Regional economic integration and foreign direct investment: the case of German investment in Europe.
Pain, Nigel ; Lansbury, Melanie
I. Introduction
The European Economic Community originally came into existence
following the Treaty of Rome in 1957. Member states planned to harmonise
their tariffs, pursue a common trade policy and liberalise intra-Community trade. All internal customs duties and quantitative
restrictions on trade were successfully removed by 1968. However it
subsequently became clear that this had not resulted in the full
integration of product markets in Europe, with capital movements and
trade continuing to be restricted by capital controls and non-tariff
barriers. In the mid-1980s the European Commission identified around 300
areas in which legislative action could be taken to help the free flow
of goods, services, capital and labour within the community. This led to
the Single European Act in 1986 which aimed to complete the internal
market by the end of 1992.
In this paper we concentrate on the relationship between foreign
direct investment and the actions designed to ease non-tariff barriers
in product markets. Measures introduced under the Internal Market
programme include the removal of internal customs barriers and
constraints on capital movements and moves to liberalise tendering
procedures for public procurement contracts. Perhaps the most important
changes have been the steps taken to harmonise technical standards and
regulations, with the principle of mutual recognition of national
standards allowing products that meet the legal standards of any
individual member state to be sold throughout the European Union unless
explicit minimum union-wide standards have been agreed. A more extensive
description of all these changes is provided by Hoeller and Louppe
(1994).
The economic impact of the Internal Market programme has been
debated widely and the European Commission has recently completed the
first detailed assessment of the measures taken so far (European
Commission, 1996). This study contributes to the assessment by examining
whether the Internal Market programme has affected the pattern of
intra-European foreign direct investment. It has long been recognised
that changes in regional economic institutions and trade policy can have
a significant impact on both the level and location of overseas
investment. The initial formation of the European Community prompted
considerable empirical study into the question of whether investment was
diverted into the region (Yannopoulos, 1990). More recently considerable
attention has been paid to the impact of the North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA) on the location of production (Eden, 1994).
Our main focus is on the location and level of foreign direct
investment by German firms within the European Union (EU). World-wide,
German firms have the fourth largest stock of overseas assets of all
investing countries. Within Europe they are the second most important
investors after the United States. At the end of 1994 just under 1.2
million workers were employed in the foreign affiliates of German firms
located in Europe. Of these some 180,000 were in the UK, representing
around 1 1/2 per cent of private sector employment.
One striking feature of German FDI is the extent to which it became
increasingly concentrated within Europe from the latter half of the
1980s. An important question of interest is whether this observed change
in the pattern of direct investment is related to regional-specific
factors or simply to differences in national characteristics and the
extent to which Germany has become an unattractive business location
(Jungnickel, 1995). To answer this we use a panel data set to analyse the determinants of foreign direct investment by German corporations
between 1980 and 1992. The panel consists of six EU locations, plus
Austria and the United States. The inclusion of the latter two locations
allows us to examine whether investment has been diverted into the EU
since the advent of the Internal Market programme. Within the EU we
distinguish France, Italy, the UK, Belgium and Luxembourg, the
Netherlands and the Iberian peninsula. We examine investments undertaken
in seven broad sectors, chemicals, mechanical engineering, electrical
engineering, transport equipment, 'other' manufacturing,
distribution and financial services.
The remainder of this article is as follows. In the next section we
review recent trends in intra-EU foreign direct investment and give an
overview of the relevant literature on regional liberalisation and
intra-regional investment. This suggests a number of specific hypotheses
of interest that can be examined in any empirical analysis. Section III
describes the basic model used and discusses ways of establishing the
impact of the Internal Market measures. Section IV contains the main
empirical results and provides a quantitative evaluation of the impact
of the Internal Market programme.
II. Regional Integration and Intra-EU FDI
Foreign direct investment (FDI) has expanded rapidly throughout the
world economy over the past two decades, particularly since the middle
of the 1980s. The growth in FDI within Europe has been especially
marked, with the proportion of the aggregate stock of world FDI located
within EU member states estimated to have risen from 31 per cent in 1985
to 39 per cent by 1995 (UNCTAD, 1996). This appears to have come about
due to rising levels of investment in the EU both by non-EU nationals
and by EU firms themselves.
The flow of investment from EU firms into other EU member states
and North America since 1982 is shown in Chart 1. Intra-EU investment
has exceeded investment in North America since 1988, reaching a peak of
1 1/4 per cent of GDP in 1990. Over the five years to 1994, intra-EU FDI
was equivalent to 4 1/2 per cent of gross domestic fixed capital
formation in the EU on average. At face value these data appear to
suggest that moves towards greater European integration have generated a
structural change in the pattern of intra-EU investment (Hoeller and
Louppe, 1994).
A simple descriptive analysis of the changing pattern of intra-EU
flows of direct investment cannot provide any direct quantitative
indication of the possible influence of the measures taken to ease
product market barriers in the Internal Market programme. The observed
pattern of investment by EU firms might in part simply be a temporary
adjustment to the removal of national capital controls in many member
states.(1) This provides one reason for focusing on a single country
such as Germany, whose capital [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED] market
has been free of foreign exchange controls for some time.
A further handicap to the use of aggregate intra-EU investment in
any empirical analysis is the well-known statistical difficulties that
arise from inconsistencies in national definitions of foreign direct
investment. Eurostat do attempt to construct harmonised data, but their
series exclude reinvested earnings, an important component of total
foreign investment, and are only available from 1984 onwards. If
developments since the advent of the Internal Market programme are to be
seen in an appropriate perspective it is necessary to be able to
evaluate them in the context of an analysis over a longer sample period.
An alternative approach is to focus on large individual investors
with detailed statistics on the location of foreign [TABULAR DATA FOR
TABLE 2 OMITTED] investments. UK outward direct investment is considered
in Pain (1997); here we utilise German data. The geographical pattern of
the recorded stocks of German foreign direct investment is reported in
Table 1. The figures provide a picture similar to those in Chart 1, with
the proportion of investments held within the EU(2) rising steadily
since 1986 and a corresponding decline in the share of investments held
within North America. In contrast, the share of investment within the
other Western Europe countries has remained relatively constant over
time, whilst investment in Central and Eastern Europe has begun to
expand since 1990. The long-term decline in the proportion of
investments sited within other developing countries suggests that the
relatively high level of outward investment from Germany is not simply a
move towards low wage locations.(3)
The German investment data were amalgamated into seven separate
sectors, five for manufacturing and two for services. The sectoral
composition within the EU, the US and Austria is summarised in Table 2.
Investments in energy, mining and holding companies have been excluded.
The 'other manufacturing' group is given by total
manufacturing investment less investments in the four separately
identified industries. It is clear from the figures in Table 2 that
investment in the two service sectors accounts for much of the growth in
the overall proportion of investment within the EU. Within
manufacturing, investment in the chemicals, electrical engineering and
transport industries appears to have risen more rapidly in Europe than
in the United States.
The Impact of Integration on FDI
The early studies of the likely impact of the Internal Market (IM)
programme suggested that the measures should bring about a considerable
degree of industrial restructuring. This was largely expected to come
about through greater industrial specialisation, with firms able to
produce in a single location, exploit any economies of scale arising
from the existence of firm-specific fixed costs and serve the wider
European market through trade (Emerson et al., 1988). Such a pattern is
consistent with the findings of Brillhart and Torstensson (1996), who
report a significant correlation between the geographical concentration
of particular industries in Europe and a prior ranking of the importance
of scale economies in those industries. Little mention was made of
intra-EU foreign direct investment in the initial studies of the
Internal Market. The implication of the specialisation argument is that
intra-EU FDI might ultimately be lower than otherwise expected as a
result of the Internal Market programme, although there could be an
initial transition period with higher cross-border investment if the
restructuring process required new investments to ensure that all stages
of production were sited in the lowest cost locations. In North America
there is some evidence that such a restructuring process has occurred
following deeper regional integration, with a number of US
multinationals closing subsidiaries within Canada and substituting
exports for FDI as a result of the improvements in market access arising
from the US-Canadian Free Trade Agreement in force since 1989 (Niosi,
1994).
The exploitation of comparative advantage was also expected to
change the geographical distribution of industry within Europe.
Labour-intensive assembly activities would be concentrated in sites on
the periphery of Europe with relatively lower labour costs. Other, more
capital-intensive, activities would be located closer to the industrial
core of Western Europe. Relatively little was said about prospective
developments within service sectors in the early evaluations of the IM
programme, in spite of the measures taken to liberalise capital markets.
Although the number of measures relating to the service sector are only
a minority of the number of Directives issued as part of the IM
programme, in many cases they represent the first significant attempt to
reduce obstacles to the cross-border provision of non-tradeable services
within the EU, and might therefore be expected to stimulate foreign
investment.
In contrast the IM programme was widely expected to bring a higher
level of inward investment in Europe from non-European firms by raising
the relative locational advantages of the European market. The removal
of internal barriers has taken place at a time of continuing
uncertainties over the external commercial policy of the European
Commission with increasing use being made of contingent protection
(Barrell and Pain, 1997). An additional implication of this argument is
that the Internal Market process may have served to divert investment
into the EU at the expense of other locations (Baldwin et al., 1995).
There is some support for these hypotheses in the econometric results of
Aristotelous and Fountas (1996) and Pain (1997). The former find that
the level of inward investment in Europe by US and Japanese firms has
been significantly higher than might otherwise have been expected since
1987, whilst the latter finds some evidence that UK companies have
raised investment in Europe since 1990 at the expense of investment in
the United States.
A broad summary of the expectations at the start of the IM process
was thus that the measures would raise inward FDI from outside the EU,
but eventually lower intra-EU FDI, particularly in the manufacturing
sector. Scope existed for greater investment in the service sectors, but
few estimates were made of the likely effects. Dunning (1996) provides a
more detailed discussion of these and other issues.
There are a number of reasons why this argument may understate the
scope for intra-EU direct investment as product market barriers are
removed. At a practical level, the IM legislative process has taken much
longer than initially anticipated. By October of last year an average of
91 per cent of all IM directives were on member states' statute
books (Commission, 1996, pg.8). Our sample period ends in 1992, by which
time the Internal Market had initially been expected to be complete. The
continuing existence of some impediments to trade at that time may make
it difficult to get a full picture of the eventual impact of market
integration.
Moreover it is clear that many national factors continue to impose
costs on market access. Some of these are regulatory, arising from
differences in environmental and health and safety provisions. Examples
include the continuing use of national health insurance price controls
within the pharmaceuticals industry and regulations on the movement of
waste and standards of packaging. In other cases markets remain
differentiated as a result of consumer preferences. The food industry is
a widely cited example (Cantwell, 1992), with substantial national
product differentiation in alcoholic drinks, sauces and biscuits.
Another example is retail banking, where greater concentration has
occurred within individual countries but not across countries, with
consumers preferring to use banks located in the domestic market. In
such cases, direct investments are often made either to enter local
markets or to establish facilities for adapting products to local needs.
The impact of the IM measures on trade and investment could also be
expected to vary across sectors. Some of the non-tariff barriers,
notably customs controls, would previously have restrained trade
linkages but not market entry by means of direct investment. Others,
such as technical requirements and lack of competition in public
procurement would have affected both exporters and foreign subsidiaries.
Capital controls would have acted to constrain direct investment, but
not trade. In other cases trade and direct investment need not be
substitutes even in the absence of barriers to market entry. This is
particularly true of many investments in the service sector, with
investment in distribution facilities often designed to improve market
access for traded goods. Cross-border investment in other industries
such as corporate banking and advertising is often stimulated by the
growing activities of home country clients in foreign markets.
Thirdly, a number of models arising out of the new literature on
economic geography suggest that the initial stages of a decline in
barriers to trade could simply generate increased agglomeration, rather
than a broader geographical dispersion of industries in line with
comparative advantage (Baldwin and Venables, 1995). Regional
differentiation within such models is driven by the interaction between
scale economies and transport costs. If trade costs are high, there is
little separation between the location of production and consumption. If
the costs to market entry via trade are minimal, production is extremely
sensitive to differences in factor costs. However, agglomeration effects
may arise under the combination of intermediate levels of trade costs
and increasing returns to scale. Firms located in densely populated areas can economise on fixed costs by concentrating production in a
single plant and on transport costs by locating close to a large
market.(4)
These form of models support the original idea that the decline in
barriers to trade will eventually lead to greater concentration of
production within industries, but suggest that the initial stages of
liberalisation could well see a one-off higher level of investment as
firms relocate. For instance, trade liberalisation appears to have
altered the economic geography of Mexico (Hanson, 1997), with Mexico
City declining in importance relative to areas on the US-Mexico border
as trade barriers between Mexico and the United States have been
lowered.
However variants of these models which allow for the presence of
firm-specific assets can generate different implications (Markusen and
Venables, 1996). Such assets might include process innovations,
marketing skills or managerial expertise. All serve to give economies of
scale at the level of the firm rather than at plant level. Multinational
firms thus have lower variable costs but higher fixed costs than
national firms in different locations. If country characteristics differ
then single-plant firms may remain more profitable than multinational
firms, since the latter have to locate some capacity in a location with
higher relative factor costs, as well as incur the fixed costs
associated with the establishment of an additional production facility.
If country characteristics are similar and transport costs (or more
generally barriers to trade) are non-zero, then multinational firms may
be better placed than single-plant firms if they have knowledge-based
assets. These act as a joint input across plants, giving lower fixed
costs per market. Thus changes in technology and production costs can
help to support the existence of multinationals even at a time of
reductions in barriers to trade.
III. The Basic Model
In practice there are a wide range of factors that may determine
the pattern of specialisation and location over time. Multinational
enterprises arise through a combination of industrial organisation
motives that result in a number of activities being placed under common
ownership and control, and comparative advantage reasons that cause
these activities to be placed in separate countries (Krugman, 1995). We
seek to capture these influences in the empirical work. The remainder of
this section gives a brief overview of the factors we include. A more
extensive discussion of our approach is provided in the accompanying
article by Barrell and Pain.
Conventional supply-side models of the location of production
determine direct investment using indicators of market size and relative
production costs. In the empirical work we proxy market size by sector
value added in the host location.(5) To capture the role of relative
labour costs we use 'normalised' trend unit labour cost data
for manufacturing produced by the IMF, converted into a common currency.
This provides a measure of the real exchange rate. Unit costs are used
so as to allow for differentials in productivity levels as well as wages
and payroll taxes.
The decision to establish foreign operations is likely to also
reflect factors internal to the firm, in particular the existence of
firm-specific knowledge based assets. Such assets may be expected to
stimulate foreign direct investment, both because they can provide a
multinational firm with a cost advantage over two separate firms in
different locations and because they affect the trade-off between direct
investment overseas and the use of licensing agreements. We follow the
approach of Pain (1997) and assume that the level of sector-specific
assets is proportional to the cumulated stock of patents granted to
German firms within that sector. Many German corporations, especially in
industries such as automobiles and mechanical engineering, have been at
the forefront of important innovations in business practice over our
sample period (Patel and Pavitt, 1989).
The patents data are taken from US Department of Commerce
statistics on the number of patents registered in the United States each
year. A five-year cumulative measure is used as there is likely to be
some time lag before the full commercial potential of most patents is
realised.(6) Although it might be expected that innovatory activity is
less important for service sector FDI, the available data in fact
suggest that around three-fifths of total investment in distribution and
one-quarter of investment in financial and other services is undertaken
by manufacturing firms. We thus use a weighted average of manufacturing
patents for the two service sectors.
Investment may depend upon the flexibility of the workforce as much
as its basic cost. It is widely claimed that the greater flexibility of
the UK labour market has been a primary factor behind the growth in
inward investment over the past decade (Eltis and Higham, 1995).
Flexibility is affected by a large number of institutional features in
labour, product and housing markets, and it is difficult to capture
these fully in any empirical study. Here we utilise data on the number
of days lost through strikes in each of the host economies. We expect
that more strike-prone locations will receive less inward investment.(7)
Following Barrell et al. (1996) we also seek to take account of
exchange rate volatility. Such volatility can affect firms whose costs
and revenues are denominated in different currencies. Whilst it is
possible to insure against currency risk, this is not without cost. Thus
exchange rate volatility may affect the foreign investment decision. To
investigate this possibility we use a dummy set to unity for those host
countries who have been members of the Exchange Rate Mechanism of the
EMS during the sample period, plus Austria which has pursued a policy of
closely shadowing the D-mark since 1981. The variable is zero for the UK
and Spain prior to ERM entry in 1990, and zero for the US throughout the
sample period.
A number of studies also suggest that the investment decisions of
companies, both at home and abroad, are affected by domestic financial
conditions, although there appears to be little agreement as to how
these are best measured. Carlin (1996) provides an overview of the
impact of corporate profitability on the pattern of domestic investment
within Germany, while Dinenis and Funke (1994) obtain a significant
effect from real equity prices on domestic fixed investment. We
investigate the role of both these factors in this study. Fluctuations
in domestic profitability and interest gearing have already been shown
to have a significant effect on the level of foreign investment by US
and UK firms (Barrell and Pain (1996) and Pain (1997)) and Heiduk and
Hodges (1992) suggest that planned foreign investments are reduced
before domestic ones at times of financial distress. Profitability is
measured using the rate of return on capital in the German business
sector, as reported by the OECD.
The basic form of the partial adjustment model we initially employ
can be expressed as:
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] [1]
where [FDI.sub.ijt] denotes the stock of foreign direct investment
in sector j in country i at time t, OUTPUT is the measure of market
size, RELCOST denotes unit labour costs in the host country relative to
those in Germany, PATENTS is the cumulated measure of registered
patents, STRIKES is the number of labour disputes in the host country,
EXCH is the exchange rate dummy, REQP denotes German equity prices in
real terms, RETURN is the rate of return on capital in the German
business sector(8) and IM is the dummy variable(s) included to capture
the direct impact of the Internal Market. We discuss this variable in
more detail below. The sector and location specific fixed effects
[[Alpha].sub.ij] allow for unobserved influences that remain constant
over the whole of the sample period. All other influences will be
contained in the disturbance term [v.sub.it]. The fixed effects may
capture factors such as contiguous borders and language that are not
reflected in the other variables.
Modelling the Internal Market
The most important factor in an exercise of this kind is to decide
how to incorporate the effects of the Internal Market programme into the
specification of the model. We argued above that it is to be expected
that the impact of the Internal Market programme will have varied by
sector. Thus it would not be appropriate to include either a single
dummy variable set to unity from 1987 across all sectors, or to draw
conclusions from a set of individual sector dummies, since these could
capture other unobserved influences as well. Some indication of the
relative sensitivity of particular sectors in the first place is
required. Here we follow Pain (1997) and use an ordinal variable
(ranging from 1-3) for the level of non-tariff barriers in particular
sectors. Sectors where the programme is expected to have a high impact
are given a ranking of 3. Sectors with moderate and little impact are
given rankings of 2 and 1 respectively.
Two separate rankings are reported in Table 3. The first is
constructed from European Commission estimates of the importance of
non-tariff barriers at the industry level, summarised in Buigues et
al.(1990). These estimates have already been successfully exploited in
studies of trade patterns within Europe, see for instance Sapir (1996).
Whilst directly comparable estimates are not available for the service
sectors, it is possible to draw on the qualitative assessments in Sapir
(1993). These indicate that the removal of non-tariff barriers could be
expected to have a 'high' impact on banking, insurance and
road transport, but a 'low' impact on hotels and catering.
An alternative strategy is to devise an indicator based on an
approach that is readily comparable across both industrial and service
sectors. Here we use data on the number of cross-border mergers and
acquisitions within the European Community in the four year period,
prior to the signing of the Single European Act in 1986 and in the four
year period immediately after. Those sectors where the growth rate in
the number of mergers was above the average growth rate of all sectors
were given a ranking of 3. Sectors whose growth rates were at or just
below the average were assigned a ranking of 2. The remaining sectors
were given a ranking of 1.
One potential objection to the use of mergers and acquisitions data
is that it comes close to using data on direct investment to devise an
indicator with which to 'explain' direct investment. However
mergers and acquisitions will not be reflected in the direct investment
data unless they are financed in the home country of the acquiring firm.
Moreover, at the econometric level, it should be emphasised that the
mergers data relate to developments within the whole EU; there is no
necessary reason why any indicator based on this data should be of use
in explaining investment by German firms, even though they are important
individual investors.
Table 3: Estimates of the Impact of the Internal Market By Sector
Sectors Internal Market Sensitivity
Commission Mergers &
Estimates Acquisition Data
Chemicals 2 2
Machinery 1 1
Electrical 3 3
Transport Equipment 2 3
Other Manufacturing 1 3
Distribution 2 2
Financial and Other Services 3 3
Source: Own calculations based on data from the Annual Report on
Competition Policy, various issues, Buigues et al. (1990) and Sapir
(1993).
The two Internal Market proxies are compared in Table 3. Both
measures are broadly similar, with financial services and electrical
equipment being shown as particularly sensitive sectors. Differences
arise for (road) transport equipment and the 'other
manufacturing' sector. In both sectors there was a marked increase
in cross-border mergers and acquisitions after 1986, although the
Commission estimates suggested that the removal of non-tariff barriers
was expected to have little impact. Cantwell (1992) argues that
considerable national differentiation remains in the food industry and
also in products such as [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 4 OMITTED] professional
and scientific instruments, both included in 'other
manufacturing'.(9)
The econometric work in this paper relies primarily on the Internal
Market indicator based on the pattern of mergers and acquisitions.
Whilst this offers a consistent estimate for each sector, it should be
recognised that the rankings are somewhat arbitrary, although this
criticism could equally be made of the alternative measure as well. In
practice the choice of measure appears to make relatively little
difference to the econometric results.(10)
IV. Empirical Results
The data set has thirteen annual observations (19801992) for seven
sectors in eight separate locations giving a total panel size of 728
observations. We use constructed data on the stock of direct investment
at constant prices. This was obtained by converting the current price
foreign direct investment stock into dollars using the end-year exchange
rate and deflating the nominal dollar stocks by the GDP deflator of the
host country. All the main explanatory variables are entered in
logarithmic form, permitting direct estimates of their elasticities. We
estimate a dynamic, partial adjustment panel model. The inclusion of a
lagged dependent variable in [1] will induce small sample bias into
panel estimates produced using OLS (Nickell, 1981), so that an
instrumental variable estimator has to be employed. There are a number
of potential instruments that can be used for the lagged dependent
variable. In this paper we employ the rank order of the lagged dependent
variable (Durbin, 1954). This latter instrument is clearly strongly
correlated with the variable being instrumented, but has been
'cleaned' of the lagged disturbance term.(11)
The econometric results are summarised in Table 4. The first column
(hereafter (4.1)) reports the parameter estimates for the basic panel
model. All of the main explanatory variables are significant at
conventional levels and there is no sign of any significant first-order
serial correlation. Overall, the coefficients are in accordance with our
priors, suggesting that foreign investment by German firms is driven by
strategic factors and firm-specific competitive advantages as well as by
a desire to relocate to lower cost sites. There appears to be an
important role for the accumulated sectoral level of patents registered
by German companies, with an implied long-run elasticity of 1.04 per
cent. There are also well determined effects from labour costs and
market size, with respective elasticities of 0.34 and 0.65 per cent,
broadly in line with the results obtained by Barrell et al.(1996). There
is also evidence that labour relations in the host country are of
importance, with an implied long-run elasticity on the strike variable
of -0.11 per cent, so that a rise in the number of strikes will reduce
inward investment.
There are sizeable significant effects from both the growth in real
equity prices and profitability, with a 1 per cent rise in profitability
generating an expansion in foreign investment of 0.75 per cent. This
suggests that financial factors have had an important influence on the
timing and scale of direct investment by German companies, confirming
the findings from the case studies cited by Heiduk and Hodges
(1992).(12) These terms should be seen primarily as indicators of the
extent to which changes in domestic financial conditions affect the
timing and the size of the flow of direct investment. As neither can be
expected to trend permanently over time they cannot be the primary
factor behind the continuing upward trend in the stock of investment.
We also obtain a significant effect from our proxy variable to
capture the impact of currency variability. The reported positive
coefficient suggests that German corporations value exchange rate
stability, and is consistent with the notion that Germany may be the
final market for some goods produced elsewhere within Europe. An
implication of this is that German firms may prefer to produce in
countries who have made a commitment to link their nominal exchange
rates to the D-mark.
The Internal Market variable has a significant positive
coefficient, implying that German investment in the EU has, on average
across sectors and countries, been higher than might otherwise have been
expected since 1987. The continued presence of the lagged dependent
variable means that the model has the implication that the impact of the
Internal Market has accumulated over time. This equation has a
marginally smaller standard error than an alternative one using the IM
indicator based on the Commission rankings shown in Table 3. However the
alternative measure also had a significant positive coefficient,
suggesting that impact of the programme on within-sector developments
cannot be estimated too precisely.
In equation (4.2) we investigate whether the Internal Market has
had different effects on the industrial and services sectors by
splitting the IM variable into two components, one for the industrial
sectors, denoted IMIND, and one for the service sectors, denoted IMSER.
Both are set to zero for Austria and the United States. Whilst
investment appears to have been significantly higher in both sectors,
the results provide support for the hypothesis that the Internal Market
programme has had a significantly greater impact on the service sectors,
with an attempt at imposing equal coefficients being rejected by the
data [Chi-squared(1) = 6.36].
The tests reported so far have explored the possibility of
variation between sectors across countries. It is also possible to allow
for variation between countries across sectors. A test for variation
within countries is reported in the third column of Table 4. Here we
have included separate dummies for each EU country, set to unity from
1987 onwards for all sectors. The IM sector dummies are also included.
This specification relaxes two implicit restrictions in the previous
equations, the common size of effects across countries and the common
direction of effects across industries. The impact of the Internal
Market on each sector, within each country, is given by the coefficient
on the country dummy plus the coefficient on the sector dummy multiplied
by the ranking of that sector as shown in Table 3. Some care is required
in interpreting the findings since the country dummies will also pick up
any factors that are otherwise accounted for and have changed
systematically within each host country since 1987.
The national dummies are jointly significant, suggesting that there
is considerable variation across countries [Chi(6) = 28.38]. This was
confirmed by the rejection of an attempt at imposing identical
coefficients on the country dummies [Chi(5) = 26.10], implying that
there have been significantly different patterns of direct investment in
European countries after 1987. In most cases the dummies have a negative
coefficient. However for all countries this is offset, in some sectors
at least, by the positive coefficient on the IM variable. Even so, the
implied Internal Market effects differ markedly between countries. For
the UK, the combination of the positive coefficients on the country and
sector dummies means that investment in all sectors has been higher
since 1987. In contrast investment in Spain has only been higher in
those sectors with a ranking of 2 or 3, whilst in Belgium and France
investment has only been higher in the most sensitive sectors. We return
to this issue in more detail below.
The Internal Market and Investment Outside the EU
In (4.4), we investigate the impact of the Internal Market on
German direct investment in the non-EU locations. We initially introduce
separate industrial and service sector dummies for Austria and the
United States. These variables have the same sector pattern as the EU
measures denoted IMIND and IMSER, and are set to zero for all EU
countries. For both the US and Austria there is evidence that German
investment has been lower than might have been expected in their
manufacturing sectors since 1987. This is consistent with the hypothesis
that the Internal Market programme has diverted investment into the EU.
However direct investment in services within the EU does not appear to
have been at the expense of investment within the non-EU locations.
Neither of the IM dummies for Austria are significant, possibly because
it became clear at an early stage that Austria would implement the
Internal Market legislation in full, initially via membership of the
European Economic Area established in 1992 and then as a result of entry
into the EU itself (Baldwin et al., 1995).
In the final column of Table 4 we drop the two insignificant
service sector dummies for the non-EU locations. This has relatively
little effect on the coefficients on the remaining IM dummy variables
and there continues to be [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 5 OMITTED] evidence
that the level of German investment in the manufacturing sector of the
United States has been significantly lower than might otherwise have
been expected since 1987. It is worth noting that the introduction of
country dummies has led to some changes in the other coefficients in the
model as compared to the initial regression. In particular the size and
significance of the exchange rate dummy has fallen, possibly suggesting
that the higher level of German investment in the UK was previously
being attributed to membership of the ERM between 1990-92, rather than
to changes arising from the IM programme. The profitability measure has
also become more significant, possibly because its coefficient was
initially biased downwards as a result of the conjunction of the decline
in profitability after 1990 and the continued high level of new
investments since that time.
Evaluating the Impact of the Internal Market
T. he full matrix of coefficients implied by (4.5) for the impact
of the Internal Market on investment by sector and country within Europe
is reported in Table 5. This indicates that German investment appears to
have risen much more rapidly since 1987 in the UK, the Netherlands and
Italy than might have been expected. Investment in Spain has also risen
on balance, although by a smaller amount. In contrast, investment in
France and Belgium and Luxembourg has been lower than might have been
expected in all sectors apart from financial services, although in some
cases, the implied coefficients are insignificantly different from zero.
It is possible to use the estimated relationships with the sector
and country dummies to calculate the direct effect of the Internal
Market programme on the stock of German FDI in any particular sector
within a EU member state.(13) Here we use equation (4.5), although there
are obviously a number of alternative equations upon which the
calculations might be based?I The methodology is based on that described
in Pain (1997, Appendix 1), extended to allow for the country dummies as
well.
The results for each EU member state and each individual sector are
summarised in Table 6. These indicate that as of 1992, the Internal
Market programme is estimated to have raised the stock of German FDI by
some $13.7 billion, at constant 1990 prices, equivalent to 17 1/2 per
cent of the aggregate stock level. Pain (1997) reports that the
programme has raised UK direct investment in Europe by a similar
absolute amount, although the proportionate effect is somewhat larger
due to the lower value of UK investment in the EU.(15)
Table 6. The Impact of the Internal Market on the Location and
Composition of German FDI in the EU
($bn, 1990 prices)
1992 Stock IM Effect
Country
Belgium & Luxembourg 21.9 2.1
United Kingdom 12.2 4.9
France 13.7 -0.5
Italy 9.0 2.5
Netherlands 9.5 3.0
Spain & Portugal 10.1 1.7
Sector
Chemicals 9.5 -0.1
Mechanical Engineering 2.4 -0.3
Electrical 4.8 1.0
Transport Equipment 4.0 0.4
Other Manufacturing 7.1 0.9
Distribution 17.3 2.9
Financial & Other Services 31.3 8.9
Total 76.4 13.7
The primary beneficiary of the higher level of outward investment
by German firms appears to have been the UK, where investment is some
$4.9 billion higher than otherwise, a little over one-third of the
reported stock level. As might be expected, given the coefficients
reported in Table 5, Italy, the Netherlands and Spain and Portugal have
also gained additional investment. Belgium and Luxembourg are also
estimated to have gained overall, although this is entirely due to the
high level of investment in financial services in those countries.
Investment in the other six sectors is estimated to have fallen. France
is the only location where investment is estimated to be lower as a
result of the IM programme. Although the estimated coefficients for
France reported in Table 5 are similar to those for Belgium, France is
less specialised in financial services, and the small gain made in this
sector fails to outweigh losses in the industrial sectors, particularly
chemicals and mechanical engineering.
The sector results indicate that the largest gains have arisen in
distribution and financial services. Within manufacturing, the largest
absolute gains are for electronics and 'other' manufacturing.
In proportionate terms the Internal Market programme has had a
particularly marked effect in the electronics sector, accounting for
some 21 per cent of the outstanding stock of German direct investment in
the EU. There is some evidence in the results obtained for chemicals and
mechanical engineering that the removal of non-tariff barriers has led
to greater concentration. Foreign investment in both sectors is
estimated to have been lower than might otherwise have been expected.
The Impact of Labour Markets and Innovation on Inward Investment
It is also of interest to estimate the extent to which the growth
in manufacturing inward investment from Germany across Europe can be
directly attributed to developments in national labour markets and the
research intensities of the investing sectors. We attempt to do this in
Table 7 by using the estimated equation to calculate the effects of
actual changes in relative labour costs, the level of strikes and
patenting on the change in inward investment from Germany between 1986
and 1992. Any such calculations have to take account of the presence of
the lagged dependent variable. For example our estimates of the extent
to which movements in relative costs can account for the change in the
stock of inward investment between 1986 and 1992 reflect the extent to
which a distributed lag of relative costs from 1987 to 1992 differed
from an equivalent distributed lag of relative costs from 1981 to 1986.
The results reveal some interesting differences between countries.
The UK has clearly benefited more than any other country from labour
market factors, with movements in costs relative to Germany estimated to
have raised the stock of inward investment by 5.5 per cent, and the
decline in the number of strikes estimated to have raised investment by
9.3 per cent. However similar outcomes were achieved by France, Austria
and, to a lesser extent, Italy, even though labour market institutions
in these countries differ markedly from those in the UK. In contrast,
the cost position of Belgium and Netherlands also stimulated inward
investment, but there was little improvement in labour relations.
Movements in labour costs and labour relations both acted to restrain
new investment in Spain over this period.
Table 7. The Contribution of European Labour Markets and German
Patents to the Growth of Manufacturing Inward FDI from Germany
between 1986-92
(per cent change in stock of inward investment)
Country Relative Strikes German Patents
Labour Costs
Belgium 3.67 -0.95 30.62
UK 5.52 9.34 28.03
France 5.90 4.84 30.20
Italy 1.58 6.17 31.73
Netherlands 5.54 -0.02 27.61
Spain -3.76 -2.14 33.09
Austria 5.96 4.80 34.10
A somewhat different picture emerges from the contribution of the
growth in patenting. It is clear that for all countries this has had a
much more substantial impact on the growth of the stock of inward
investment than have labour market developments. This reflects the
extent to which the accumulated number of patents registered by German
firms has tended to rise over time, as well as the respective
elasticities of the estimated model. The estimates indicate that the UK
has fared relatively poorly in attracting investments from those sectors
in which innovation within Germany has risen most rapidly. Overall,
Austria appears to have gained the most, attracting research intensive
investments and benefiting from improvements in labour market
performance.
V. Conclusions
The primary objective of this study has been to quantify the impact
of continuing moves towards European integration on the sectoral and
geographical pattern of foreign direct investment by German
corporations. We have used a panel data set to estimate a conventional
econometric model for the stock of direct investment with allowance for
sector-specific and country-specific effects, augmented by a set of
constructed Internal Market indicator variables.
Our results suggest that the Internal Market programme has had a
significant, positive impact on the aggregate level of intra-EU
investment by German corporations in both industrial and service sectors
as a whole, with some evidence of investment diversion from the US in
the manufacturing sector. There is some evidence that investment in
Europe has been reduced in the chemicals and mechanical engineering
sectors, consistent with the hypothesis that the removal of internal
barriers to trade could result in production becoming more concentrated.
The largest single beneficiaries of the extra investment appear to be
the UK, the Netherlands and Italy, with additional evidence of a modest
increase in investment in the Southern periphery of the EU.
Overall, the combined results of this study and Pain (1997) suggest
that the Internal Market programme raised the constant price stock of
intra-EU investment from UK and German firms by some $27 billion as of
1992, equivalent to 0.5 per cent of EU GDP. The financial services
sector accounts for half of this additional investment. These estimates
should perhaps be regarded as providing a lower bound to the overall
Internal Market impact, since the programme may also have affected the
growth of output and research intensity. The conclusions of this paper
and the accompanying paper by Agarwal in this Review also suggest that,
for Germany at least, the Internal Market has been associated with
investment creation in Europe, with little evidence that the higher
level of foreign investment has been at the expense of domestic
investment.
The results in this paper suggest that any overall evaluation of
the 1992 programme should take into account developments in the service
sectors as well as within the manufacturing ones. It would also be of
interest to know more about the forms of activity undertaken by foreign
subsidiaries within the EU. Our findings are consistent both with models
of horizontal direct investment, such as Markusen and Venables (1996),
in which firms produce similar products in different locations and
models in which firms aim to widen their international division of
labour. To address this question it would be of considerable interest to
seek to augment the findings from sectoral econometric analyses with
those from more detailed case studies of individual multinational firms.
Correspondence should be addressed to the authors at NIESR. Earlier
versions of this paper were presented at the 1996 European Economic
Association Conference in Istanbul and the winter seminar meeting of the
International Economics Study Group. We are grateful to Ray Barrell,
John Dunning, Peter Holmes, Helen Popper, Martin Weale and seminar
participants for helpful comments and discussions and to the
Economists' Advisory Group and the ESRC for financial support.
NOTES
(1) Arrowsmith et al. (1997) provide a detailed account of the
evolution of EU capital markets and the pattern of capital flows since
the start of the Internal Market programme.
(2) The EU figures are for the twelve member states as of 1994;
they therefore include data for Greece, Spain and Portugal prior to
their accession into the EU.
(3) It is possible that the rise in the EU share is exaggerated by
a vintage effect. As the stock data are at book values, more recent
investments can be expected to be closer to their present market values
than older ones. To the extent that such investments tend to be within
Europe, this will serve to raise the proportion of total investment held
within Europe.
(4) Brulhart and Torstensson (1996) find that the industries with
the greatest scope for scale economies tend to be concentrated within
central EU countries and regions.
(5) The sector output data are for gross-value added by branch,
obtained from Eurostat.
(6) Comparison of our results with those in Pain and Lansbury
(1995) using a three-year cumulation of patents and in Barrell et
al.,(1996) using a cumulative R&D based indicator suggest that the
degree of cumulation makes little difference to the estimated long-run
elasticities.
(7) However if there are other factors which attract companies to a
particular location then it is possible that labour disruption could
simply encourage capital-labour substitution.
(8) This variable is lagged one year to avoid possible simultaneity
problems. If foreign investment was a perfect substitute for domestic
investment, then a rise in the stock of FDI would be associated with a
fall in the domestic capital stock and hence, for given income, with an
apparent rise in the rate-of-return on domestic capital.
(9) There are other sectors, notably chemicals, with an
intermediate ranking in spite of a high number of cross-border mergers
since 1986. However these sectors also had a relatively high number of
mergers prior to 1986 as well, implying that the recently observed
restructuring is part of a longer term process of rationalisation (Thomsen and Woolcock, 1993).
(10) Further work might usefully seek to investigate whether
alternative estimates could be obtained from a detailed analysis of
industrial structure in the United States and Europe, possibly drawing
on information on either scale economies or concentration within sectors
prior to the start of the Internal Market programme.
(11) The rank order may be a weak instrument if there is
substantial measurement error present in the instrumented variable and,
hence, in the associated rank order. There are a number of alternative
estimators available, but most would force us to estimate an equation
for the investment flow rather than the investment stock as first
differences of the data would have to be employed.
(12) It might be argued that the profitability measure is simply a
general indicator for the rate of return throughout Europe, rather than
a particular indicator of the financial health of German companies and
that an explicit measure of the rate of return on foreign investments
should be included. To investigate this (4.1) was augmented by an
additional term for the rate of return in the business sector in the
host location relative to that in Germany. This term was found to have a
positive coefficient (of 0.10) but was insignificantly different from
zero. The separate term on German profitability remained significant.
(13) The Internal Market may also have had an indirect effect to
the extent that the programme has affected both the economic growth and
cost competitiveness of the host location.
(14) Again it should be emphasised that such estimates need to be
treated with a degree of caution because the country dummies may be
picking up additional effects unrelated to the Internal Market.
(15) This estimate for Germany is much larger than that obtained in
Pain and Lansbury (1995). This is because their estimates came from a
model with common coefficients on the IMIND and IMSER dummy variables.
In the alternative model used in this paper, such a restriction is
rejected, with a larger effect being obtained for the service sector.
Our earlier estimates formed part of the European Commission's
initial assessment of impact of the Internal Market (European
Commission, 1996, pg.86).
REFERENCES
Aristotelous, K. and S. Fountas (1996), 'An empirical analysis
of inward foreign direct investment flows in the EU with emphasis on the
market enlargement hypothesis, Journal of Common Market Studies, no. 34,
pp. 571-583.
Arrowsmith, J., Barrell, R., Pain, N., Young, G. and Wlodek, K.
Baldwin, R., R. Forslid and J. Haaland (1995), 'Investment
creation and investment diversion: simulation analysis of the single
market programme', CEPR Discussion Paper no. 1308.
Baldwin, R.E. and A.J. Venables (1995), 'Regional economic
integration', in G.M. Grossman and K. Rogoff (eds.), Handbook of
International Economics Volume III, Elsevier, North Holland.
Barrell, R. and N. Pain (1996a), 'An econometric analysis of
US foreign direct investment', Review of Economics and Statistics,
vol. LXXVIII, pp. 200-207.
Barrell, R. and N. Pain (1997), 'Trade restraints and Japanese
direct investment flows', European Economic Review, forthcoming.
Barrell, R., N. Pain and F. Hubert (1996), 'Regionalism,
innovation and the location of German foreign direct investment',
National Institute Discussion Paper no. 91.
Brulhart, M. and J. Torstensson (1996), 'Regional integration,
scale economies and industry location in the European Union', CEPR
Discussion Paper no. 1435.
Buigues, P., F. Ilzkovitz and J. Lebrun (1990), 'The impact of
the internal market by industrial sector: the challenge for the member
states', European Economy, Special Edition, pp. 1-114.
Cantwell, J. (1992), The effects of integration on the structure of
multinational corporation activity in the EC' in M.W. Klein and
P.J.J. Welfens (eds.), Multinationals In The New Europe and Global
Trade, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.
Carlin, W. (1996), West German growth and institutions,
1945-90' in N.Crafts and G.Toniolo (eds.), Economic Growth In
Europe Since 1945, Cambridge University Press.
Dinenis, E. and M. Funke (1994), 'Factor prices, employment
and investment in UK and West German manufacturing', The Manchester
School, vol. LXII, pp. 412-424.
Dunning, J.H. (1996), 'The European internal market program
and inbound foreign direct investment', University of Reading
Discussion Papers in International Investment and Business Studies no.
217, Journal of Common Market Studies forthcoming.
Durbin, J. (1954), 'Errors in variables', Review of the
International Statistical Institute, vol. 22, pp. 23-32.
Eden, L. (1994), 'Who does what after NAFTA? Location
strategies of US multinationals' in L.Eden (ed.), Multinationals In
North America, The University of Calgary Press, Calgary.
Eltis, W. and D. Higham (1995), 'Closing the UK
competitiveness gap', National Institute Economic Review, no. 154,
pp. 71-84.
Emerson, M., M. Aujean, M. Catinat, P. Goybet and A. Jacquemin
(1988), The Economics of 1992: The EC Commission's Assessment of
the Effects Of Completing The Internal Market, Oxford University Press,
Oxford.
European Commission,(1996), The Single Market And Tomorrow's
Europe, Kogan Page, London.
Hanson, G.H. (1997), Increasing returns, trade and the regional
structure of wages, Economic Journal, no. 107, pp. 113-133.
Heiduk, G. and U.W. Hodges (1992), 'German multinationals in
Europe; patterns and perspectives' in M. W. Klein and P.J.J.
Welfens (eds.), Multinationals in the New Europe and Global Trade,
Springer-Verlag, Berlin.
Hoeller, P. and M-O Louppe (1994), 'The EC's internal
market: implementation and economic effects', OECD Economic
Studies, vol. 23, pp. 55-108.
Krugman, P.R. (1995), 'International trade theory and
policy', in (eds.) G. Grossman and K. Rogoff, Handbook of
International Economics Volume III, Elsevier, Amsterdam.
Markusen, J.R. and Venables, A.J. (1996), 'The increased
importance of direct investment in North Atlantic economic
relationships: a convergence hypothesis', in M.B. Canzoneri, W.J.
Ethier and V. Grilli (eds.), The New Transatlantic Economy, Cambridge
University Press.
Nickell, S. (1981), 'Biases in dynamic models with fixed
effects', Econometrica, vol. 49, pp. 1399-1416.
Niosi, J. (1994), 'Foreign direct investment in Canada',
in L. Eden (ed.), Multinationals In North America, The University of
Calgary Press, Calgary.
Pain, N. (1997), 'Continental drift: European integration and
the location of UK foreign direct investment', The Manchester
School, forthcoming.
Pain, N. and M. Lansbury (1995), 'The impact of the internal
market on the evolution of european direct investment'. NIESR
report prepared for Economists Advisory Group.
Patel, P. and K. Pavitt (1989), 'A comparison of technological
activities in West Germany and the United Kingdom', National
Westminster Bank Quarterly Review, May, pp. 27-42.
Sapir, A. (1993), 'Sectoral dimension' in Market Services
and European Integration, European Economy, vol. 3, pp. 23-40.
Sapir, A. (1996), 'The effects of Europe's internal
market programme on production and trade: a first assessment',
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, vol. 132, no. 3, pp. 457-475.
Thomsen, S. and S. Woolcock (1993), Direct Investment and European
Integration: Competition Among Firms and Governments, Pinter Publishers,
London.
UNCTAD (1996), World Investment Report 1996, United Nations,
Geneva.
Yannopoulos, G.N. (1990), 'Foreign direct investment and
European integration: the evidence from the formative years of the
European Community', Journal of Common Market Studies, vol. XXVIII,
pp. 235-259.