Properties of the fundamental equilibrium exchange rate in the Treasury model.
Church, Keith B.
1. Introduction On 1 January 1999 the inhabitants of eleven member
states of the European Union commenced the buying and selling of goods
and services using the European single currency. The UK has opted not to
participate for the time being, but retains the option to do so at a
later date. One feature of the single currency is the joining together
of currencies at the nominal parities that previously prevailed in the
Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM). However, this fixing of nominal rates
does not mean that exchange rates between members ceased to be important
from the start of 1999, because the existence of different inflation
rates across countries ensures that real exchange rates between member
states still vary.
Any country experiencing higher inflation than its fellow
participants, perhaps following a shock felt only in the domestic
market, finds its goods and services becoming less attractive with the
appreciation of the real exchange rate. Outside of a currency union this
loss of competitiveness might be eliminated by a fall in the nominal
exchange rate, a reduction in domestic inflation or a combination of
both. For the member of the single currency the first option is ruled
out and so the domestic inflation rate must fall below levels elsewhere
until the loss of competitiveness is reversed Given the rigidity in
European labour markets, achieving adjustment through lower price rises
is likely to be costly in terms of jobs and output in the medium term.
If it is decided that the costs of membership are outweighed by the
benefits and the UK elects to join the single currency then the question
arises of the appropriate entry rate for sterling. This choice should
reflect the fact that any adjustment of the real exchange rate to an
appropriate level will be harder to achieve once the nominal exchange
rate is fixed. This article uses the model of Her Majesty's
Treasury (HMT) to calculate the value of the real exchange rate for the
UK that is compatible with medium-term macroeconomic equilibrium. This
is known as the fundamental equilibrium exchange rate (FEER) and is the
rate consistent with an economy growing at its 'natural' rate
with unemployment at the NAIRU, and where any deviation of the current
account from balance is sustainable through inflows or outflows of
capital over the medium term. The long-run relationships which form the
supply side and trading sectors of the HMT model are solved to give this
equilibrium rate.
The consequences of entering a fixed exchange rate regime at the
wrong nominal rate were demonstrated in September 1992 when sterling
left the ERM. Several studies were published at that time, including
Wren-Lewis et al. (1991) and Church (1992), showing that the actual real
exchange rate was well above the FEER. Convergence while sterling was
fixed around a band centred on DM2.95 might have been achieved through a
prolonged period where UK inflation was lower than that in the rest of
Europe but one interpretation of the events of September 1992 is that
the markets saw this as unrealistic and so forced the convergence to
occur through a large depreciation in the nominal exchange rate instead.
If the single currency is a success for the eleven countries
participating from the start then it seems likely that the current
government would want sterling to join. If the model of Her
Majesty's Treasury (HMT) in some sense represents the
government's view of how the UK economy works then it should give
some insight into the decision of the appropriate level of the exchange
rate to enter at. This article uses the HMT model to estimate the FEER
so that the extent of any real exchange rate disequilibrium can be
evaluated.
The article proceeds as follows. In Section 2 the theoretical
framework underlying the FEER is outlined. The extent to which the HMT
model conforms to this framework is examined in Section 3, while in
Section 4 the core results together with the outcome of various
sensitivity exercises are presented. Section 5 contains concluding
comments.
2. The FEER framework
The fundamental equilibrium exchange rate (FEER) as developed by
Williamson (1983) is that value of the real exchange rate which is
consistent with medium-term macroeconomic equilibrium and is achieved
when domestic activity is at its 'normal' rate and the trading
position with the rest of the world is sustainable. The FEER
calculations presented here give estimates of the value of the real
exchange rate that we might expect the economy to converge towards, but
we do not suggest how the convergence to this equilibrium might take
place. Indeed the FEER itself is dependent on the path the actual real
exchange rate takes to reach equilibrium, a point noted by Wren-Lewis
(1992). When the real exchange rate moves very slowly to the FEER, large
differences in current account imbalance persist which flow onto asset
stocks. This is not the case when adjustment is rapid. The size of asset
stocks determines the magnitude of debt interest payments which are
themselves a part of the FEER calculation. Hence if the UK takes a long
time to eliminate any deficit exceeding 'normal' capital
inflows then a lower than otherwise level of the FEER is required to
counter the higher debt interest payments heading abroad.
Looking at the components of overall equilibrium we first consider
'internal balance'. The domestic economy is in equilibrium
when inflation is stable and the prevailing rate of unemployment is the
equilibrium rate. There are a variety of methods we might use to arrive
at an estimate for the equilibrium path for output in the economy. The
benefit of using a large-scale macroeconometric model is that it
provides consistent estimates of all the relationships that form the
supply side of the economy and from these relationships it is possible
to derive the steady-state growth path for output. This equilibrium path
is an important determinant of the FEER because changes in domestic
activity feed directly into the import equations and hence change the
level of the current account. However, there are differing views on
whether the real exchange rate itself influences the equilibrium level of activity in the long run. Earlier vintages of several UK models
described in Church et al. (1993) have this property because of the way
the real exchange rate influences wage bargaining, while in the UK
models described in Church et al. (1997) this feature is confined to the
HMT model. Where this effect is present there is a positive relationship
between the level of the real exchange rate and the equilibrium level of
activity. This is illustrated by considering the impact of a devaluation and the associated increase in real import prices. This increase puts
downward pressure on real wage rates. On one side of the wage bargain,
workers or their representatives resist this reduction while on the
other side firms wish to limit the fall in their profitability caused by
this resistance. The equilibrium level of activity changes to balance
the objectives of both sides. In this case equilibrium employment and
output fall to ensure inflation stability.
Wren-Lewis and Driver (1998) outline two further mechanisms through
which the real exchange rate might influence internal balance. The first
is closely related to the bargaining issue discussed above. Real labour
costs are linked to the price of domestic output while real incomes are
measured in terms of consumer prices which have an import price
component. Therefore an appreciation in the real exchange rate increases
real incomes and hence (assuming a positively-sloped labour supply
curve) the supply of labour and trend output. This effect is present in
the manufacturing sector of the HMT model. The second channel is through
the cost of capital. Where capital goods are imported an appreciation in
the real exchange rate reduces the relative price of investment goods and hence the cost of capital. This increases investment and hence the
productive capacity of the country. This effect does not appear in the
FEER calculations presented in Section 4.
The second part of overall equilibrium is 'external
balance'. Because the FEER is a medium-term concept it is not
necessary for the current account balance to be zero in equilibrium. The
UK economy has in the recent past usually run a current account deficit
and there are various reasons why this might be sustainable over the
medium term. Some structural capital inflows reflect long-term
investment in the UK and cannot be quickly reversed. This type of
substantial structural capital flows persisting into the medium term is
typified by the flow of investment into the UK by large car
manufacturers, rather than 'hot' money which seeks a
short-term home based on fluctuating overnight interest rates. The size
of these effects are difficult to quantify and deciding the proportion
of the current account disequilibrium that can be justified as
'structural' is perhaps the most fragile part of the FEER
calculation.
To help decide what the 'normal' current account balance
might be, Williamson (1991) reproduces the standard textbook identity,
namely
(X - M) = (S - I)- (G - T)
or, in words,
current account = net savings of private sector - public sector
deficit.
Therefore the equilibrium current account balance depends on the
nature of the asset equilibrium of the private sector and also on the
public sector deficit position. Implicit in the calculation of internal
balance outlined above is the existence of an asset flow equilibrium for
the private sector, but the presence of equilibrium in the goods market
does not preclude the possibility that asset stocks are changing because
invariably private sector investment differs from saving and the
government fiscal stance is not neutral. If, in the medium term, asset
stocks are changing and a country is in a position where it needs to
import or export capital then the sustainable current account need not
be in balance. Evaluating the normal private and government sector
position automatically informs us of the equilibrium current account
position.
Any change in the attitude of the government to fiscal policy in
light of the Maastricht conditions has important implications for the
asset flow equilibrium. Barrell and Sefton (1998) look at the effects on
the real exchange rate of the fiscal policy required to deliver the
conditions on debt and deficits that the European countries agreed as
part of monetary union. They calibrate a modified Mundell-Fleming model
reflecting the properties of the National Institute of Economic and
Social Research (NIESR) large-scale world model and show the
consequences of an increase in the domestic debt target. Private sector
assets return to base in the long run as there is little Ricardian
equivalence in the model and virtually all the new debt is held
overseas. The real exchange rate must depreciate to ensure that a trade
surplus is generated to match exactly the increased outflow of debt
interest payments going abroad. The policy implication from this is that
the equilibrium real exchange rate changes with the level of debt
target. If the UK is to hit a debt target of 40 per cent of GDP as
outlined by the Chancellor in his 1998 Mansion House speech, then this
implies a higher level of the FEER than that associated with a looser
fiscal policy. The belief expressed by Barrell and Sefton (1998) that
the public sector structural deficit for the UK is falling is matched by
a target current account that shows a trend from large deficit to small
surplus over the 1990s.
The current account target used by Wren-Lewis and Driver (1998) is
provided by an appendix to their paper by Williamson and Madar. Their
approach is to examine the actual data and then to adjust in response to
various factors. The current account target is determined by OECD projections of savings and investment rates, and amongst the various
factors considered are demographics, initial levels of debt stock, the
impact of inflation bias, the global current account discrepancy and
revaluation effects on asset stocks. They finally decide that the
appropriate target level for the UK current account is a deficit equal
to 0.2 per cent of GDP. Again, this is only a target in the sense that
the equilibrium level is automatically given when the normal level of
capital flows is calculated.
3. The HMT model
The version of the HMT model used in this exercise was released in
September 1996 and its properties, along with those of four other
models, are evaluated by Church et al. (1997). The data used are from
the version of the model released a year later. This model has been
chosen because it is an 'official' model and therefore is
presumably an important part of the decision-making process on whether
or not the UK should enter a monetary union and if so the exchange rate
at which this might happen.
The HMT model contains a large degree of detail describing the UK
economy. This is an advantage in situations where aggregation implies a
loss of information. For example, export and import volumes are
separated into four sectors with the relevant activity and
competitiveness measures varying across these sectors. If the volumes in
each sector evolve differently in response to diverse factors then
aggregation leads to a misspecified model. Competitiveness is typically
measured by the relationship
R = PPIO.RX/WP,
where R is a measure of the real exchange rate and PPIO, RX and WP
are domestic producer output prices, the sterling effective exchange
rate index and world prices in dollars respectively. In the HMT model
there are actually eight different real exchange rate measures, obtained
by defining world prices in this expression as in turn, manufacturing
exports prices, consumer prices, unit labour costs, commodity prices,
oil prices, agricultural prices in the EU, food prices and basic
material prices. Clearly if all these measures behave in exactly the
same way then it is possible to aggregate without loss of information.
The extent to which this is the case is demonstrated by the plots in
Chart I which shows the first three versions of R, these having most
weight in the model. They all share the sudden fall in 1992 caused by
the exit of sterling from the ERM but subsequent behaviour differs
slightly. The key measure defined in terms of manufacturing export
prices immediately appreciated sharply for a year before declining again
while the other two measures did not. Each measure is driven higher from
the middle of 1996 onwards, reflecting the strength of sterling during
this period.
Internal balance The HMT model is alone among the current vintage
of UK macroeconomic models deposited at the ESRC Macroeconomic Modelling
Bureau in having an estimate of the NAIRU which depends on the real
exchange rate. The real exchange rate is one component of the wedge
between employers' real wage costs and workers' real
consumption wages. Bean (1994) argues that the impact of any permanent
change in this wedge and hence the equilibrium level of activity has an
offsetting effect on the workers' permanent income and subsequently
their reservation wage. In other words, real wage resistance does not
persist in the long run. However Chan et al. (1995) argue that there is
empirical support for this type of long-run effect, hence its appearance
in the HMT model. The estimate of the natural rate is obtained from the
long-run solution to the supply side of the model. A stylised version of
the supply side of the HMT model which assumes capacity utilisation is
at equilibrium and ignores constant terms in the equations is given
below. All variables are in natural logs and all coefficients defined to
be positive. The wage rate is given by
w = pgdp + [pr.sup.*] - [[Alpha].sub.2]u + [[Alpha].sub.3](prx -
pgdp), (1)
where u is the log of the unemployment rate, [pr.sup.*] is trend
productivity and pgdp is the GDP deflator and is assumed to be simply
determined by unit labour costs
pgdp = (w-[pr.sup.*]), (2)
while retail prices excluding mortgage interest payments (prx) are
given by
prx = [[Beta]sub.1] (w - [pr.sup.*]) + [[Beta].sub.2]ppio + (1 -
[[Beta].sub.1] - [[Beta].sub.2]) pm (3)
where pm is import prices and ppio is producer prices whose
equation is represented by
ppio = [[Theta].sub.1]pm + (1 - [[Theta].sub.1])(w - [pr.sup.*]).
(4)
Combining equations (1)-(4) and rearranging gives an expression for
the NAIRU, namely
[u.sup.*] = -[[Alpha].sub.3]/[[Alpha].sub.2] ([[Theta].sub.1](1 -
[[Beta].sub.1])/(1 - [[Theta].sub.1]) + (1 - [[Beta].sub.1] -
[[Beta].sub.2])(ppio - pm).
From this we can see that the NAIRU decreases as the equilibrium
level of the real exchange rate (ppio-pm) increases. Given this
knowledge of how the unemployment rate changes in response to the real
exchange rate, the (exogenous) level of working population gives the
change in the number employed and this is allocated between
manufacturing and non-manufacturing proportionally given the size of the
two sectors. The equilibrium level of output in the economy is then
obtained by finding the values consistent with the employment equations
in the model. This demonstrates how, although the real exchange rate
directly influences output, the HMT model is also consistent with the
standard result from the neoclassical growth model because the
equilibrium level of output in the economy depends on the growth rate of
the working population and the rate of labour-augmenting technical
progress, the latter being represented by time trends in the labour
demand functions. External balance
The HMT model disaggregates exports and imports into four
categories: manufactures, non-manufactures, services and oil.
Export volumes depend on the appropriate measure of competitiveness
for that sector and WT a measure of the level of world trade.
X = W[T.sup.[[Theta].sub.1] [R.sup.-[[Omega].sub.2].
Import volumes depend on domestic activity Y rather than world
trade
M = [Y.sup.[[Omega].sub.1] [R.sup.[[Omega].sub.2].
The trade balance part of the current account is obtained by the
identity
CB = PX.X - PM.M,
where PX and PM are the prices of export and import goods and are
given by
PX = PPI[O[[Sigma].sub.1] P[M.sup.(1 - [[Sigma].sub.1]
and
PM = (WP/RX).
The volume and price equations over the four different sectors of
the economy are reparameterised in terms of the eight different measures
of competitiveness described earlier. For a complete description for the
current account the model of trade outlined above is insufficient as we
also need to incorporate interest, profit and dividend (IPD) flows, net
government payments to the EU and personal sector net transfers. IPD
flows depend on the level of overseas assets held by domestic residents
and by the level of domestic assets held by those abroad. As the FEER is
consistent with an asset accumulation equilibrium a fully specified
macroeconomic model would give the values of these flows. However, in
this partial equilibrium approach it is assumed that IPD flows are in
equilibrium, and they are not modelled explicitly, although the fact
that the movement of the actual real exchange rate to the FEER changes
the value of assets denominated in foreign currency is recognised and
this revaluation effect is present for IPD credits. EU payments and
transfers are not modelled but are smoothed to eliminate erratic
behaviour and to give some idea of equilibrium behaviour. The real
exchange rate can now be used to target the current account balance to
whatever are regarded as 'normal' capital flows.
4. Results
The initial results here assume that 0.2 per cent of GDP represents
a 'normal' level of the current account to GDP ratio. The
sensitivity of the results to this choice is examined in the final
simulation. The eight different measures of competitiveness are linked
together in a way that the movements in the key measure of the real
exchange rate defined in terms of the world price of manufactures are
fully reflected in each of the other definitions.
Chart 2 shows the actual and fundamental rate from the start of
1990 to the middle of 1997. A useful appraisal of the model is achieved
by examining the outcomes from around the time that sterling departed
from the ERM. The model suggests that sterling was 19.5 per cent
overvalued in the second quarter of 1992. The large fall in sterling
during the third quarter of that year ensured that the difference
between actual and fundamental closed to 10 per cent immediately after
the UK left the ERM. For some time afterwards a small overvaluation persisted but during 1995 the actual was below the fundamental rate.
This period is characterised by a fall in the actual rate but also by an
improvement in the FEER. This improvement can be traced through to the
performance of the manufacturing exports equation which substantially
overpredicts the actual volume of exports during this period. This
overprediction is associated with a sustained fall in the actual real
exchange rate. The result is an improved underlying current account and
hence the FEER has to depreciate by less in order to hit the target
deficit of 0.2 percentage points. By the second quarter of 1997 the
overvaluation had risen again to 18 per cent.
The path of the FEER slopes gently upwards over the 1990s at a rate
of about 0.5 per cent per annum. This trend component of the FEER arises
from the fitting of time trends to that part of the export and import
volume data that is not explained by the activity and competitiveness
terms. These trend terms suggest a generally improving current account
position mainly through a reduced tendency to import as time goes by.
The actual level of unemployment for most of the 1990s has been
much higher than the natural rate. Chart 3 plots the prevailing NAIRU
and the actual unemployment rate. In equilibrium, when the economy
achieves internal balance the actual rate of unemployment is equal to
the NAIRU. Clearly this implies that all the previously unemployed
workers are now in employment and producing output. The structure of the
model is such that a 1 per cent increase in employment is matched by a I
per cent increase in output. The consequence is that in equilibrium the
levels of output and domestic GDP are much higher than the actual values
of the mid-1990s. This increase in equilibrium domestic activity sucks
in imports worsening the current account. The real exchange rate must
then depreciate to make UK exports more attractive so that the extra
output can be sold abroad, bringing the current account back to target.
This decrease in the equilibrium real exchange rate also puts downward
pressure on the natural rate of activity in the economy.
The model is silent on the nature of the extra output generated in
equilibrium. If the workers removed from unemployment were assumed to be
employed in industries producing goods and services in areas where the
UK has a comparative advantage over its competitors and there is high
demand, then off-loading the extra output abroad to offset the increase
in imports and generate the equilibrium current account position might
be achieved with a fairly small reduction in the real exchange rate. If,
as seems more realistic, the extra employment was in low productivity
sectors, then the decrease in the real exchange rate required to export
the extra output would be much higher. Despite the actual current
account showing a surplus in 1996-7, the FEER still lies below the
actual real exchange rate during this period. If domestic activity had
actually been in equilibrium, the higher level of demand implies more
imports. The improvement in the current account observed in 1996-7
reflects import volumes being below trend. The overall underlying
position for the UK economy appears to be a current account deficit that
exceeds 1 per cent of GDP.
A partial simulation on the model indicates that a 1 per cent
increase in the equilibrium real exchange rate delivers a fall in the
NAIRU of about 0.2 percentage points. This feature of the model relies
on the assumption that the level of the real exchange rate affects the
wage bargain. This is not a feature of most large-scale macroeconomic
models and the sensitivity of this link can be judged by simply setting
[[Alpha].sub.3] = 0 in the wage equation and then recalculating the
intercept term in the relationship. Because of this adjustment the NAIRU
estimate in this variant is not directly comparable with the previous
case. As Chart 4 confirms, the real exchange rate no longer influences
the NAIRU and the estimate of the natural rate is now a constant 6.8 per
cent. This change increases the gap between equilibrium and actual real
exchange rate over the early part of the 1990s. The major difference
that this change to the model makes is that previously the depreciation
in the FEER put downward pressure on the equilibrium level of domestic
utilisation and hence the response of imports.
Without this link the FEER must fall slightly more to generate the
required improvement in the current account as shown in Chart 5.
The calculation of the NAIRU in this model is heavily dependent on
the econometric estimates of parameters in the wage equation,
particularly the intercept term and the coefficient on the log of the
unemployment rate. As a degree of uncertainty surrounds these
econometric estimates and because there are several other methods of
calculating the NAIRU which give conflicting answers, it is important to
examine the sensitivity of the FEER estimate to changes in the
'natural' rate. Chart 6 shows the FEER paths for NAIRUs that
are 1 percentage point either side of the baseline case. When the NAIRU
is 1 percentage point lower as shown by the line FEER-, employment,
output and imports are higher and the FEER must depreciate in order to
generate the extra exports required to give current account equilibrium.
The fall in the FEER itself is around 1.9 per cent, increasing the gap
between the actual real exchange rate and FEER in the second quarter of
1992 to 22.0 per cent and in the second quarter of 1997 to 20.7 per
cent. If the NAIRU is actually 1 percentage point higher than our
central estimate, the FEER is shown by line FEER+, and the overvaluation
in the second quarters of 1992 and 1997 is reduced to 17.1 per cent and
16.4 per cent respectively.
Arguably the most important piece of sensitivity analysis revolves
around the choice of target for the current account, which is possibly
the most fragile part of the FEER calculation. The target in the
previous experiments was a deficit of 0.2 per cent of nominal GDP, but
given that the UK economy has routinely, over a period