industries. The fact that these industries have been the
fastest growing parts of manufacturing reinforces the view that capital
spending is related to the strength of product demand. The outlook for
investment growth here is looking more positive now that sterling has
fallen from the levels reached in April. We expect that it will be
broadly flat in 2000 and 2001, before picking up further in 2002.
Private sector housing investment is perhaps weaker than one might
expect given the strength of the housing market in general. We are
expecting growth of above 4 per cent, both this year and in 2001.
Investment in commercial property has not been strong in recent years,
reflecting the excess capacity built up in the late 1980s. However,
rents are now growing more quickly and prices are also picking up. This
has led to signs that some new development, at least in London, is for
speculative purposes. This is perhaps evidence of renewed confidence in
the commercial property sector.
Public sector housing investment is expected to grow sharply this
year, rising by over 20 per cent, but from a low level. The main
non-housing component of general government investment is also expected
to rise sharply over the coming years in line with the government's
plans. However, there is a good deal of uncertainty about when the
expenditure will actually be made. Public sector investment was up by
3.6 per cent in 1999 and is expected to grow by 64 per cent between 1999
and 2002.
The overall outlook for fixed investment spending is good, albeit
with a number of uncertainties relating to companies' need for new
capital rather than the availability and cost of finance. Our central
expectation is for growth of 3 1/2 per cent this year, followed by
growth of 5 per cent in 2001 and 2002.
As with the household sector, the company sector balance sheet
appears to be strong overall. However, just as investment spending has
been disparate across different industries, so some firms, particularly
those exporting to the Continent, have a worse balance sheet than the
average. Nevertheless, there is no strong evidence of a significant
number of companies in financial difficulty. The strength of the overall
balance sheet also indicates that the company sector net borrowing of
around 2 per cent of GDP is unlikely to be problematic or to impose a
brake on capital spending.
Balance of payments (Tables 6 and 7)
The traded sector of the economy has suffered the effects of a high
exchange rate against the other European economies since the end of
1996. This has resulted in both a loss of market share in export markets
and a sharp reduction in the profitability of exports. The volume of
exports grew by an average of 3 percentage points less than world trade
in 1998 and 1999. This loss of share would have been much more
pronounced if exporters had not reduced their prices substantially. The
average price of manufactured exports is now 14 per cent lower than in
1995, but export price competitiveness is still 3 per cent worse than at
that time, reflecting the effects of the strong pound and low world
inflation.
It now appears that the outlook for exporters is much more
promising with world demand growing quickly and the exchange rate having
fallen back somewhat from its highs in early May. While there is
relatively little room for manoeuvre, firms are likely to take advantage
of the improving situation to boost their margins, especially in export
markets.
Looking forward, we do not expect to see any substantial
improvement in export price competitiveness. Export prices are expected
to go up slowly from now onwards as firms attempt to improve their
margins and by the end of the year manufactured export prices are
expected to be 3 per cent higher than at the end of 1999. A further rise
of 4 1/2 per cent is in prospect for next year.
Against this background, the volume of manufactured exports is
expected to grow by about 10 per cent in both this year and next. This
is more or less in line with the growth of world trade which is forecast
to grow by 10 per cent this year and 7 1/2 per cent in 2001.
Manufactured import prices are forecast to grow by 1 per cent this
year and 3 per cent in 2001. This would mark an end to the period of
falling import prices enjoyed since 1996. Nevertheless the volume of
manufactured imports should continue to expand strongly with growth
expected to be 9 per cent in 2000 and 8 per cent in 2001.
The trade balance is forecast to reach a record deficit of
[pound]23 1/2 billion in 2000. We expect this to decline over the next
few years as the world economy remains strong and domestic exporters
seek to improve their profitability. This improvement is also reflected
in the overall goods deficit which is expected to fall from [pound]29
billion this year to [pound]26 billion in 2002. With the services,
transfers and income balance forecast to return a surplus of around
[pound]15 billion, the overall current balance deficit is forecast to
decline from [pound]15 billion this year to [pound]12 billion in 2002.
This is relatively small at just over 1 per cent of GDP.
The financial account of the balance of payments has seen some very
large flows recently. These largely reflect international mergers and
acquisitions. In the first quarter, direct investment abroad was
[pound]125.3 billion. This mainly reflects the acquisition of Mannesmann AG by Vodafone AirTouch Plc for [pound]133 billion. This was financed by
the issue of Vodafone AirTouch shares to Mannesmann shareholders and, as
such, is recorded as inward portfolio investment. Such flows swamp the
current account deficit.
The net investment position of the UK economy showed a negative
balance of [pound]128.7 billion at the end of the first quarter. This is
the difference between assets of [pound]2582.3 billion and liabilities
of [pound]2711.1 billion. Despite the negative net balance, net income
is generally positive (over [pound]8 billion in 1999) reflecting the
higher yield on assets than liabilities, much of which are on deposit in
the UK banking system. While this situation persists, the overall net
position is not any cause for concern.
Output and employment (tables 8 and 9)
The annual growth rate in the first quarter was 2.9 per cent. This
reflected strong growth of 3.3 per cent in the service sector and slower
growth of 1.5 per cent in production. The construction industry picked
up strongly to grow by 4.8 per cent. At a more detailed level, output in
the post and telecommunications industry grew by 13.3 per cent. This
industry produced 67 per cent more output than it did in 1995. Apart
from such obvious exceptions, growth over the past year appears to be
much more similar in different industries than had been the case a year
or more ago.
It had been feared that such divergent trends would continue this
year, with manufacturing looking particularly vulnerable to problems
caused by the high exchange rate. However, recent information suggests a
better outlook. The exchange rate has declined from its earlier peaks.
At the end of April it reached [epsilon]1.71, 7.5 per cent higher than
is assumed for the current quarter. In addition, manufacturing output
grew in April and May and is expected to show growth of around 0.6 per
cent in the second quarter. With demand picking up generally, the
prospects for manufacturing are better than they were three months ago.
We now expect growth of about 1 1/2 per cent in manufacturing output
this year. This is set to rise by around 2 1/2 per cent in 2001 and
2002.
Although the outlook for manufacturing has improved, the industry
is unlikely to perform as well as other parts of the economy. Public
sector output will expand quite strongly in response to increased
spending. Similarly, the service sector is also likely to continue to
expand rapidly.
The increase in aggregate output in the forecast is not expected to
be matched by increased employment. The number of workforce jobs is
expected to increase at a similar rate to last year, by 0.8 per cent, to
28.21 million by the end of the year. While there are differences across
sectors this implies that the increases in output discussed above must
be generated by improvements in productivity.
Productivity growth has been relatively sluggish since the
mid-1990s, such that its level is now only 7 per cent higher than in
1995. This has been much less than might have been expected on past
trends. It reflects the absorption into employment of almost one and a
half million people over the same period. It also partly reflects the
stagnation of manufacturing which is typically the source of much of the
UK's productivity growth. Our expectation is that productivity
growth will make up some of the lost ground over the next few years.
This is likely to be particularly apparent in manufacturing. Here
profitability has been hit by the strong pound and this will encourage
firms to keep costs down as they grow. We are expecting productivity
growth here to pick up to 4 per cent this year and 5 per cent in 2001
and 2002. It is possible that this underestimates the scope for a
productivity improvement since this does little to make up for the
ground lost since the mid-1990s.
Greater competition for labour in the other sectors of the economy
is likely to encourage firms there to economise on the number of workers
they employ. We expect overall productivity growth to rise from 1.5 per
cent in 1999 to 2 1/2 per cent this year and 3 per cent in 2001 and
2002. This is above the trend growth rate and reflects some catch-up,
following below trend growth in the second half of the 1990s.
Employment is expected to grow at about the same pace as the
workforce in the next few years. This will stabilise the unemployment
rate at around current levels.
Thus ILO unemployment is expected to remain at around 5 1/2 per
cent of the workforce. The non-employment rate is also expected to
stabilise at about 24 per cent of the population of working age.
Earnings and prices (Tables 3 and 10)
After peaking at 6 per cent in February, the headline rate of
growth of average earnings in the whole economy fell to 4.6 per cent per
annum in May. On the national accounts measure of wages and salaries per
head, pay growth was at 5.2 per cent per annum in the first quarter.
Given the distortions in pay around the turn of the year and the effects
of the introduction of the National Minimum Wage in April 1999,
underlying pay is probably now growing at around 4 1/2 per cent per
annum.
Looking ahead, continuing growth in the economy is likely to add to
upward pressure on pay. This will be compounded by the effect of
slightly increasing RPI inflation which tends to form the basis for many
pay deals. We expect a modest rise in the growth of average earnings to
just over 5 per cent in 2000 and then to 5 1/2 per cent in 2001 and 6
per cent in 2002.
This rate of growth need not contribute to excessive inflationary
pressure if it is accompanied by fast enough growth in productivity
which reduces the growth of unit labour costs. Unit labour costs are
estimated to have grown by 4 per cent in 1999, reflecting growth of 5
per cent in average earnings and productivity growth of around 1 1/2 per
cent (other influences on unit labour costs are employer contributions
made to the national insurance scheme and other payments on behalf of
employees). It is generally reckoned that the trend growth rate of
productivity in the UK is about 2 per cent per annum. However, after the
sluggish performance of the late 1990s, we expect it to expand
sufficiently to keep the growth of unit labour costs in check at around,
or just under 3 per cent per annum. But with import prices now expected
to rise, having fallen from 1996, any pressure on inflation from the
labour market will not be off-set by cheaper imports.
This would suggest that the inflation outlook is now very finely
balanced. We foresee consumer prices rising by 2 per cent by the end of
this year and by 2 1/2 per cent by the end of 2001, broadly in line with
costs. A similar pattern is predicted for RPIX, but the headline RPI is
expected to rise a little more quickly in response to the rise in
interest rates in the second half of 1999.
Other domestic prices are expected to grow more or less at the same
rate as consumer prices. The GDP deflator is expected to grow at about 2
1/2 per cent in 2001, but is forecast to rise to 3 per cent in 2002,
partly reflecting faster growth in the prices of goods and services consumed by the government.
National and sectoral saving (Table II)
The current account deficit of the economy as a whole is a
reflection, subject to a statistical residual, of the financial position
of the individual sectors in the economy. Table 11 shows how the
imbalances between the saving and investment of the individual sectors
is resolved. Ultimately, any investment that cannot be financed by
domestic saving needs to be financed abroad.
Household sector saving is expected to be about 3 per cent of GDP
this year, but picking up in the years ahead. At present saving is less
than investment by households resulting in an unusual financial deficit.
This means that the household sector is not a net lender to other
sectors as is usually the case. Company sector saving is expected to
remain below investment such that the deficit of saving relative to
investment is of the order of 2 per cent of GDP. The government sector
is now meeting the Golden Rule so that its saving is positive and is
forecast to remain in excess of its investment over the next three
years.
The current account moved into deficit last year and is expected to
remain at a little over 1 per cent of GDP in the coming four or five
years. It is fairly clear that the movement into deficit of the current
account of the balance of payments is associated with the increased
deficit of the private sector. For households, saving fell sharply in
1998 and has remained low since. For companies, the move into deficit
can be traced back partly to the strength of the pound which has
encouraged spending to be switched away from domestic goods and towards
foreign goods, thereby reducing profits and company saving. If this
situation were to continue then companies would at some stage need to
adjust their saving or investment to prevent their indebtedness rising
too quickly. This would feed through either directly, through lower
spending on foreign investment goods, or indirectly through the effects
of lower dividend payments on household spending on imports, to the
current account. The process of adjustment would also affect prices in
such a way that competitiveness is eventually restored. Through these
channels, a current account deficit is ultimately corrected.
The economy in the medium term (Table 12)
The way in which the economy behaves over the medium term is
determined partly by a range of shocks that are inherently
unpredictable. But there are other important influences on its
development that can be foreseen. These include trends in the size and
composition of the population, forthcoming changes in the policy
framework as well as adjustments to existing disequilibria. As we have
noted, the economy as a whole is close to an equilibrium position at
present, but there are a few imbalances that will be adjusted in the
medium term. Among these is the current weakness of manufacturing due
largely to the overvalued exchange rate.
We continue to assume that sterling's rate against the euro
will stabilise in the fairly near future in advance of actually joining
EMU. We have assumed that sterling will be fixed at [epsilon]1.55
(equivalent to DM3.04) from the beginning of 2005, a rate broadly
consistent with market expectations. Many would regard this rate as
being too high and it certainly implies a higher real exchange rate than
the UK has been able to sustain historically. But since the end of 1996
the economy does appear to have adjusted to a high exchange rate. At
first exports appeared not to be affected by the strong pound, but these
then weakened sharply both in 1998 and in the first half of 1999. The
contraction in the manufacturing sector was also a consequence of the
high pound. But we now see grounds for expecting the growth of exports
and manufacturing output to recover without a substantial depreciation
of the nominal exchange rate. However, we are not expecting the ground
lost over the last few years to be made up.
The increases in public spending announced in Budget 2000,
especially with respect to investment, will have an expansionary impact
of aggregate demand over the medium term. This will put some upward
pressure on domestic inflation and the current account deficit which
will however decline over the coming decade as households and firms
bring saving and investment into line.
Inflation is forecast to remain low over this period. With the
sterling exchange rate fixed, there will nor be room for large
persistent differences in inflation across the Euro Area. So long as
this is clearly understood, expectations, which are crucially important
in the inflationary process, should help anchor inflation itself.
The outlook for interest rates and inflation is consistent with
long-term real interest rates of around 2 per cent. This is much lower
than has been normal in the UK over the past twenty years, but is
consistent with real yields on UK government index-linked debt.
Short-term interest rates are expected to rise slightly, reaching 6 1/2
per cent in 2001. They are then projected to fall, converging on euro
rates by the beginning of 2005.
Unemployment, on the ILO definition, is forecast to fall to just
over S per cent of the working population. This is slightly lower than
is the case now, and is a reasonable estimate of the sustainable rate of
unemployment. The rate of real wage growth is sensitive to which
deflator is used. Using the GDP deflator at basic prices, the real wage
is forecast to grow at about 2 1/2 per cent per annum, similar to the
rate of growth of productivity.
The government has identified slow productivity growth as one of
the important problems of the UK economy and it is possible that policy
action over the coming years will be successful in raising it. However,
we have made no special allowance for this. Our forecast of productivity
growth is consistent with long-term trends in the economy, although we
are forecasting some above trend growth in the early part of the decade
as productivity makes up some of the ground lost in the second half of
the 1990s.
Forecast errors and probability distribution (Tables 13 and 14)
Table 13 provides a set of summary information as regards the
accuracy of forecasts that have been published in the July Review. The
latest complete National Accounts information available when these
forecasts are constructed is for the first quarter of the current year.
A rule of thumb is that a 70 per cent confidence interval for a
variable of interest can be obtained by adding a range of one absolute
average error around our central forecast. Thus we can be 70 per cent
sure that GDP growth in 2000 will be between 2.4 and 3.8 per cent. The
size of the average errors indicates that some variables are easier to
forecast than others. For example, the errors in forecasting
consumers' expenditure are smaller than those in forecasting fixed
investment. It is also the case that the error in forecasting GDP growth
is smaller than that made in forecasting its components. This arises
because of offsetting movements among the components.
The probability distributions around the growth and inflation
forecasts have been calculated assuming that the distributions are
normal and are shown in Table 14. The standard errors have been
calculated from the historical forecast errors underlying Table 13.
These estimates of the probability distribution around our central
forecasts provide a quantitative assessment of the limits of our
forecasts.
Our estimates suggest that there is now a 76 per cent chance that
growth this year will turn out to be in the range of 2 to 4 per cent,
with only a 10 per cent chance of growth below 2 per cent. For next
year, growth prospects are much more uncertain. However, it is now
thought very unlikely that it will be below 1 per cent. There is a 51
per cent chance that it will be between 1 and 4 per cent and a 40 per
cent chance that it will be above that.
For inflation, there is a 60 per cent chance that it will end the
year between 1.5 and 2.5 per cent. The risks are clearly larger looking
ahead. In two years' time, there is an evens chance that inflation
will be above 2 1/2 per cent. However, the imprecision of the forecast
is shown by the fact that there is a 30 per cent chance that it will be
below 1 1/2 per cent. The chance that it will be more than 1 per cent
away from target in either direction is put at 60 per cent. The fact
that it has stayed within this fairly narrow bound over the past two
years is an indication of either the skill of the MPC or their good
fortune.
(*.) The forecast was compiled using the latest version of the
National Institute Domestic Econometric Model. I am grateful to Ray
Barrell, Richard Kneller, Nigel Pain, Rebecca Riley and Martin Weale for
comment and discussion.
Box I. Productivity to the rescue?
Our central forecast sees the growth rate increasing to accommodate
higher public sector spending without generating any substantial
inflationary pressure. The key reason that this is feasible is because
we believe that there is room for a spurt in productivity growth to
match the spurt in spending. This box considers the outlook for the
economy if this judgement is wrong.
Without an acceleration in productivity growth, firms would be able
to meet demand only by increasing employment and this would tighten the
labour market further, contributing to an increase in wage pressure. In
the short run, an increase in wages would reduce the profit share. But
it would also add to inflation, unless action were taken to damp down
demand by raising interest rates.
To quantify these effects we have re-run the forecast, assuming
that productivity grows at an average rate of 2.1 per cent per annum
over the five years to 2004. rather than the 2.6 per cent per annum
growth predicted in the central forecast. We have not changed the
interest rate and exchange rate projections underlying the forecast in
order to focus on the impact on inflationary pressure. In the short run,
output would grow as in the main forecast, but with employment rather
than productivity rising. But in the longer term it would decelerate to
reflect lower productivity growth. ILO unemployment would be reduced
temporarily by 1/2 a percentage point relative to the main forecast and
RPIX inflation would rise to 3.7 per cent in 2001, almost 1 1/2
percentage points above the main case. This shows how far inflation can
change even within the MPC's forecast horizon.
Increased inflationary pressure at home would worsen competitiveness, thus reducing exports and increasing imports. This
would worsen the current account deficit, but also draw in resources to
meet fast-growing demand. However, the public finances would be improved
further in this situation. This is because public spending is fixed in
cash terms, while the extra inflationary pressure is likely to raise tax
receipts.
The table below outlines some of the main results. It shows an
upside risk to inflation that might materialise without a pick-up in
productivity growth. An early signal of this would come from an
acceleration in earnings growth above the rate of 5.4 per cent per annum
predicted for 2001 in our forecast.
However, this is just one of the many risks to which the forecast
is exposed. It is possible that productivity growth stays low, but wage
pressure does not pick up because the sustainable rate of unemployment
is lower than we currently believe. A good guide to the overall
uncertainty surrounding our forecast is shown in tables 13 and 14 of
this chapter.