COMMENTARY.
Weale, Martin ; Young, Garry
Introduction
The early Autumn has brought two issues into focus, the taxation of
motor fuel and the question of old age pensions. The debate on both of
these has been coloured by the widow's cruse of the government
budget. Despite the fact that government spending is rising the current
account is in large surplus and the buoyant revenue shows no sign of
diminishing. We predict a continuing surplus on the current account of
the public sector of [pound]l9bn in the current fiscal year, falling
only slowly next year. With rapid growth in public sector investment,
the public sector cash surplus, having been swollen in 2000/2001 by
sales of broad-band spectrum licences, is expected to be [pound]7bn next
year and thereafter to settle close to zero.
This picture, of course, leads to the view that the money is there
to reduce fuel taxes and increase pensions and that such changes are in
some sense 'costless' instead of being at the expense of
higher taxes or lower spending elsewhere. There are two immediate
observations which follow. First of all, from a macroeconomic point of
view, the state of demand in the economy is such that significant tax
cuts or pension increases should be expected to lead to a higher
interest rate at a time when some people feel already that monetary
policy is too tight and, in consequence, that fiscal policy is too
slack. Secondly, it is always the case that public spending or lower
taxes have a cost. The government does not have to balance its budget in
any one year, but a lower surplus now means higher taxes in the future,
possibly at a time when revenue has lost its current buoyancy.
Pensions
The issue of pensions is complicated and for a number of reasons.
There is pressure on the government to target help at poor pensioners
but at the same time it is objected that this penalises people who save.
On the other hand, to raise the basic pension for everyone, or to resume
earnings indexation is expensive. The logic of the position is that
'targeting' of help amounts to a high effective tax rate,
either on the investment income of people of modest means or on their
capital. One can reasonably question why a government which thinks it
inappropriate to levy a tax rate of more than 40 per cent at the top end
of the income scale, should think it appropriate to impose much higher
tax rates on much poorer people. These high tax rates act as a
disincentive to save which is mitigated only by the complexity of the
benefit structure serving to mask its true nature. However their effect
is to increase wealth inequality (Sefton, Dutta and Weale, 1998). People
of modest means are discouraged from saving, while tho se with more
resources see benefit withdrawal as a lump-sum tax which does not affect
their marginal decisions.
In the short term there is little that the government can do except
muddle through. Most of those currently retired did so after the link
between pensions and earnings ended twenty years ago and have had the
opportunity to provide for their retirement, although there is a case
for paying more to very old people who retired before the end of the
earnings link or had only a few years to adjust to the changed
circumstances. There is also a question whether the government did
enough to inform people of the consequences of breaking the earnings
link at the time the link was broken; this might also justify some
increase now. In the longer term the key question that the government
needs to address is the appropriate balance between means-tested
benefits paid to old people and means-tested pension contribution
credits paid to people of working age. The former discourage saving
while the latter reduce the incentive to work. For any overall level of
support to pensioners it is necessary to strike a balance between thes e
two disincentives. As yet it is too soon to offer any precise guidance
on this issue; a project studying the trade-off funded by the ESRC begins at the National Institute next year. On the other hand we can
note that the government has additionally discouraged private saving in
pension schemes by reducing the 'carry forward' of private
pension contribution entitlements from seven years to one year. This
greatly reduces the flexibility of private pension schemes and is bound
to discourage their use as compared to other forms of saving (see
Sefton, 2000).
One should not lose sight of the effect of paying larger pensions
to old people out of current revenue. It amounts to a permanent transfer
from the young to the old; those drawing pensions at the time of the
increase receive a benefit that they have not necessarily paid for. As
the population ages the proportion of old voters increases and it
becomes more and more likely that governments will bow to pressure from
the elderly. But at the same time, as the balance of the population
ages, the burden imposed on those of working age by any particular
pension increase is all the greater. It should also be noted that young
people are typically wealth-constrained; on average their incomes rise
at least until their forties. In consequence the level of spending that
they can afford out of their life-time income is likely to be higher
than their current income. Lack of access to borrowing means that their
consumption is held below its optimum level in the first part of their
working lives, rising above it in the second part. To impose further
taxes on young people so that they receive extra pension benefits when
they are old worsens the impact of this wealth constraint.
The cost of any pension increase is, of course, compounded by
ageing of the population As the population ages there are more
recipients and fewer taxpayers. It is therefore a mistake to assess the
cost of any permanent increase in terms only of current year costs. The
most sensible question to ask is what permanent change in the tax rate
is needed to finance a permanent change to pensions, although this means
that initially the extra tax collected will be more than adequate to
meet the pension increase because there are relatively fewer pensioners
at the start of the period. On page 15 we set out some calculations from
the National Institute's generational accounts. These suggest, for
example, that a resumption of earnings indexation would take the
standard rate of income tax about 5p higher than it would otherwise have
been.
Fuel tax
There are also a number of microeconomic arguments which suggest
that the Chancellor of the Exchequer would be wrong to respond directly
to the pressures he is facing to reduce fuel taxes. At present fuel tax
is the best means that we have of charging for road use. It is a blunt
instrument which might eventually be replaced by proper charging
mechanisms, but until these exist one has to rely on fuel tax. The
degree of congestion in urban streets makes it seem that fuel taxes are
more likely to be too low than too high. In the long term the problem
could be allieviated by urban road building, but it is doubtful that
there is a consensus for building urban motorways on any significant
scale. Secondly, the government has agreed targets to limit emissions of
carbon dioxide. Taxation of motor spirit, as a means of discouraging car
use and encouraging people to buy fuel-efficient cars is an important
means of delivering these targets. More generally, there can be no doubt
that the best means of keeping oil prices i n check would be for the
oil-consuming countries to levy a substantial tax on the use of oil.
This is bound to be more effective than exhorting OPEC to raise output
but there are obvious difficulties in explaining and implementing it,
particularly in the United States.
Against these arguments for continuing and increased taxation, we
have seen pressure from the producer interests of farmers and road
hauliers making a number of arguments which are ill-founded or reflect
vested interests. Both groups complain, rather oddly, that they are
unable to pass on cost increases, despite the fact that fuel price rises
affect their competitors as much as themselves. UK hauliers competing
with foreign truckers have the same access to foreign fuel sources as do
their competitors. Hauliers observe that they face 'unfair'
competition from competitors from Central Europe who use lower-paid
drivers while farmers complain of low prices which make farming
uneconomic. In both of these cases it is worth pausing to consider the
consumer interest. If goods can be delivered more cheaply in Britain by
foreign hauliers, that surely is in the public interest and particularly
so at a time when the labour market is tight. Similarly, if food, like
coal, can be bought from overseas without the subsidies o r inflated
prices that are paid to British farmers and were paid to British coal mines, that too must be in the taxpayer's interest. The solution
floated to hauliers' problems, that foreign truckers should be
taxed for driving on UK roads is equivalent to an import tariff with
clear adverse effects on consumer welfare. [1] As so often in these
debates, the producer interests are focused, while the consumer
interests are dispersed making it all too likely that governments
succumb to producer pressure at the consumers' expense. Skillful producers may even succeed in generating public sympathy at the same
time as they burden consumers with the costs of subsidies or protection
from foreign competition.
The international environment
In our forecasts of the UK and world economies we discuss the
question of fuel prices from a number of perspectives. First of all we
look at the impact on the world economy of different oil prices. We note
that there is some sensitivity to the oil price, in that an increase of
the oil price of 50 per cent depresses output in the UK, the Euro Area
and the United States by 1/2-3/4 percentage points by 2002 and leads to
a price level which is up to 1 per cent higher. Monetary policy responds
to the increased inflationary pressures, so that interest rates are
raised by up to 1/4-1/2 percentage points by 2002.
The other international development of some importance is the
concern that the US is showing about the strength of the US dollar. This
led to intervention to support the euro in September. However since then
the dollar has risen to an even higher level against the euro. Exchange
rates are notoriously unpredictable, but a forecast requires some
assumption. Our forecast is based on the premise that exchange rates
remain close to current levels, although it shows some recovery of the
euro from the very low levels reached recently.
The world economy remains very exposed to the risks that world
stock markets, and in particular the US market, will fall back to more
normal levels. Such falls are likely to have more of an impact on
aggregate demand than was the case in the crashes of 1973/4 and 1987
because stock market wealth is a more important component of
people's portfolios than it was then. Savings ratios, particularly
in the United States, are likely to rise in response to falling stock
markets, with a consequent reduction of aggregate demand. This stock
market risk may be aggravated by fears that banks have lent too heavily
to telecom and information technology firms, raising the possibility of
new liquidity problems for the banking sector.
The UK economy
At a more domestic level, the result of the Danish referendum must
make it less likely that Britain will join the Euro Area in the short or
medium term. On the other hand this now has few implications for our
forecast. We take the view that exchange rate movements are generally
best indicated by interest rate differentials. The term structures of
interest rates in sterling and the euro suggest that, after a modest
decline of sterling to [epsilon]1.65 in 2002-3, the exchange rate is
expected to be stable. For long maturities sterling yields are lower
than euro yields. We take the view that this is because the minimum
funding requirement creates an artificial demand for UK government
stocks and do not assume that the difference implies that the euro is
expected to fall against sterling in the longer term.
As we reported in July, our projection does not suggest that the
exchange rate at this level will cause severe problems for the British
economy, although its structure will obviously be different from that
suited to a much lower exchange rate. The buoyancy in manufacturing
reported in the August data is perhaps the first explicit signal that
the economy is developing a structure suited to the level of the
exchange rate. The argument becomes even stronger when one looks at the
export performance of manufactures. Manufacturing exports were in 2000Q2
more than 10 per cent above their value a year earlier and the buoyant
growth has continued into the third quarter of the year. Thus, with most
of the estimate for the year based on data rather than a forecast, we
expect that, in the year as a whole manufacturing exports, growing by
12.5 per cent over 1999, will have grown more than manufacturing imports
and also faster than world trade as a whole. We expect that, with the
exchange rate close to current levels, manu facturing exports will
continue to grow broadly in line with world trade.
There is, however, one risk we should mention. This is that the
rapid growth of manufacturing exports reflects the outcome of decisions
to raise manufacturing capacity made at a time when either the exchange
rate was lower than it was now or in the belief that the high exchange
rate would prove short-lived. If this is the case there is a risk that
manufacturing capacity, and therefore manufacturing exports, may fall in
the future. Manufacturing investment gives a mixed signal about this. In
1999 investment fell back to the 1996 level from a record in 1998. Our
estimate for 2000, again based partly on data, is that there has been a
recovery from the low levels of last year, but that investment remains
below its 1997 and 1998 figures. Indeed the modest growth we project in
2001 and 2002 is not sufficient to lift manufacturing investment above
its 1998 level. On the other hand non-manufacturing business investment,
which is much the larger part of overall business investment, is now one
third higher than it was in 1997 and is expected to remain buoyant.
This generally buoyant picture leads us to forecast a growth rate
of about 3 1/2 per cent for next year falling to about 3 per cent in
2002. Manufacturing output overall is expected to grow faster next year
than in 2000. From the demand side both government spending and fixed
investment are expected to show rapid growth. We anticipate some
recovery of the household saving ratio, so that household consumption
will grow more slowly than GDP. Plainly, if this recovery of the savings
ratio does not occur, then GDP growth will be even faster with a major
risk of overheating.
If the growth rate does not rise above the level we have forecast,
we expect the inflation rate to remain within the government's
target. However, our analysis is predicated on the assumption that a
period of relatively rapid productivity growth is now possible. As we
explained in July, unless this happens it will prove very difficult for
the economy to accommodate the Chancellor's spending plans without
being overwhelmed by inflationary pressures. It will also become
increasingly difficult for the economy to compete satisfactorily in
world markets.
But with our forecast of productivity growth of close to 3 per cent
per annum for the whole of the economy in 2001 and 2002, and remaining
above 2 per cent per annum until 2007, inflation remains in check with
interest rates not far above today's level. With claimant count
unemployment at just over 1 million, the scope for continuing falls is
plainly limited. The labour market is likely to remain tight, and we
expect earnings growth of over 5 per cent per annum during 2001.
This time last year we expressed the view that the Monetary Policy
Committee had changed interest rates far too frequently with rather
little impact on the inflation rate (see National Institute Economic
Review, No. 170, p. 12). A number of members of the Monetary Policy
Committee publicly disagreed with this view although there are no
official estimates of what has been achieved by monetary policy
activism. But the interest rate has now remained unchanged since
February and our view is that a rise would be prudent and consistent
with our forecast for GDP growth. We have assumed that the base rate
will rise to 6 1/4 per cent per annum by the end of this year, with a
further rise to 6 1/2 per cent per annum early next year.
NOTE
1 The only case where a levy can be justified is if UK road fund
taxes are higher than those collected elsewhere. It makes sense to
equalise these charges by imposing a levy on foreigners to match that
imposed on UK firms.
REFERENCES
Sefton, J., Dutta, J. and Weale, M.R. (1998), 'Pension finance
in a calibrated model of savings and income distribution of the
UK', National Institute Economic Review, 166, pp. 97-107.
Sefton, J. (2000), 'The demand for personal pensions',
paper presented to INQUIRE conference, September.