The stability pact: safeguarding the credibility of the European Central Bank.
Artis, Michael ; Winkler, Bernhard
I. Introduction
Based on a proposal by the German finance minister, Theo Waigel,
first launched in November 1995, the Stability and Growth Pact agreed at
the Dublin Summit of 13-14 December 1996 and finalized in Amsterdam on
16 June 1997 seeks to enforce fiscal discipline. inside EMU by
strengthening, clarifying and speeding-up the 'excessive deficit
procedure' of the Maastricht Treaty; and by building in
quasi-automatic sanctions to penalize countries found in excessive
deficit.
The central features of the Stability Pact provisions regarding the
decision procedures, the timing and the size of sanctions are examined
in the next section (Section II) of this paper. In order to form a
balanced judgement on the usefulness (or otherwise) of the Stability
Pact it is necessary to understand the rationale behind it. Reactions to
the Maastricht fiscal criteria, both as an entry condition for EMU and
as a permanent constraint to be enforced by the Stability Pact inside
Stage Three of EMU, can be classified into three main groups. The first
group welcomes the discipline the criteria impose on policymakers and is
concerned about limiting negative spillovers from irresponsible fiscal
policies inside EMU; we review these arguments in Section III of the
paper. The second group - on the contrary - worries about the costs of
restricting the flexibility of fiscal policy. Both arguments together
give rise to a (familiar) debate over the relative virtues of rules
versus discretion (or credibility versus flexibility), here applied to
fiscal policy. Section IV of the paper presents a stylized model of the
Stability Pact to show that it need not necessarily compromise
macroeconomic stabilization. While most of the debate has been dominated
by the first two groups, the main inspiration for the fiscal criteria
really has been to aid the European Central Bank in its pursuit of price
stability, as we argue in Section V.
The three different views on the Stability Pact can easily be
traced to the respective theoretical frameworks used to assess the role
of the fiscal criteria. From the perspective of traditional (Keynesian)
macroeconomics and optimum currency area (OCA) theory the suggestion
that fiscal policy should be restricted appears to be the opposite of
what is required, since fiscal policy is the only remaining national
policy instrument. This line of argument has led to the prevalently
critical attitude towards the Maastricht fiscal provisions in the
economics profession. Arguments in favour of deficit and debt ceilings
are usually drawn from political economy or public choice approaches
that identify a deficit bias in political decision making processes. In
this perspective the Maastricht provisions are useful to help achieve a
reduction in deficits and debt desirable in its own right and
independently of EMU. Besides drawing on the debate over rules versus
discretion the discussion of the Maastricht fiscal provisions can also
be approached from the perspective of the literature on international
policy coordination. If there are fiscal policy spillovers across
countries and in a common capital market, deficit ceilings might be seen
as a rule-based partial substitute for fiscal policy coordination inside
EMU.
None of the above purely fiscal arguments adequately reflects the
primary purpose of the Maastricht criteria and the Stability Pact. In
the words of the president of the European Monetary Institute Alexandre
Lamfalussy (1997) the Maastricht provisions help countries to
"exercise concerted discipline in the conduct of their fiscal
management ... to minimize the risk of an adverse policy mix and an
excessive burden on monetary policy". Any attempt to capture the
motivation for the Stability Pact and the Maastricht fiscal criteria
must therefore focus on the interaction of fiscal and monetary policy.
The premise here is that central bank independence alone is not
sufficient for the credibility of monetary policy but requires the
support of a generalized "stability culture" (Winkler 1996)
and of fiscal discipline in particular. Furthermore, the crucial problem
of policy coordination arises between (national and aggregate European)
fiscal policies and the common monetary policy, rather than across
national fiscal authorities alone.
II. The Provisions of the Stability Pact
The legal background
The declared purpose of the Stability and Growth Pact is to provide
"both for prevention and deterrence" in securing budgetary
discipline (European Council 1997, Annex I, II and III). In order to
understand the motivation and the legal construction of the Stability
Pact it is important to recall that the Maastricht Treaty not only makes
accession to EMU conditional on convergence as measured by the
well-known convergence criteria but also commits countries joining EMU
to avoid "excessive deficits" thereafter. At the root of the
Stability Pact lies the perception that the procedures and the
possibility of sanctions already incorporated in the Maastricht Treaty
would prove insufficient and impractical for securing budgetary
discipline once the threat of exclusion from EMU was removed after 1999.
The original German proposal of concluding a separate treaty among EMU
participants was quickly discarded, since it was argued to require a
risky and lengthy ratification process and also would have introduced an
undesirable additional legal divide between the "Ins" and the
"Outs". Therefore the Stability Pact had to build on the
existing Treaty provisions, which it could not supersede but only
complement.
This explains the peculiar legal construction of the Stability Pact
which consists of three separate components, a European Council
Resolution and two Council Regulations. The European Council Resolution
on the Stability and Growth Pact (Council Resolution 97/C 236/01, see
Appendix A) "solemnly invites all parties, namely the Member
States, the Council and the Commission, to implement the Treaty and the
Stability and Growth Pact in a strict and timely manner" and
"provides firm political guidance" (para. IV.), but - unlike
the Council Regulations - without being legally binding. Essentially,
the Resolution is a self-commitment device to take certain decisions and
vote in a certain way within the procedures envisaged by the original
Maastricht Treaty. In particular, the commitment to keep medium-term
budgetary positions close to balance or in surplus and the
"automaticity" of sanctions for violations of the 3 per cent
deficit ceiling rest solely on a political declaration with no immediate
legal force and without abrogating the elements of qualitative judgement
contained in the Treaty.
The Council Regulation on the strengthening of the surveillance of
budgetary positions and the surveillance and coordination of economic
policies (Council Regulation (EC) No. 1466/97) builds on Article 103 of
the Maastricht Treaty and represents the prevention element of the
Stability Pact. It requires euro members to annually and publicly
present "stability programmes", while non-euro members submit
annual "convergence programmes" specifying medium-term
budgetary objectives. The Council, on recommendation of the Commission,
gives an opinion on the programmes, monitors their implementation and
can pass recommendations that may be made public.
The Council Regulation on speeding up and clarifying the
implementation of the excessive deficit procedure (Council Regulation
(EC) No. 1467/97, see Appendix B) - together with the Resolution -
mainly represents the deterrence elements of the Pact. It seeks to
render more precise the definition of an excessive deficit given in
Article 104c(2a) 2nd indent, which allows for breaches of the 3 per cent
criterion if they are "exceptional", "temporary" and
if the deficit remains "close" to the reference value, thereby
reducing the flexibility and degree of discretion of the original
Treaty. It also specifies the nature of sanctions and the procedures and
timing of their imposition in order to deter excessive deficits.
The mechanics
We now turn to a consideration of the mechanics of the procedures
involved, with a view to establishing how effective - and how flexible -
they are likely to be. The important elements are the timing and size of
the sanctions envisaged, the circumstances under which exceptions are
granted and the degree of discretion in the application of sanctions.
The size of sanctions must be of an order that serves as an effective ex
ante deterrent but without being so severe as to render the control of
public finances too difficult ex post. The Pact envisages that these
sanctions (see Appendix B) would comprise a fixed element equal to 0.2
per cent of GDP plus a variable element equal to one tenth of the
difference between the deficit ratio and the 3 per cent reference value.
To begin with (see below) the sanctions would take the form of a
non-interest-bearing deposit, only later that of an outright
'fine'. In this context it is important to note the
potentially destabilizing effects that could arise from the interaction
of the sanctions and the reactions of financial markets to the
imposition of fines. In fact the financial penalties that could be
exacted by the bond market in the form of higher interest payments may
easily be much larger than those arising from the Pact itself (Thumann,
1997): perhaps for this reason the size of the latter is limited to a
ceiling value of 0.5 per cent of GDP.
With respect to the time frame, five components can be
distinguished counting from the date (March 1) when national deficit
data are transmitted to the Commission. First, the decision time for the
Council upon recommendation from the Commission amounts to three months.
Then the Member State has four months to react to Council
recommendations by announcing corrective action, which, second, leads to
the excessive deficit procedure being held "in abeyance".
Third, if and when the procedure is resumed, a further three months can
elapse before sanctions are imposed. In the case of defiance of Council
recommendations from the start (ie without intermittent abeyance)
sanctions must be imposed within 10 months (ie within the same calendar
year, counting from March 1). Fourth, "unless there are special
circumstances" the Member State is expected to have corrected the
excessive deficit in the year following its identification. Therefore,
in cases where countries pay "lip-service" to Council
recommendations but the measures taken turn out to have been
ineffective, a full two years will have passed until hard data are
available (again March 1), plus up to another three months until
sanctions are decided. Fifth, an additional two years pass before a
non-interest bearing deposit "should be" transformed into a
fine.
The second set of issues regards the exceptions granted and the
degree of discretion. The first thing to note is that whilst the
Stability Pact gives tighter definitions of the "exceptional"
and "temporary" escape clauses of Article 104c(2a) of the
Maastricht Treaty it is not any more clear on what is to be meant by
"close to the reference value". In case of exceptionally
severe recessions exceeding a 2 per cent annual output loss, sanctions
will be waived. According to Eichengreen (1997), who considers output
declines over four quarters, such deep recessions have only occurred
thirteen times over the last 30 years in the 15 EU countries. However,
the Stability Pact has opened a window of discretion for output declines
falling in between 0.75 per cent and 2 per cent, which are much more
frequent, and for which special circumstances can be pleaded.
Considering annual changes Buti et al (1997) have counted 7 cases (5
distinct episodes) of real GDP declines exceeding 2 per cent in the
1961-1996 period for all 15 EU countries, and 30 cases (25 separate
episodes) in the case of the 0.75 per cent limit.
Note that the 2 per cent reference value is included in the Council
regulation and has therefore stronger legal status, whereas the 0.75 per
cent rule is based on self-commitment by the Member States. Both values
are applied "as a rule", ie are not strictly automatic, and
they do not supersede the possibility under Article 104c (3) and (6)
that other factors will be taken into account in the decision on whether
a deficit is excessive. Inside the corridor of discretion, for output
losses between 0.75 per cent and 2 per cent, two additional decision
criteria are mentioned explicitly, "the abruptness of the
downturn" and "the cumulated output loss relative to past
trends".
Qualified majority voting
Where there is room for interpretation, the voting dynamics of the
Ecofin Council become decisive. The imposition of sanctions requires a
qualified majority where the country in question is excluded together
with euro-outsiders. However, the prior decision on whether an excessive
deficit exists, according to Article 104c (6) of the Maastricht Treaty,
is voted by qualified majority of all Member States under Article 148
(2), ie including the country under examination and even including
euro-outsiders. This means that a blocking minority of 26 votes (for
example Italy, Spain, Portugal and Greece have 28 votes) could prevent
the excessive deficit procedure getting off the ground in the first
place, even if there should be a qualified majority of insiders in
favour of the imposition of sanctions.
For the decision on sanctions (voted only by euro-insiders,
excluding the country under examination) the size of the monetary union
matters. Eichengreen (1997) suspects that the application of the
Stability Pact will be more rigid in a large EMU as a counterweight to
the perceived greater (inflation) pressures on the ECB. On the other
hand, the presence of fiscally less disciplined countries should affect
the voting behaviour of Ecofin in the opposite direction.
Since a vote on the imposition of sanctions is always required,
even outside the "corridor of discretion" concerning
exceptional recessions, the practical question for the operation of the
Stability Pact depends on how seriously the declaration of intent on
future voting behaviour, the "solemn invitation" to the strict
and timely application of the Stability Pact, is to be taken. Moreover,
the wording of the Pact itself suggests additional room for discretion,
since the numerical values and sanctions are only to be applied "as
a rule". Both the question of legal enforcement - according to
Article 104c(10) of the Maastricht Treaty violations of the fiscal
provisions in Article 104c(1-9) cannot be brought before the European
Court of Justice - and political realism would lead one to predict a
much more pragmatic application of the Stability Pact than the focus on
rules and numbers suggests. Finance ministers may well be reluctant to
impose sanctions on colleagues, possibly knowing that they themselves
may well soon end up in the same situation. In particular, voting
behaviour is likely to reflect not only the absolute 3 per cent
reference value but the relative budgetary positions of partner
countries (and their probabilities of also breaching the deficit
ceiling). A relative performance application of the Stability Pact could
in fact be desirable if the fact that many countries are in difficulties
is due to a common adverse shock and not a sign of a generalized lack of
discipline. The drawback is the opportunity for countries to collude in
order to escape the discipline of the 3 per cent ceiling (Winkler,
1997b).
III. The Stability Pact and Fiscal Policy
Constraints on fiscal policy, such as the deficit ceiling of the
Stability Pact, can be useful if in their absence deficits would tend to
be excessive from the national or the international (here: European)
point of view. In both cases, the benefits of commitment to rules or
deficit ceilings must be weighed against the potential losses from
reduced flexibility of fiscal policy in stabilizing economic shocks, as
discussed in Section IV.
Countering domestic deficit bias
Many proponents of the Stability Pact regard it as a valuable
external commitment technology - desirable in its own right - in the
face of unsatisfactory domestic political budget processes. The simplest
story, put forward most forcefully by public choice theorists (Buchanan
1977, Olson 1965), draws on the observation that special interests
pushing for public expenditure programmes are generally well-organized,
unlike taxpayers. Moreover, future taxpayers are not represented at all
in the democratic process, which favours the build-up of public debt to
be repaid by future generations and may also lead politicians to ignore
the negative long-run growth effects of deficits via the crowding out of
productive private investment. Government instability and a host of
other political and institutional factors can be used to explain why the
public finance performance of political systems has differed widely
across countries (Alesina and Perotti 1995, Roubini and Sachs 1989,
Grilli et al 1991, Corsetti and Roubini 1993) and has produced a debt
build-up in most of Europe over the past two decades, which is widely
regarded as excessive (Masson 1996). For this argument to provide
support for the Stability Pact, though, one would have to find that
Monetary Union in some way would increase the domestic deficit bias.
In fact, the effects of monetary union on the incentives of fiscal
policymakers can go in both directions. On the one hand, the long-run
budget constraint facing governments is hardened to the extent that the
Maastricht Treaty's "no-bail-out clause" is credible and
monetary financing of government debt by the European Central Bank is
ruled out (Glick and Hutchison 1993). On the other hand, access to
financing will be easier in the unified European capital market and
(presumably) cheaper for high debt and deficit countries no longer
suffering national interest rate premia for devaluation and inflation
risk. Abolishing national currencies removes the disciplining effect of
international currency markets on national fiscal policies (Thygesen
1996), even though bond markets may be expected to remain a powerful
deterrent (provided that the "no-bail-out clause" is perceived
as credible).
The trust in bond markets exerting sufficient discipline on fiscal
policies inside EMU and thus obviating the need for additional fiscal
constraints can be challenged on two grounds. First, default
probabilities and therefore risk premia are unlikely to be sizeable
enough to act as an effective deterrent ex ante, as long as countries
retain sufficient taxing powers and control of tax bases to continue
servicing their debt (Eichengreen and von Hagen 1996). Second, market
reactions and political crises in response to fiscal problems tend to be
discontinuous, ie provoke a sudden and abrupt withdrawal of confidence
which is difficult and costly to deal with ex post and thus may
undermine the credibility of the no-bail-out clause ex ante (thus
reducing risk premia) especially if financial market instability
threatens to spill over across the euro-area. For these reasons it
remains doubtful that market discipline can be effective in offsetting a
domestic political deficit bias or in preventing possible adverse
effects on partner countries, as discussed below.
Coordinating fiscal policies
The main channels through which national fiscal policies affect
partner countries in EMU are via import demand, the common interest
rates, the common exchange rate and the stability of the financial
system. The case for the Stability Pact as a proxy for fiscal policy
coordination first requires that spillovers from fiscal expansions and
debt build-up would tend to be negative and that monetary union would
aggravate any such spillovers. The short-run effects from fiscal
expansions on foreign output should be positive and, in a standard
Mundell-Fleming model, should be smaller under fixed exchange rates. The
effects on the common real interest rate, and therefore the crowding out
of partner countries' investment, should be negligible to the
extent that individual borrowers are small relative to the European (and
world) capital market. Moreover, the interest rate link represents a
pecuniary externality and therefore would not call for a centralized intervention on welfare grounds (Buiter et al 1993). The justification
for the 3 per cent ceiling on actual rather than primary or structural
deficits as the relevant "expression of the burden on financial
markets" (Thygesen 1996) is therefore not convincing by itself.
A third externality arises from effects of fiscal expansions on the
common external exchange rate, which - in the short run - should
appreciate, thus crowding out partner countries' net exports. In
the long-run the build-up of debt would tend to lead to a lower real
exchange rate. Again, the effects from any individual national fiscal
policy path on the common exchange rate should be relatively small
compared to the influence of the single monetary policy and the question
of the aggregate policy-mix addressed in Section V.
A fourth possible channel of fiscal spillovers arises if an
increase in default risk in a member country or a subsequent financial
crisis cannot be confined to the country in question but leads to
expectations of an explicit or implicit bail-out or a systemic financial
crisis across the common capital market. In this perspective the
Stability Pact could be helpful in reducing possible systemic risks from
sovereign debt default inside EMU. However, it would be more appropriate
to limit bank exposure to sovereign debt, to strengthen European banking
supervision in general and to clarify the lender-of-last-resort
functions at the national and European levels.
On the whole, most of the spillovers of fiscal policies are not
strongly related to monetary union per se but rather rest on the degree
of trade or financial market integration (Eichengreen and von Hagen
1996). Moreover, strategic interaction with the rest of the world
complicates the picture further (Eichengreen and Ghironi 1997) and
intra-European fiscal policy coordination may not be desirable given
that both monetary and fiscal policies remain uncoordinated with the
rest of the world.
IV. The Stability Pact and Fiscal Stabilization
Fiscal stabilization under EMU
Whatever the rationale for the Maastricht criteria and the
Stability Pact there is a potential price to be paid for satisfying
their rigid numerical limits. This price comes in the form of lost
flexibility in the use of active fiscal policy or in the operation of
the built-in automatic stabilizers of national budgets and has been the
major source of criticism of the fiscal criteria. Two aspects of
stabilization can be distinguished conceptually, intra-union
stabilization in response to asymmetric shocks and pan-European
responses to common shocks.
The debate over fiscal federalism examines the question where
stabilization mechanisms should be located, ie whether at the European
or at the national level (eg Melitz and Vori 1992, von Hagen and Hammond
1995). It is obvious that a European-wide stabilization scheme is
superior in principle since it provides insurance across countries at
any point in time, whereas national stabilization has to rely on debt
build-up for consumption-smoothing over time. If there are significant
Ricardian effects, national fiscal stabilization may be less powerful to
the extent that consumption is reduced in the expectation of a higher
future tax burden (Bayoumi and Masson 1996). However, empirically
Ricardian effects are likely to be small, especially if deficits are
perceived to be strictly temporary. The issue then hinges on the
question to what extent capital market imperfections impede private
agents and national governments from lending and borrowing in order to
achieve consumption-smoothing over time (Gros 1996). Again, integrated
financial markets and EMU should make access to credit easier for
governments (eg the balance of payments constraint is removed) and thus
facilitate national stabilization policies.
However, a European-wide scheme could be attractive for another
reason since it may be able to stabilize intra-union shocks
automatically and in a way that leaves the aggregate fiscal stance
unaltered. Unfortunately, there are serious design problems in a
centralized insurance scheme which relate to the difficulty of
separating out temporary and permanent shocks (and therefore insurance
from redistribution issues) and to problems of moral hazard. In any
case, the Maastricht construction does not call for an expansion of the
central European budget nor the installation of a European-wide fiscal
co-insurance mechanism.
Empirical research on fiscal federalism has looked at the
experience of federal states such as the US, where the federal budget
does perform a sizeable stabilization function in the order of 20 per
cent of income shocks in most of the more recent studies (eg Bayoumi and
Masson 1995). This does not necessarily imply that the same
stabilization function could not be performed equally effectively at the
state level. In the US, State budget policies are both less important
for stabilization and more severely constrained than in European
countries. Moreover, the size of the state sector and the volume of
welfare and unemployment benefits is generally much greater in Europe
and therefore national automatic stabilizers should be more powerful
(Allsopp and Vines 1996). Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1995) have estimated
the elasticity of the central government revenue/GDP ratio with respect
to output to be in the order of 0.30.5 for a number of European
countries, as a measure of the fraction of changes in disposable income that is offset by changes in government revenues. Buti et al (1997) find
that the cyclical sensitivity of the budget balance for Europe as a
whole is around 0.5 per cent (increase in the deficit in response to a
deterioration of the output gap of 1 per cent).
The second issue, therefore, is to examine how well-equipped
national fiscal policy would be to perform stabilization within monetary
union, ie how necessary and how effective national fiscal stabilization
will be in EMU. The main concern from the stabilization and OCA
perspective is that the Stability Pact could hamper the operation of
automatic stabilizers at the national level, just when they are most
needed. In particular, the fear is that in a recession countries will be
induced to undertake "perverse" procyclical measures in order
to avoid hitting the 3 per cent deficit ceiling. The main recommendation
from this line of argument is to formulate any deficit targets in terms
of structural deficits or "constant-employment budget balance"
(Eichengreen 1997) rather than actual deficits. The problem with the
NAIRU-adjusted deficit targets, besides disputes about measurement, is
that they provide no reassurance about the long-run sustainability of
public finances, unlike the medium-run budget balance aim of the Pact.
The Stability Pact as an Incentive Device
How much of a constraint on fiscal stabilization the Stability Pact
turns out to be depends, of course, on the average, structural, deficits
that countries aim for, on the size of shocks and whether countries will
decide to honour the 3 per cent ceiling in a recession or not.
Under uncertainty governments will equate the marginal cost of
undertaking fiscal adjustment with the marginal benefit of reducing the
risk of incurring penalties under the Stability Pact (Winkler, 1997a).
Rational governments optimizing ex ante, will aim for a deficit much
below the 3 per cent as a "cushion" against subsequent
unfavourable shocks. If countries react to the Stability Pact in this
way, automatic stabilizers need not necessarily be compromised as feared
by Eichengreen (1997), in particular in view of the Stability
Pact's exceptions in the event of unusually large shocks. The 3 per
cent ceiling on the actual deficit could induce behaviour not much
different from a target on structural deficits. The main difference is
that countries can choose their target structural deficit for
themselves, ie the optimal size of their "cushion" depending
on their own preferences. Likewise, the choice of the nature and
instruments of fiscal adjustment is left to the individual countries.
The criticism of the 3 per cent target as arbitrary and
"one-size-fits-all" (Eichengreen 1997) is therefore only
partially justified. Moreover, the same criticism would equally apply to
the alternative suggestions of NAIRU-adjusted deficit targets or a
centrally-imposed reform of national budget procedures proposed by yon
Hagen and Harden (1994).
Moreover, the Stability Pact explicitly calls on countries to keep
their medium term budgetary positions close to balance or in surplus and
if "the structural deficit is close to zero ... the operation of
automatic stabilizers should still be available" (Lamfalussy 1997).
Over the course of normal business cycle fluctuations the difference
between actual and structural deficits is unlikely to exceed 3 per cent
very frequently. Masson (1996) has calculated a standard deviation of
ca. 2 per cent, suggesting that aiming for 1 per cent deficits or below
might be sufficient. Eichengreen (1997) reports cases where European
countries have experienced shifts in their fiscal positions exceeding 3
per cent, ie implying a violation of the Maastricht ceiling under the
assumption that countries start out in fiscal balance, for four EU
countries in the mid-70s, one country in the early 80s and five
countries in the early 1990s. This inspires reasonable confidence that
the Stability Pact need not be unduly restrictive in the face of
"normal"-size business cycles.
The real question therefore becomes whether the Stability
Pact's target range for structural deficits is desirable, realistic
and credible and what happens in the early days of EMU if countries
should enter with deficits right up against the 3 per cent ceiling and
even without their economies being in the trough of a recession. A
common line of defence for the Maastricht fiscal criteria is the
argument that a substantial reduction in structural deficits and debt is
required independently of EMU in particular in view of demographic
trends in Europe (Masson 1996). From this reasoning prudent governments
would be well-advised to perhaps even aim for budget surpluses on
average in the coming decades. In this perspective the 3 per cent
deficit ceiling does not appear to be excessively ambitious at all.
Moreover, turning the critics' argument on its head, it has been
argued that fiscal consolidation might be necessary precisely in order
to regain the room for manoeuvre that allows automatic stabilizers to
operate effectively. In the pre-EMU situation of a number of countries
(eg Italy with deficits close to 10 per cent of GDP for much of the
1980s) market fears of further deterioration in public finances already
effectively curtailed both the advisability and the effectiveness of
letting automatic stabilizers operate fully. According to Buti et al
(1997, p.13) EU countries with above-average pre-recession debt and
deficits actually have pursued pro-cyclical policies in the past,
reducing structural primary deficits in recessions by 1.2 per cent of
GDP on average.
Put in this perspective the trade-off between discipline and
flexibility disappears, at least in the long-run, and the debate really
is one about the transition period in the run-up to EMU and in the early
years of Stage Three. Even here it has been argued that fiscal
retrenchment need not always compromise output, especially if it
restores confidence in public finances over the longer term (Giavazzi
and Pagano 1991, Bertola and Drazen 1991, IMF 1995) - though the
empirical evidence for "anti-Keynesian" effects appears to be
mixed at best (Cour et al 1996, Hughes-Hallett and McAdam 1996). For
high debt countries EMU-entry by itself should improve the fiscal
outlook even in the short term via a reduction in the interest burden.
The obvious way to reduce the risk of the Stability Pact imposing
excessive constraints on fiscal stabilization in the early years of EMU
is, of course, to insist on strict entry conditions and large enough
safety margins for EMU participants from the start. It is important to
recall that the Treaty not only establishes numerical reference values for the fiscal criteria but emphasizes the need for the sustainability
of budgetary positions. The same point has been emphasized in the
resolution of the German parliament from 2.12.1992 stating that
compliance with the criteria must not only be statistical, but
"durable" and "credible" (Deutscher Bundestag 1992).
This could be read as being much like a condition on structural deficits
which should prevent countries with a high risk of subsequently
violating the 3 per cent ceiling from joining in the first place.
V. The Stability Pact and Monetary Policy
The considerations reviewed in the previous section may all be
relevant for the cost-benefit analysis of the Stability Pact but they do
not reflect the principal motive of the insertion of the fiscal criteria
in the Maastricht Treaty, which is to facilitate the ECB's primary
task of achieving low and stable inflation. The relevant spillovers in
this perspective regard the negative effects of undisciplined fiscal
policy on the incentives, credibility and performance of the common
monetary policy. As is stated in para. 18 of Annex 1 of the Presidency
conclusions of the Dublin summit (Ecofin 1996):
"Sound government finances are crucial to preserving stable
economic conditions in the Member States and in the Community. They
lessen the burden on monetary policy and contribute to low and stable
inflationary expectations such that interest rates can be expected to be
low."
The primary task of the Stability Pact is to safeguard the
credibility of monetary policy both in the long term (by preventing
excessive public debt build-up) and in the short run by keeping deficits
in check and thereby reducing the risk of imbalances in the
macroeconomic policy mix. Contrary to the presumption in the standard
literature on the credibility of monetary policy and virtues of central
bank independence (Rogoff 1985a, Walsh 1995) monetary policy does not
operate in a vacuum. First, as pointed out by McCallum (1995), Jensen
(1997) and Lohmann (1996), the commitment to delegate monetary policy
must itself be credible. Second, even independent central banks depend
critically on the support from fiscal and wage policies and the general
public (Eijffinger and De Haan 1996) if they are to deliver low
inflation at low real economic costs. These considerations mean that
there is reason to be concerned about the likely performance of the
European Central Bank - despite the legal independence it will enjoy,
despite its explicit statutory commitment to the goal of price stability
and despite the fact that it will face a fragmented set of fiscal
players rather than a single Ministry of Finance. For it will not have
its own stock of reputation on which to draw, nor can it count on
receiving the necessary backing from the European public and the
European economic policy process.
Consider the simple illustration of monetary-fiscal policy
interaction in Figure 1. Payoffs are arbitrary and chosen to capture the
benefits from fiscal and monetary policy paths being coordinated in the
short run and mutually consistent in the long run. Conversely, if
policymakers are on a collision course payoffs are much lower. For
example, a lax fiscal policy combined with tight money leads to an
unbalanced policy mix, high interest rates, currency appreciation and
output losses. Note that both sides have an incentive to fall in line.
Faced with lax fiscal policy, the monetary authorities will in the end
be forced to accommodate and, likewise, when facing a tough ECB fiscal
authorities will "chicken out" and accept discipline.
Figure 1: A Game of Chicken
Fiscal Authorities
tight policy lax policy
ECB tight policy 4, 2 -1, -1
lax policy 0, 0 1, 3
There are two Nash equilibria in the game of Figure 1. The central
bank prefers the "tight" equilibrium (top-left) with tight
monetary and fiscal policies, whereas fiscal authorities prefer the
"lax" outcome (bottom-right) with relaxed policies. The
payoffs are as in the standard "game of chicken" (except here
we make the tight equilibrium the socially more attractive one), where
players have an incentive to coordinate their actions but differ over
the preferred outcome and therefore each side would like to precommit in
advance. Depending on which side gains strategic leadership in this way,
we can distinguish two regimes, "monetary dominance" and
"fiscal dominance" in the terminology of Canzoneri and Diba
(1996).
The game can be given economic interpretations both with respect to
the long-run or the short-run strategic interaction between monetary and
fiscal policymakers, as discussed in the following subsections. The
long-run interpretation focuses on the intertemporal government budget
constraint and the credibility of low inflation and no-bail-out
promises. The short-run interpretation looks at the issue of the
appropriate policy mix for macroeconomic stabilization. The Maastricht
criteria can be seen as an attempt to secure pre-commitment to the
monetary dominance regime, ie select the better of the two possible
equilibria and in particular to avoid costly conflict (leadership
battles) between monetary and fiscal policy.
Long-run credibility
A first link between fiscal and monetary variables can be
established even in a simple Barro-Gordon (1983) framework. As stressed
by De Grauwe (1996) the presence of nominal (long-term) debt undermines
the central bank's anti-inflation incentives, because of the
temptation to inflate away the stock of debt. His policy recommendations
are either to suspend the voting rights of the representatives of high
debt countries on the ECB board or to issue short term debt. The former
solution runs against the spirit of the ECB as being an independent and
collegiate European institution, the latter has the drawback of
undermining ECB credibility in the short run, as public finances become
more vulnerable to variations in short term interest rates.
More generally, monetary and fiscal policy are linked via the
intertemporal government budget constraint, which says that a stream of
expenditures can be financed via taxes, issuing bonds or printing money.
Here a regime of "fiscal dominance" would mean that the
government can precommit to a path of net deficits and thus ultimately
force the central bank to inflate in order to avoid insolvency as in the
"unpleasant monetarist arithmetic" of Sargent and Wallace
(1981). Under "monetary dominance" the central bank can commit
not to inflate (no explicit or implicit bail-out) and thus force the
government to adjust its path of spending and taxes as in the
"unpleasant fiscal arithmetic" of Winckler et al (1996).
In the model of Canzoneri and Diba (1996) in a regime of fiscal
dominance the fiscal authorities do not respect the implications of the
intertemporal budget constraint, which leads to current inflation
irrespective of the central bank's monetary policy. The price level
will then be determined by the present value government budget
constraint, "by the dictates of fiscal solvency", and not by
the supply and demand for money (Woodford 1995). This can happen even if
the monetary authorities ignore the path of debt completely (eg only
care about inflation) as long as fiscal policymakers do not follow a
"Ricardian fiscal policy rule" (Woodford 1996), that offsets
any change in debt exactly by a compensating change in the present value
of future government surpluses. Under monetary dominance, by contrast,
fiscal authorities conform to their long-run budget constraint and
therefore the central bank is undisturbed in achieving its inflation
target and enjoys "functional independence". The latter regime
requires that primary surpluses respond to the level of debt in a
systematic way.
Whether an economy finds itself in a monetary or fiscal dominance
regime depends on financial markets' beliefs about whether primary
surpluses will respond fast enough to rising government debt. A deficit
rule, like the one endorsed by Maastricht and the Stability Pact, can be
shown to ensure this responsiveness and thus establish monetary
dominance and the "functional" as opposed to "legal"
independence of the ECB. From this perspective the Stability Pact seems
right in focusing on deficits rather than debt. However, large stocks of
debt may reduce the credibility of the deficit rule if the required
primary surpluses become too large. A debt criterion may still be
important for this reason and also as a safeguard against manipulations
of the deficit figures, which sooner or later require stock-flow
adjustments and show up in the level of debt.
There are a number of other papers that have explored the
fiscal-monetary policy interaction that could be interpreted to underpin
a situation as in Figure 1 in more detail such as Mourmouras and
Su's (1995) differential debt stabilization game, Beetsma and
Bovenberg (1995a, b) and Beetsma and Uhlig (1997) who focus on
seigniorage and government myopia as causes for a debt bias and
justifications for fiscal constraints to complement central bank
independence. The picture is complicated in models that introduce fiscal
policy coordination issues on top of the fiscal-monetary interaction as
in Jensen (1996), Bryson et al (1993) and Levine and Pearlman (1992). In
such settings fiscal coordination may be bad if the common monetary
policy lacks credibility with the private sector. This mirrors an
earlier result by Rogoff (1985b) showing that coordination of a subset
of players can be counterproductive. In other words, in a second best
world, removing one distortion in the presence of another may make
matters worse. If the central bank cannot precommit, fiscal coordination
would reduce the credibility of the central bank further, supporting the
Maastricht choice of fiscal constraints rather than full-fledged fiscal
coordination.
Agell et al (1996) have a version of the coordination cum
commitment story with a more Keynesian flavour, ie not based on the
inflation tax as the link between fiscal and monetary policy (which
arguably is of scant empirical relevance). The government faces an ex
ante trade-off between stimulating economic activity and containing
budget deficits. It may or may not heed the intertemporal budget
constraint, while for the monetary authorities both discretion and
commitment via permanently fixed exchange rates (monetary union) is
considered. Under discretion both inflation and deficits will be high,
ie the situation of a wage-devaluation cycle with debt build-up. Under
monetary union inflation will be low, but the deficit bias is worsened,
which provides a case for introducing fiscal constraints when moving to
EMU.
Our contention is that the Stability Pact can be seen as a means of
strengthening the independence of the ECB and its ability to resist
pressures to ease monetary policy (Masson, 1996).
Short-term credibility and policy-mix
Critics of the Stability Pact have argued that "discipline is
a long-term issue" and that, if anything, restrictions should be
placed on the debt stock rather than on current deficits (Pisani-Ferry
1996). From the Canzoneri-Diba (1996) perspective of the previous
subsection, by contrast, what matters is the responsiveness of current
deficits to a debt build-up and therefore a deficit rule can be
sufficient. Discipline becomes a short-term issue because the long-run
deficit-debt dynamics can affect inflation expectations and current
inflation directly.
In addition to the long-run compatibility of fiscal and monetary
policy paths as reflected in the interaction via the intertemporal
government budget constraint, the choice of policy-mix also becomes
important in short-term macroeconomic management. Conflicts between
fiscal and monetary authorities can be very costly, as the episodes of
Reagonomics in the early 1980s and in the wake of German unification
demonstrate. In terms of Figure 1 a lax fiscal policy stance confronted
with tight monetary policy gives rise to a leadership battle, where each
side tries to secure its preferred equilibrium. The long but unbalanced
struggle of many European economies to regain stability over the course
of the 1980s also illustrates the costs of an unbalanced policy mix
(Allsopp and Vines 1996, p. 97), resulting from a credibility bias
towards monetary policy (strongly constrained by the EMS) but too lax
fiscal regimes. The story here applies both to the medium-to-longer term
disinflation effort as well as the short run.
In the case of EMU the short-run concern over an unbalanced
policy-mix mainly relates to the fear that undisciplined fiscal policies
(in the aggregate) will force the ECB to keep short term interest rates
higher than desirable in order to offset inflationary pressures. More
generally, if other economic agents affecting the determinants of
inflation (fiscal authorities and wage setters in particular) do not
play their part the ECB will either be induced to accommodate (ie accept
the fiscal dominance outcome) or impose great real economic costs in an
attempt to reassert its leadership. The Stability Pact can be seen as a
(blunt) safeguard to limit the extent to which the ECB will be
confronted with this dilemma and to safeguard its strategic leadership.
Again the criteria are an (imperfect) substitute for an explicit or
implicit coordination mechanism via common institutions or a shared
stability culture. They try to limit the risk that the ECB's
independence is tested or contested too severely.
The Stability Pact attempts to pre-empt any potential leadership
battles between fiscal and monetary policy in favour of the ECB and to
prevent an unbalanced policy-mix of a lax fiscal stance and tight money.
Here, it is not quite clear how the European Council Resolution on
Growth and Employment, adopted at French insistence in Amsterdam, might
play out. It calls for "developing the economic pillar" and
"enhancing policy coordination" under Articles 102a and 103 of
the Maastricht Treaty (European Council 1997). Meanwhile it seems
certain that an informal Euro-X Council will serve as a forum for the
discussion of economic policy among EMU participants. This could be
harmful for stability if it undermines the strategic leadership of the
ECB, but it could also be helpful if policy-coordination serves to
provide support for the ECB's objectives and contributes to finding
an appropriate policy-mix.
VI. Conclusion
The Stability Pact's orientation towards a zero budget deficit
in 'normal' times is consistent with its 3 per cent deficit
ceiling being used as a flexible margin of response in adverse
conditions. Unfortunately, though, it seems possible that countries will
enter Stage Three with deficits close up against the ceiling. The
European Commission's November 1997 point forecasts for the budget
deficits of the countries likely to form a broad-based EMU - that is,
all EU countries except the UK, Sweden, Denmark and Greece - shows six
countries in 1999 with deficits still at 2.2 per cent or more, a further
two with deficits above 1.5 per cent and three (of the smaller
countries) in surplus. If these forecasts are only somewhat too
optimistic, the provisions of the Stability Pact would face an early
test just at the time when the new ECB will be keen to establish its
reputation. The seriousness of the problem (the strain on the ECB and
the Stability Pact) will depend on the exact cyclical position of the
European economies and on how strictly the Maastricht entry criteria
will be applied. In this light, the scope for a trade-off between the
Stability Pact and the entry criteria (Artis 1996) appears to be
limited.
Yet, while there is some reason to doubt the effectiveness of the
technical provisions of the Stability Pact in guaranteeing the desired
discipline and flexibility in practice, the mere fact that Member States
have agreed to subject national budget policies to a concerted European
joint discipline is of great significance on two counts. First,
conceding concerted fiscal discipline in order to safeguard the
leadership and credibility of the ECB may be an important step towards
further implicit or explicit coordination of policies, whilst also
serving as an important signal to the financial markets of Europe's
credibility credentials that may help build stability reputation ahead
of the leap into EMU (Masson 1996). Second, the conclusion of the
Stability Pact also represents a small, but important, transfer of
national sovereignty in the budgetary field. Unlike Gros (1996) and
Thygesen (1996) we believe that there is a nexus between Political Union
and Monetary Union. Putting a lot of faith in codified rules as in the
Stability Pact and statutory central bank independence, is a reflection
of the German Ordo-liberal tradition in economics, but may be misplaced unless the rules are built on strong political legitimacy. Failing a
source of legitimacy the rules risk being ignored or of becoming the
object of serious conflict. Monetary stability and political cohesion in
Europe may yet become lost in the "Bermuda triangle" between
national and European institutions and responsibilities. Here, too, the
Stability Pact serves as an important test.
Appendix A
Key provisions of the European Council Resolution on the Stability
and Growth Pact (Council Resolution 97/C 236/01)
Member States
1. commit themselves to respect the medium-term budgetary position
of close to balance or in surplus set out in their stability or
convergence programmes [...];
5. will correct excessive deficits as quickly as possible after
their emergence; this correction should be completed in the year
following its identification, unless there are special circumstances;
7. commit themselves not to invoke the benefit of Article 2
paragraph 3 of the Council Regulation on speeding up and clarifying the
excessive deficit procedure unless they are in severe recession; in
evaluating whether the economic downturn is severe, the Member States
will, as a rule, take as a reference point an annual fall in real GDP of
at least 0.75%.
The Commission
3. commits itself to prepare a report under Article 104c(3)
whenever there is the risk of an excessive deficit or whenever the
planned or actual government deficit exceeds the 3% of GDP reference
value, thereby triggering the procedure under Article 104c(3);
4. commits itself, in the event that the Commission considers that
a deficit exceeding 3% is not excessive and this opinion differs from
that of the Economic and Financial Committee, to present in writing to
the Council the reasons for its position;
5. commits itself, following a request from the Council under
Article 109d, to make, as a rule, a recommendation for a Council
decision on whether an excessive deficit exists under Article 104c(6);
The Council
3. is invited to impose sanctions if a participating Member State
fails to take the necessary steps to bring the excessive deficit
situation to an end as recommended by the Council;
4. is urged to always require a non-interest bearing deposit,
whenever the Council decides to impose sanctions on a participating
Member State in accordance with Article 104c(11);
5. is urged always to convert a deposit into a fine after two years
[....], unless the excessive deficit has in the view of the Council been
corrected;
Appendix B
Key Articles of the Council Regulation on speeding up and
clarifying the implementation of the excessive deficit procedure
(Council Regulation (EC) No. 1467/97):
Article 2
1. The excess of a government deficit over the 3% reference value
shall be considered exceptional and temporary [...] when resulting from
an unusual event outside the control of the Member State concerned and
which has a major impact on the financial position of the general
government, or when resulting from a severe economic downturn. In
addition, the excess over the reference value shall be considered
temporary if budgetary forecasts as provided by the Commission indicate
that the deficit will fall below the reference value following the end
of the unusual event or the severe economic downturn.
2. The Commission when preparing a report under Article 104c(3)
shall, as a rule, consider an excess over the reference value resulting
from an economic downturn to be exceptional only if there is an annual
fall of real GDP of at least 2%".
3. The Council when deciding, according to Article 104c (6),
whether an excessive deficit exists, shall in its overall assessment
take into account any observations made by the Member State showing that
an annual fall of real GDP of less than 2% is nevertheless exceptional
in the light of further supporting evidence, in particular on the
abruptness of the downturn or on the accumulated loss of output relative
to past trends.
Article 3
3. The Council shall decide on the existence of an excessive
deficit [...] within three months of the reporting dates [...].
4. The Council recommendation [....] shall establish a deadline of
four months at the most for effective action to be taken by the Member
State concerned. The Council recommendation shall also establish a
deadline for the correction of the excessive deficit, which should be
completed in the year following its identification unless there are
special circumstances.
Article 4
2. The Council, when considering whether effective action has been
taken [...], shall base its decision on publicly-announced decisions by
the Government of the Member State concerned.
Article 5
Any Council decision to give notice to the participating Member
State concerned to take measures for the deficit reduction in accordance
with Article 104c(9) shall be taken within one month of the Council
decision having established that no effective action has been taken in
accordance with Article 104c(8).
Article 6
Where the conditions to apply Article 104c(11) are met, the Council
shall impose sanctions in accordance with Article 104c(11). Any such
decision shall be taken no later than two months after the Council
decision giving notice [...].
Article 7
If a participating Member State fails to act in compliance with the
successive decisions of the Council [...], the decision of the Council
to impose sanctions, [...], shall be taken within ten months of the
reporting dates [...]. An expedited procedure will be used in the case
of a deliberately planned deficit which the Council decides is
excessive.
Article 9
1. The excessive deficit procedure shall be held in abeyance:
* if a Member State concerned acts in compliance with
recommendations made in accordance with Article 104c(7),
* if a Member State concerned acts in compliance with notices given
in accordance with Article 104c(9).
Article 11
Whenever the Council decides to apply sanctions to a participating
Member State in accordance with Article 104c(11), a non-interest beating
deposit shall, as a rule, be required. [...]
Article 12
1. When the excessive deficit results from non-compliance with the
criterion relating to the government deficit ratio in Article 104c(2a),
the amount of the first deposit shall comprise a fixed component equal
to 0.2% of GDP, and a variable component equal to one tenth of the
difference between the deficit as a percentage of GDP in the preceding
year and the 3% of GDP reference value.
2. Each following year, [...]. The amount of an additional deposit
shall be equal to one tenth of the difference between the deficit as a
percentage of GDP in the preceding year and the 3% of GDP reference
value.
3. Any single deposit [...] shall not exceed the upper limit of
0.5% of GDP.
Article 13
A deposit shall, as a rule, be converted [...] into a fine if two
years after the decision to require [...] a deposit, the excessive
deficit has in the view of the Council not been corrected.
European University Institute and CEPR, European University
Institute. We would like to thank two anonymous referees for helpful
comments on a previous draft. Correspondence should be addressed to:
Department of Economics, European University Institute, Badia Fiesolana,
1-50016 San Domenico di Fiesole (Firenze), Italy.
REFERENCES
Agell, J., L. Calmfors and G. Jonsson (1996), 'Fiscal policy
when monetary policy is tied to the mast', European Economic Review
40, pp. 1413-1440.
Alesina, A. and R. Perotti (1995), 'The political economy, of
budget deficits', IMF Staff Papers 42, pp. 1-32.
Allsopp, C. and D. Vines (1996), Fiscal policy and EMU, National
Institute Economic Review, 158, 4/96, pp. 91-107.
Artis, M. (1996), 'Alternative transitions to EMU',
Economic Journal 106, pp. 1005-1015.
Barro, R. and D. Gordon (1983), 'A positive theory of monetary
policy in a natural rate model', Journal of Political Economy 91,
pp. 585-610.
Bayoumi, T. and B. Eichengreen (1995), 'Restraining yourself:
the implication of fiscal rules for economic stabilization', IMF
Staff Papers 42, pp. 32-48.
Bayoumi, T. and P. Masson (1995), 'Fiscal flows in the United
States and Canada: lessons for monetary union in Europe', European
Economic Review 39, pp. 253-274.
Bayoumi, T. and P. Masson (1996), 'Debt-creating versus
non-debt-creating fiscal stabilization policies: Ricardian equivalence,
fiscal stabilization, and EMU', Mimeo, International Monetary Fund,
March 1996.
Beetsma, R. and L. Bovenberg (1995a), Does monetary unification
lead to excessive debt accumulation?' CEPR Discussion Paper 1299.
Beetsma, R. and L. Bovenberg (1995b), 'Designing fiscal and
monetary institutions for a European Monetary Union', CEPR
Discussion Paper 1303.
Beetsma, R. and H. Uhlig (1997), 'An analysis of the stability
pact', CEPR Discussion Paper 1669.
Bertola, G. and A. Drazen (1993), 'Trigger points and budget
cuts: explaining the effects of fiscal austerity', American
Economic Review 83, pp. 11-26.
Bryson, J., H. Jensen and D. van Hoose (1993), 'Rules,
discretion, and international monetary and fiscal policy
coordination', Open Economies Review 4, pp. 117-132.
Buchanan, J. (1977), Democracy in Deficit. The Political Legacy of
Lord Keynes. Academic Press: New York.
Buiter, W., G. Corsetti and N. Roubini (1993), Excessive deficits:
sense and nonsense in the Treaty of Maastricht', Economic Policy
16, April, pp. 57-100.
Buti, M., D. Franco and H Ongena (1997), 'Budgetary policies
during recession - retrospective application of the 'stability and
growth pact' to the post-war period', European Commission,
DGII, Economic Papers no. 121, May.
Canzoneri, M. and B. Diba (1996), 'Fiscal constraints on
central bank independence and price stability', CEPR Discussion
Paper 1463.
Corsetti, G. and N. Roubini (1993), 'The design of optimal
fiscal rules for Europe after 1992', in F. Torres and F. Giavazzi
(eds.) Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary System, Cambridge
University Press: Cambridge, pp. 46-82.
Cour, P., E. Dubois, S. Mahfouz and J. Pisani-Ferry (1996), The
cost of fiscal retrenchment revisited how strong is the evidence?'
CEPII Document de Travail, Paris, pp. 96-16.
De Grauwe, P. (1996), 'The economics of convergence: towards
monetary union in Europe', Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 132, pp.
1-27.
Deutscher Bundestag (1,992), Bundestagsdrucksache 12/3906, 2.
Dezember 1992.
Ecofin Report (1996), Report by the Ecofin Council to the European
Council', Annex 1 of Presidency Conclusions of the Dublin European
Council. Europe Documents, Agence Internationale D Information pour la
Presse, Luxembourg, No. 2015/16, 18 December 1996.
Eichengreen, B. (1997), 'Saving Europe's automatic
stabilisers', National Institute Economic Review 159, 1/97, pp.
92-98.
Eichengreen, B. and E Ghironi (1997), 'How will transatlantic
policy interaction change with the advent of EMU?', Mimeo,
University of California, Berkeley, January 1997.
Eichengreen, B. and J. von Hagen (1996), 'Fiscal policy and
monetary union: federalism, fiscal restrictions, and the no-bailout
rule,' in H. Siebert (ed.) Monetary Policy in an Integrated World
Economy. Mohr (Paul Siebeck): Tubingen, pp. 211-231.
Eijffinger, S. and J. De Haan (1996), 'The political economy
of central-bank independence', Special Papers in International
Economics no. 19, International Finance Section, Princeton University.
European Council (1997), 'Presidency conclusions',
Amsterdam European Council 16 and 17 June 1997, Reprinted in European
Economy, no. 64.
Giavazzi, F. and M. Pagano (1990), 'Can severe fiscal
contractions be expansionary? tales of two small European
countries', NBER Macroeconomics Annual, pp,. 75-111.
Glick, R. and M. Hutchison (1993), Fiscal policy in monetary
unions: implications for Europe', Open Economies Review 4, pp.
39-65.
Grilli, V., D. Masciandaro and G. Tabellini (1991), 'Political
and monetary institutions and public financial policies in the
industrial countries', Economic Policy 13, pp. 341-392.
Gros, D. (1996), Towards Economic and Monetary Union: problems and
prospects', CEPS Paper 65.
Hughes Hallett, A. and P. McAdam (1996), Fiscal deficit reduction
in line with the Maastricht criteria for monetary union: an empirical
analysis', CEPR Discussion Paper 1351.
IMF (1995), World Economic Outlook, Washington, D.C.: International
Monetary Fund, May.
Jensen, H. (1996), 'The advantage of international fiscal
cooperation under alternative monetary regimes', European Journal
of Political Economy 12, pp. 485-504.
Jensen, H. (1997), Credibility of optimal monetary
delegation', American Economic Review, forthcoming.
Lamfalussy, A. (1997), Securing the benefits of EMU', In
Deutsche Bundesbank: Auszuge and Presseartikeln Nr. 14, pp. 4-7.
Levine, P. and J. Pearlman (1992), 'Fiscal and monetary policy
under EMU: credible inflation targets or unpleasant monetary
arithmetic?' CEPR Discussion Paper 701.
Lohmann, S. (1996), 'Quis custodiet ipsos custodes. Necessary
conditions for price stability in Europe, In H. Siebert (ed.), Monetary
Policy in an Integrated World Economy, Mohr (Paul Siebeck): Tubingen,
pp. 139-160.
Masson, P. (1996), 'Fiscal dimensions of EMU', Economic
Journal 106, pp. 996-1004.
McCallum, B. (1995), 'Two fallacies concerning central-bank
independence', American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 85,
pp. 207-211.
Melitz, J. and S. Vori (1992), 'National insurance against
unevenly distributed shocks', CEPR Discussion Paper 697.
Mourmouras, I. and D-M. Su (1995), 'Central bank independence,
policy reforms and the credibility of public debt stabilizations',
European Journal of Political Economy 11, pp. 189-204.
Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action. Harvard
University Press: Cambridge (Mass.).
Pisani-Ferry, J. (1996), 'Fiscal policy under EMU', CEPII
Newsletter no. 6, 2nd semester 96, Paris, 1-2.
Rogoff, K. (1985a), 'The optimal degree of commitment to an
intermediate target', Quarterly Journal of Economics 100, pp.
1169-1189.
Rogoff, K. (1985b), 'Can international monetary policy
coordination be counterproductive?' Journal of International
Economics 18, pp. 199-217.
Roubini, N. and J. Sachs (1989), 'Political and economic
determinant of budget deficits in the industrial democracies',
European Economic Review 33, pp. 903-938.
Sargent, T. and N. Wallace (1981), 'Some unpleasant monetarist
arithmetic', Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis (Fall), pp. 1-17.
Thygesen, N. (1996), 'Should budgetary policies be coordinated
further in economic and monetary union - and is that feasible?'
Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review no. 196 (Special Issue), pp.
5-32.
Thumann, G. (1997), Stability Pact Primer, Salomon Brothers,
January, London.
Von Hagen, J. and G. Hammond (1995), 'Regional insurance
against asymmetric shocks: an empirical study for the EC', CEPR
Discussion Paper 1170.
Von Hagen, J. and I. Harden (1994), 'National budget processes
and fiscal performance', European Economy, Reports and Studies no.
3, pp. 311-408.
Walsh, C. (1995), 'Optimal contracts for central
bankers', American Economic Review 85, pp. 150-167.
Winckler, G., E. Hochreiter and P. Brandner (1997), 'Deficits,
debt and European Monetary Union: some unpleasant fiscal
arithmetic', in G. Calvo and M. King (eds.) The Debt Burden and its
Consequences for Monetary Policy, London: Macmillan.
Winkler, B. (1996), 'Towards a strategic view on EMU: a
critical survey', Journal of Public Policy 16, pp. 1-28.
Winkler, B. (1997a), 'Of sticks and carrots: incentives and
the Maastricht road to EMU', EUI Working Paper ECO 97/2, European
University Institute, Florence.
Winkler, B. (1997b), 'Coordinating European Monetary
Union', EUI Working Paper ECO 97/10, European University Institute,
Florence.
Woodford, M. (1995), 'Price level determinacy without control
of a monetary aggregate', Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy.
Woodford, M. (1996), 'Control of the public debt: a
requirement for price stability?', Mimeo, Princeton University,
February 1996.