The effects of British industrial relations legislation 1979-97.
Brown, William ; Deakin, Simon ; Ryan, Paul 等
The Review is pleased to give hospitality to CLARE Group articles,
but is not necessarily in agreement with the views expressed;
responsibility for these rests with the authors. Members of the CLARE
Group are M.J. Artis, A.J.C. Britton, W.A. Brown, W.J. Carlin, J.S.
Flemming, C.A.E. Goodhart, J.A. Kay, R.C.O. Matthews, D.K. Miles, M.H.
Miller, P.M. Oppenheimer, M.V. Posner, W.B. Reddaway, J.R. Sargent,
M.FG. Scott, Z.A. Silberston, S. Wadhwani and M. Weale.
The recent change of government brings to an end a sustained attempt
to transform British industrial relations by legislative action. This
article explores the consequences. It explains the cumulative effect of
the legal changes since 1979, including the growing influence of the
European Community, and examines the economic and social results. While
legal intervention has had an impact on the institutions of industrial
relations, most notably in reducing the power of organised labour, this
cannot be isolated from wider structural changes in labour and product
markets. A review of research on economic outcomes suggests an uneven
and tenuous link between institutional change and economic performance.
Introduction
The use of legislation to reform industrial relations has been a
central component of economic policy during the period of Conservative
government that has now come to an end. It is widely considered to have
made a major contribution to improving the performance of the economy
since 1980. In 1990 the CLARE Group published a paper in this Review
(Brown and Wadhwani, 1990) attempting to assess the nature and extent of
this contribution. The purpose of the present paper is to return to this
task after more time has elapsed, and more legislation has been passed.
There is now an abundance of research evidence dealing with different
aspects of these changes, including attempts to address the same topic,
either in part, by Elgar and Simpson (1993) and by Addison and Siebert
(1997), or as a whole, by Dunn and Metcalf (1996). As well as this
research, we draw on recent interviews of our own with employers over a
wide range of industry.
Throughout the period an explicit link between legal change and
economic performance was made by government itself. But there were also
broader economic changes which were particularly unfavourable to
organised labour. Labour markets slackened and product markets
tightened, both very substantially. Official measures of unemployment,
which had averaged below 4 per cent of the workforce over the fifteen
years before 1980, rose to over 9 per cent during the subsequent fifteen
years. There was a massive increase in the exposure of the workforce to
product market competition. In manufacturing, imports increased as a
proportion of home demand from 26 per cent in 1980 to 45 per cent in
1995. The highly unionised public sector was greatly reduced in
employment and subjected to a variety of market mechanisms.
The bargaining system continued to fragment. In the private
sector, enterprise-based bargaining at plant or company level
increasingly eclipsed the once dominant multi-employer, industry level
agreements, the coverage of which fell from perhaps 60 per cent of the
workforce in 1950, to 30 per cent by 1980, and 10 per cent in 1990. The
principal explanation of the trend, evident in most industrialised countries, is the internationalisation of product markets, which
diminishes the advantages of national industry-based collective
bargaining (Brown and Walsh, 1994). As with the substantial
decentralisation of the public sector after 1980, this fragmentation
greatly reduced the industrial basis of trade union power, tying the
interests of union organisations increasingly to those of individual
employers. These changed economic and institutional circumstances had
consequences for trade unions which were in many ways similar to those
intended by the legislation, creating a further difficulty for its
evaluation.
The experience of other industrialised countries, in most of which
there were comparable changes in economic conditions, is of relevance
and will be drawn upon later. Most of these countries adapted to a
changing economic environment without undertaking similar adjustments to
their systems of industrial relations to Britain (OECD, 1994). In some,
greater labour flexibility was achieved and productivity enhanced
through adjustments to legislation which left collective institutions in
the field of employment largely intact (Deakin, 1991). A comparative
perspective suggests that the reforms adopted in Britain represent just
one possible path among many. However, we should not conclude from this
that the legislative changes made in Britain were either irrelevant or
unnecessary to the wider process of economic reform undertaken by the
Conservative governments. The question which we have to address is,
given the broad thrust of economic policy after 1979, did the changes
made to industrial relations legislation have the economic impact which
was envisaged for them?
2. Labour law and the industrial relations system before 1979
In order to assess the impact of changes in legislation in the period
after 1979, it is necessary to consider the role previously played by
the state within the industrial relations system. The essence of the
system which Kahn-Freund (1959) described in terms of `collective
laissez-faire' was that the state supported the principle of
collective self-organisation, without prescribing the form, level or
structure of collective bargaining. The statutory `immunities',
which protected the right to organise and the right to strike, insulated
trade unions and their members and officials from liabilities which
would otherwise have arisen at common law. The common law was (and is)
hostile to collective organisation. Trade unions, in so far as they seek
to regulate wages and conditions and to control the supply of labour,
are potentially acting in restraint of trade. As a result, at common law
they cannot effectively hold property or enforce their own rule books.
Industrial action almost inevitably involves the commission of one or
more legal wrongs (torts) which arise where economic pressure is
exercised collectively or with the effect that certain property or
contract rights are infringed. These rights could be those of employers,
non-members or non-strikers, or third parties such as consumers of
services.
In the Conspiracy and Protection of Property Act 1875 and again in
the Trade Disputes Act 1906, Parliament intervened to protect unions
from such liabilities. The restraint of trade doctrine was disarmed,
unions were exempted from all liability in tort, and individual
organisers of strike activity were protected against certain torts where
their action was taken `in contemplation or furtherance of a trade
dispute'. This formula, in turn, was given a broad meaning which
embraced secondary or sympathy action and action in support of the
closed shop.
Within this framework, collective bargaining developed to the
point where, by the 1950s, basic wage rates were set at industry level
in most sectors. Court-based sanctions played almost no role in the
process of resolving industrial disputes, nor in the enforcement of
collective agreements. Disputes between unions over spheres of influence
were settled under the auspices of the TUC, and not in the courts.
Although the courts were neutralised, other organs of the state
supported collective bargaining in various ways. From the mid-1890s on,
conciliation and arbitration were used to encourage employers to settle
disputes on the basis of agreements for the recognition of trade unions.
The principles of freedom of association and the right to organise were
adopted in the public sector after 1918. Both central and local
government pursued fair wages policies which had the effect of requiring
private contractors to recognise trade unions or to follow the going
rate. Regulatory legislation was introduced to deal with areas of
workplace relations where collective bargaining was limited in scope (in
particular, health and safety) or in low-paying sectors where voluntary
collective bargaining had failed to take root (as in the case of the
industries covered by the trade boards and, later, wages councils, which
in the late 1940s amounted to 25 per cent of the employed labour force).
Various attempts were made to modernise the system of collective
laissez-faire from the early 1960s onwards including the ill-fated
Industrial Relations Act of 1971, which offered unions a greater range
of positive legal rights (including a right to recognition) in return
for stricter legislative controls over union organisation, in particular
in relation to industrial action. The unions rejected the Act and it was
never effectively implemented before its repeal in 1974. Incomes
policies during this period failed in part because efforts to impose
greater control over wage increases from the centre were undermined by
the increasing decentralisation of bargaining to company and
establishment level which many unions favoured and which the reforms of
the Donovan Report (1968) also encouraged. Individual employment
protection legislation was introduced in the form of rights to a written
statement of terms and conditions, the payment of redundancy
compensation, protection against unfair dismissal, and rights to
compensation for interruption to wages. Anti-discrimination laws also
came in at this time. However, basic terms and conditions--in particular
wages and working hours--remained essentially the preserve of collective
bargaining. A policy of abolishing wages councils was pursued from the
1960s onwards, in the expectation (largely disappointed) that voluntary
collective bargaining would emerge in sectors where legal regulation was
removed.
The result was that by the end of the 1970s, British labour law lacked certain features which had been widely adopted elsewhere in
Europe, in particular universal minimum standards on wages and hours.
The state's support for the institutions of voluntary collective
bargaining had produced a system in which trade union membership was
high by international standards, and elements of union monopoly (the
closed shop in its various forms) were well entrenched. But in many
respects the system was more fragile than it appeared. Outside the core
of union strength in manufacturing and the public sector, organ]sat]on
was sporadic and the coverage of collective bargaining was patchy.
Despite their involvement in the corporatist experiments of the
mid-1970s, British trade unions had a more limited voice in economic
decisionmaking at all levels than some of their continental
counterparts. With the failure of the Bullock Committee (1977) there was
no equivalent to the various forms of codetermination and company- and
workplace-based employee representation which existed alongside union
organ]sat]on in some mainland systems.
3. Implementing neoliberal policies
The British system was subject to substantial criticism by neoliberal
theorists. Union organ]sat]on in general and the closed shop in
particular were seen as stifling managerial initiative and entrenching
`restrictive practices'. Hayek (1973) identified the Trade Disputes
Act 1906 as conferring upon the unions `unique privileges' which
protected them against the normal consequences of civil liability. He
argued for a return to the common law of tort and contract which the
statutory immunities had displaced. He also rejected most forms of
regulatory legislation aimed at protecting the employment relationship,
a criticism that had much less resonance for Britain in 1979 than it
would have had for other European systems.
However, Hayek's critique by no means implied a reduced role
for the law in relation to the labour market. A straightforward return
to private law, through deregulation, proved to be insufficient.
Although the trade dispute immunities were whittled away by successive
legal changes, in other respects the body of labour legislation grew
enormously to cope with the task of controlling collective labour
organ]sat]on. The state, and legislation in particular, remained a
powerful influence within the labour market.
What is of immediate interest here are the regulatory techniques
by which the goal of restoring a functioning labour market was to be
achieved. Three may be identified: the restoration of private law; the
use of competition policy and informal government pressure to
restructure systems of pay determination; and the restrictive
re-regulation of collective action.
Return to private law
The Employment Act 1982 made it possible for the first time since
1906 for the trade union itself to be sued in tort. In what was in
effect a partial restoration of the Taft Vale judgment of 1901, unions
were made responsible for the acts of certain officials and committees
in organising industrial action. The statutory change revived legal
possibilities which, in the context of industrial relations, had lain
dormant for decades. From 1982 on, unions engaging in tortious conduct
faced the prospect of injunctions prohibiting industrial action. Failure
to obey would result in fines for contempt being levied by the court
and, if necessary, collected through sequestration, involving the
seizure of union assets. This duly occurred in a number of major
disputes in the mid- to late- 1980s. In this way private law rights were
supplemented by the quasi-criminal procedures of contempt of court,
which were applied and extended by the courts in innovative ways.
The substantive scope of the immunities was gradually reduced, so
that by the end of the 1980s it was unlawful for industrial action to
involve secondary action, secondary picketing, action in defence of the
closed shop, and action in support of union recognition by third party
employers. The legal concept of the `trade dispute' was also
narrowed in such a way as to reinforce the tendency to confine lawful
industrial action to individual employment units. Picketing was subject
to new controls in the form of a limit on numbers and more effective
exercise of police powers. These changes to the law were used by
employers to tilt the balance of power in their favour during strikes.
Employers could effectively redraw the limits of lawful industrial
action through changes to corporate form, as appears to have happened
during the Wapping dispute (Ewing and Napier, 1986).
Competition policy and pay bargaining
The second strand represents the growing encroachment upon the
industrial relations system of competition policy. In the first wave of
1980s legislation, `props' to collective bargaining were removed.
These included the complex recognition procedure which had operated
through ACAS in the 1970s, and both the Fair Wages Resolution and the
`Schedule 11' procedure for extending the effect of industry-level
collective agreements to non-unionised firms and establishments. The
powers of the remaining wages councils were severely reduced (in 1986)
before they were removed completely in 1993, leaving only the
Agricultural Wages Board as the last minimum wage setting body.
Gradually, the focus of the law shifted from deregulation to active
intervention, aimed at limiting the scope of collective regulation of
wages and conditions. Compulsory competitive tendering to local
authorities, and a prohibition from imposing minimum labour standards,
were introduced in 1988. The abolition of the National Dock Labour
Scheme in 1989 removed the basis of operation of the pre-entry closed
shop in port transport.
Less formal government pressure was used to encourage changes in
the system of pay determination. The public sector received official
encouragement to decentralise bargaining, considerably constrained by
Treasury concerns about loss of public expenditure control. Since
industry level agreements in private industry were almost all based on
voluntary arrangements, it was not necessary to introduce legislation in
order to encourage continuing change there. Changes to industrial
relations law nevertheless facilitated the break up of industrial
agreements, by making it more difficult for trade unions to mount
nationwide disputes.
Re-regulation of collective action
New forms of regulation sprang up to restrict the scope for
collective action by workers. These included the imposition upon trade
unions of complex procedural requirements, relating to the conduct of
industrial action, the recruitment and organisation of members, and
internal union governance. In relation to industrial action, the
essential point is that the regulations dovetailed with the newly
effective private law liabilities. Once the principle of the trade
union's liability in tort was re-established, it provided the route
to imposing upon the union the obligation to conduct a ballot in respect
of industrial action. If the union failed to conduct an appropriate
ballot, with a simple majority voting in support of the action, it would
forfeit any further immunity it would otherwise have had. Following the
initial 1984 Act, the procedural constraints on unions were gradually
tightened. From 1988, it became necessary in certain cases to conduct
separate ballots for each workplace and to obtain a separate majority in
each one. After 1990 it was no longer possible for the union to organise
a ballot in order to legitimise industrial action which had already
begun. The ballot now had to precede the industrial action. This was the
precursor to the introduction (in 1993) of a requirement that the union
give seven days' notice of the commencement of industrial action.
Notice of the ballot itself was made mandatory. The union was also
required to provide the employer with a list of its members entitled to
take part in the ballot.
These and related procedural restrictions are also closely linked
to changes which were made to the law governing the dismissal of
employees taking part in industrial action. At common law, an employee
taking part in such action almost invariably commits a breach of his or
her contract of employment. Prior to 1971, when unfair dismissal law was
introduced for the first time, there was no legal protection for
strikers whatsoever; they were liable to instant dismissal. With the
arrival of statutory controls over dismissal, it became necessary to
specify what the rights of strikers were. The Labour government of
1974-79 provided employers with an immunity from liability in unfair
dismissal only if all those taking part in a strike or other industrial
action at the relevant time were dismissed. Either selective dismissal,
or selective re-engagement, would result in the loss of this
employer's immunity.
From the early 1980s onwards, the employer's immunity was
widened, most notably by allowing selective reengagement of strikers
after a certain period had elapsed. In 1990 it became possible for an
employer to dismiss on a selective basis individuals taking part in
industrial action which the union had not authorised. Faced with
industrial action which started prior to a ballot, a union now had two
options, each unpleasant. It could either endorse the action, in which
case it would automatically face legal consequences, most likely an
injunction and claims for damages in tort; or it could repudiate it,
leaving its members vulnerable to selective dismissals. If the union
organised a protest action against the dismissal it would face further
legal liabilities.
Changes to unfair dismissal law provided the principal means by
which the closed shop was made effectively inoperable, or, in some
cases, driven underground. Under the law put in place by the 1974 Labour
government, it was automatically unfair for an employer to dismiss an
employee on the grounds of his or her trade union membership, and
enhanced compensation was payable. However, it was automatically fair to
dismiss on grounds of an employee's non-membership where a
`union-membership agreement', or closed shop, was in force. In the
1980s, the scope for fair dismissal on grounds of non-membership was
gradually reduced, until in 1988 a principle of parity between members
and non-members was established. Dismissal on the grounds of either
membership or nonmembership was automatically unfair.
In 1990 a new, statutory civil wrong was also created, to prevent
employers refusing to hire workers on the grounds of membership or
non-membership. This helped put an end to the pre-entry closed shop.
However, it did not affect the blacklisting of individuals on the basis
of their past trade union activities. The increasing role of the law may
be contrasted to the position prior to the introduction of unfair
dismissal law in the 1970s, when employers had, in legal terms, complete
freedom to adopt whatever strategy they liked, but where, in practice,
they were constrained by the social force of union organisation to adopt
closed shops. Further changes to the law undermined the principle of
parity between membership and non-membership, and employers exploited
the growing weakness of unions on the ground to pursue strategies aimed
at discouraging union membership. For a while, judicial decisions kept
in check attempts by employers to provide differential benefits to
members in particular unions, or to non-unionists. Such practices
infringed the principle that no `action short of dismissal' should
be taken to penalise either membership or non-membership. However,
following the decision of the House of Lords in the Wilson and Palmer
case (1995), it became possible for employers to introduce
`individualised' or personal contracts of employment outside the
scope of collective agreements, without falling foul of the law, a
result which Parliament itself sanctioned by amending the relevant
legislation while the case was going through the courts (Deakin and
Morris, 1995).
The law relating to internal union governance saw some of the most
pronounced effects of restrictive regulation. Statutory controls over
the admission, discipline and expulsion of members were introduced.
Unions were prevented from taking disciplinary action against
strikebreakers. Periodic ballots became mandatory for senior union
posts, and for the purposes of maintaining a political fund. The
organisation of members and the collection of union dues were made
procedurally more complex and expensive, by requiring workers to give
written authorisation every three years for employers' deducting
membership dues from wages.
4. Countervailing influences: European Community law
The tide of legislation did not just flow in one direction.
Throughout the period from 1979, the influence of European Community law
grew steadily (Deakin, 1997). EC labour law, while far from representing
a comprehensive body of labour legislation, nevertheless draws on a
continental tradition in which the rights of employees are laid down in
constitutional texts and legislative codes. This contrasts with the
British tradition of collective laissez faire. Unlike standards laid
down in conventions of the ILO, those contained in the European
Community Treaty, and in directives and regulations, may form part of
the domestic legal order. A series of court rulings established that
European Community law took priority over domestic law in the event of a
conflict, and that certain rights--those having `direct
effect'--could be directly enforced by individuals in the UK
courts. Legislation concerning equal pay and equal treatment between men
and women, on the one hand, and employment protection, on the other,
slowly began to take effect in Britain. Equal pay for work of equal
value was introduced in 1983, and the principle of equal treatment was
later applied to retirement and pension rights.
An influential EC provision was the 1977 Acquired Rights
Directive, which had been implemented by a Conservative government in
1981 in the form of the Transfer of Undertakings (Protection of
Employment) Regulations. The European Court of Justice made it clear in
a series of judgements that the Directive could be invoked to preserve
the rights of employees affected by outsourcing or where there was a
change in the identity of the employer following privatisation. It also
held that existing UK law failed to make adequate provision for
consultation with employee representatives in the event of a transfer or
large scale redundancies. A number of EC measures in the field of health
and safety, in particular Directives on Working Time and Young Workers,
also necessitated changes in UK law during this period.
The government's willingness to use its veto in the Council
of Ministers effectively blocked a number of new initiatives and, to
this extent, it was able to limit the influence of European level norms.
This policy reached its logical conclusion in the opt-out from the
so-called Social Chapter in the Maastricht Treaty. However, the
UK's self-exclusion enabled the other member states to make
progress on measures such as the European Works Councils Directive. All
eligible UK-based multinationals appear to have extended EWC arrangements to their British operations, even though not legally
obliged to do so. EWCs are so far in place in 53 UK based and 151
overseas based companies operating in Britain, and a further 127
UK-based companies will become subject to the Directive when
Britain's opt-out is reversed (EWC Bulletin). The Maastricht Treaty
also initiated `social dialogue' or discussion between social
partners at transnational level, encompassing the British CBI and TUC,
with agreements on parental leave and on the rights of part-time workers
being a tangible result. It is a process with the potential to transform
still further the relationship between European-level labour standards
and the laws of individual member states.
5. Outcomes--the coverage of trade unions and of bargaining
As we have seen, the intention of the legislative programme was to
reduce in various ways the impact of trade unions and the coverage of
collective bargaining. Table 1 provides data on membership collected
from unions, as well as that more recently available from individuals;
their absolute figures differ but they point in the same direction. The
steady growth in trade union membership of the 1970s turned to a sharp
fall in the early 1980s which slowed in the late 1980s before turning to
a sharper decline in the first half of the 1990s.
Table 1. Trade union membership in the UK, 1971-96
Certification Officer Data
Members (000s) % of employed
5-year annual average
1971-75 11,548 (+1.5) 50.0
1976-80 12,916 (+1.5) 55.1
1981-85 11,350 (-3.5) 53.2
1986-90 10,299 (-1.7) 46.1
1991-95 8,740 (-4.0) 40.2
annual
1989 10,158 (-2.1) 44.2
1990 9,947 (-2.1) 43.9
1991 9.585 (-3.6) 43.8
1992 9,048 (-5.6) 42.3
1993 8,700 (-3.8) 40.2
1994 8,278 (-4.9) 38.1
1995 8,089 (-2.3) 36.7
1996 n.a. n.a.
Labour Force Survey Data
Members(000s) % of employed
5-year annual average
1971-75 n.a. n.a.
1976-80 n.a. n.a.
1981-85 n.a. n.a.
1986-90 n.a. n.a.
1991-95 7,854 34.8
annual
1989 8,964 39.0
1990 8,854 (-1.2) 38.1
1991 8,633 (-2.5) 37.5
1992 7,999 (-7.3) 35.8
1993 7,808 (-2.4) 35.1
1994 7,553 (-3.30 33.6
1995 7,275 (-3.7) 32.1
1996 7,215 (-0.8) 31.3
Sources: Employment Gazette and Labour Market Trends (various).
Figures in brackets indicate percentage change in membership as an
annual rate.
It is helpful to place Britain's unionisation experience in
an international perspective (Table 2). Many of the economic and
structural factors that influence unionisation are common to most
industrialised countries. There are considerable difficulties in
interpreting absolute differences between countries, but the comparison
of their experiences over time is useful. Many have experienced
substantial declines in union membership during the 1980s and 1990s.
Indeed, the UK's `league position' in this list barely
changed, at about the midway point, between 1970 and 1995. Bearing in
mind that several of the countries saw declining membership while
governments were in power which were sympathetic to trade
unions--France, Spain and Australia, for example--it is not immediately
evident that Britain's legislative experience had a distinctive
impact.
Table 2. Trade union membership by country as a percentage of all
employees, 1970-95
Country 1970 1980 1990 1995
United Kingdom 45[9th] 50[10th] 39[10th] 32[11th]
Australia 50 48 40 33
Austria 62 56 46 43
Belgium 45 56 51 53
Canada 31 36 36 34
Denmark 60 76 71 82
Finland 51 70 72 81
France 22 17 10 9
Germany (West) 33 36 33 29(*)
Greece 36 37 34 n.a.
Ireland 53 57 50 38
Italy 36 49 39 38
Japan 35 31 25 24
Netherlands 38 35 25 26
New Zealand 41 56 45 22
Norway 51 57 56 56
Portugal 61 61 32 32
Spain 27 25 11 15
Sweden 68 80 82 83
Switzerland 30 31 27 26
United States 23 22 16 15
Trade union membership as a per cent of wage- and salary-earners. (*)
1993 Source for 1970-90: OECD Employment Outlook, July 1994; cf for
details. Sources for 1995: various including ILO unpublished; Ebbinghaus
and Visser (forthcoming); Ferner and Hyman (forthcoming); miscellaneous.
UK rank order of highness of density.
The decline in membership in Britain has been traced to various
factors. Although Freeman and Pelletier (1990) tried to link it directly
to the early legal changes, other research suggests that more dominant
influences have included the changing composition of employment, and
limited bargaining opportunities at new sites (Geroski et al, 1995;
Disney et al, 1996). These studies support the view implied by the
international comparison that British legislative change has not exerted
a major influence on union membership.
Coverage of collective bargaining
One of the startling findings of the 1990 Workplace Industrial
Relations Survey (WIRS) was the extent to which the coverage of
collective bargaining had contracted after the 1984 WIRS. The proportion
of employees in workplaces of 25 or more covered by collective
bargaining fell from 71 per cent to 54 per cent over the six year period
(Millward et al, 1992). Dunn and Metcalf (1996) concluded that much of
this arose from broader changes in the way employment is managed, most
notably the shift from industry level to enterprise-based bargaining,
rather than from legislative change.
There is, however, a deeper point, best made by international
comparison. Table 3 shows the proportion of the employed workforce
covered by collective bargaining or some form of enforceable industrial
wage arrangement in ten OECD countries between 1980 and 1994. The
British figures up to 1990 overstate as they combine the coverage of
collective agreements and wages councils (abolished in 1993), ignoring a
degree of overlap (Milner, 1995). The British figure for 1994 is the
proportion of employees in workplaces with some union recognition and
also overstates somewhat (Cully and Woodland, 1997). Several of these
countries have experienced substantial declines in unionisation over the
period. But none experienced so dramatic a fall in coverage of
agreements as Britain. This is partly because, for several European
countries, the law provides what are called `extension rules'
whereby the terms and conditions of a collective agreement can be made
legally binding over those non-unionised employees who are within the
appropriate industry or bargaining unit (OECD, 1994). Thus, although the
decline of trade union membership in Britain may not have been
exceptional in international terms, the implications of it are. When
taken with the abolition of statutory wage minima, it will be evident
that Britain has, in a relatively short time, become exceptional within
Europe in its low coverage of collective arrangements (Gregory and
Sandoval, 1994).
Table 3. The proportion of the workforce covered by collective
bargaining and statutory sectoral wage arrangements by country 1980-94
Country 1980 1985 1990 1994
United Kingdom 83 76 65 48
Australia 88 85 80 80
Canada n.a. 37 38 36
Finland 95 n.a. 95 95(**)
France 85 92 95 95(*)
Germany 91 91 90 92(**)
Japan 28 n.a. 23 22
Netherlands 76 76 71 81(**)
Spain n.a. 67 68 66(**)
United States 26 20 18 18
Source: UK: maxima derived from Milner (1995) and Cully and Woodland
(1997). Non UK: For 1980, '85, '90: OECD Employment Outlook,
July 1994. For 1994, OECD unpublished from Blanchflower (1996) (*) 1992;
(**) 1993.
Closed shop
We can sharpen our focus by looking at two sources of trade union
security which have been the subject of direct legislative action: the
closed shop and union recognition by employers. The WIRS evidence is
that the coverage of closed shops declined from over five million union
members in 1980 to under half a million in 1990 (Millward et al, 1992).
The pre-entry closed shop had previously been in retreat as its
craft-based and other bastions shrank, but several industries with
substantial pre-entry closed shops (notably in printing, newspapers,
television, shipping, and docks) lost them in the 1980s as a direct
result of disputes in which the outcome was critically dependent upon
recent legal changes. The relevant legislation here was not the banning
of the pre-entry closed shop per se, which did not become effective
until 1991, but rather the earlier prohibition of the secondary action
and mass picketing upon which it had depended for viability at industry
level (Elgar and Simpson, 1993).
So far as the more common post-entry closed shop was concerned,
however, action in its defence did not become illegal until the 1988
Act, and many employers who had routinely treated it as a source of
procedural discipline continued subsequently to support it informally
(Wright, 1996). Union membership was not substantially greater in 1990
where a closed shop survived than where the union had no more than
strong endorsement by management, leading to the conclusion that `the
decline of the closed shop had only a limited part to play in the
overall drop in union membership' (Millward et al, 1992:101).
Recognition
Continuing decline in union membership in the 1990s suggests there
may have been a change in employer policy toward recognition. The
evidence of the 1980s was that union derecognition was unusual. The WIRS
panel data suggested that withdrawal of recognition reflected employee
apathy rather than employer initiative (Millward et al, 1992; Beaumont
and Harris, 1995). But there was evidence that unions were being shunned
in new premises, and only a minority of companies which already
recognised unions automatically granted recognition at new sites
(Marginson et al, 1996)
More recently there has been evidence of a shift towards more
strategic derecognition. A survey of unions suggested that a step
increase in derecognition occurred during 1987 (Claydon, 1996).
Certainly there is growing anecdotal evidence that strategic
derecognition has, during the 1990s, become a feature of many industries
where once trade unions were strong, notably the newly privatised
utilities, printing, publishing, television, docks, and chemicals. How
far has this development been dependent upon legal change? Many
employers who have derecognised unions have told us that they considered
that the legal changes had been important. Rather than specify
particular acts, they have generally said that it was the whole range of
post-1980 legislation which had contributed to a change in attitude and
made possible the new strategies of which &recognition was a part.
6. Trade union governance and finances
One of the stated intentions of the legislation was to make trade
unions more accountable to their members. Research suggests that it
strengthened the national leadership of unions (Undy et al, 1996; Heery,
1996). This was partly because of the necessity of controlling the
conduct of strike ballots in order to avoid expensive procedural errors.
In addition, the requirement to maintain a record of members' names
and addresses and to publish financial details has stimulated
improvements in their information, accounting and communication systems.
Unions generally complied with the laws affecting their own governance.
This had no consistent impact on their policies; it did not, for
example, promote the emergence of more `moderate' leadership. The
outcome of ballots depends in part upon the presence of factions which
can organise the vote. More formal processes such as postal ballots do
not generally increase turnouts, and increased turnouts do not generally
lead to more moderate outcomes.
How far has the legislative change affected the financial
resources of trade unions? Many unions suffered financially during the
1980s when they incurred the penalties for newly illegal actions. Such
expensive conflicts have been unusual in the 1990s. The use of
injunctions by employers involved in industrial disputes, which had
looked like becoming an expensive field of litigation in the 1980s, has
diminished in the 1990s with the number of applications made generally
falling to single figures per year (Gall and McKay, 1996).
A potentially costly legal innovation encouraged individuals to
take their own action against trade unions. The Commissioner for the
Rights of Trade Union Members was established in 1988 with considerable
investigative powers as a self-styled `union ombudsman', and with
the duty to provide a form of `legal aid' for union members wishing
to pursue a grievance. However, the fact that her agency has paid legal
costs averaging only 125,000 [pounds sterling] per year for the five
years since 1991 suggests that it did not generate substantial extra
burdens for trade unions. In 1993 she was given additional duties as
Commissioner for Protection Against Unlawful Industrial Action to help
members of the public believing themselves to be financially damaged by
unlawful strikes, but there has been minimal use of this facility
(CRTUM/CPAUIA, 1996). Unions appear to be coping with these legal and
financial minefields.
Apart from the penalties for newly unlawful actions, the
legislation has given trade unions increased difficulties in raising
funds and also increased running costs. The 1984 requirement to have a
ballot authorising a political fund every ten years triggered a second
round of ballots between 1993 and 1996, and this time they had to be
postal. However, although this new requirement reduced the turnout
substantially, the outcome was a very similarly supportive 4:1 vote in
favour as had been delivered in the first 1985/86 round, and with a
slightly increased number of unions participating (Leopold, 1997).
The requirement for postal ballots has brought additional costs to
unions. From 1980 until 1996 they could reclaim some of these from the
Government, and over that period a total of 24 million [pounds sterling]
was paid back. By the mid 1990s, when the scheme was being widely used,
the costs implied by the compensation paid averaged over 3 million
[pounds sterling] per year, approximately one third of which was for
strike ballots (Certification Office, unpublished data). This amounts to
approximately half a per cent of trade unions' total annual
expenditure. Although this cost, which unions since 1996 have had to
bear themselves, may not seem particularly high, it is additional to the
procedurally demanding balloting rules. It is significant that well over
half of all injunctions sought by employers relate to alleged balloting
infringements.
These increased costs should be put in the perspective of the
broader financial circumstances of trade unions (Table 4). Although
these aggregate data conceal variations between unions, it is clear that
their overall finances have deteriorated since the 1950s and early
1960s, when unions had substantial reserves and adequate income, not
least from membership subscriptions. They apparently failed both to
invest in inflation-proof assets and to keep up the real value of
subscriptions. Most unions have thus been left with few reserves for
bargaining purposes. Undiminished competition for membership has
prevented effective increases in subscriptions. Unions have improved and
centralised their controls, but their financial performance continues to
deteriorate (Willman and Morris, 1995). This deterioration long
pre-dates both membership decline and the legislative change.
Table 4. Trade union financial ratios
Date (assets-liab) subs income
total expenditure total expenditure
1951-55 4.13 1.04
1956-60 3.54 0.97
1961-65 3.60 1.03
1966-70 2.92 0.87
1971-75 n.a. n.a.
1976-80 1.47 0.96
1981-85 1.29 0.90
1986-90 1.25 0.85
1991-95 1.09 0.84
Date total income
total expenditure
1951-55 1.18
1956-60 1.11
1961-65 1.19
1966-70 1.08
1971-75 n.a.
1976-80 1.14
1981-85 1.12
1986-90 1.05
1991-95 1.03
Source: Willman, Morris and Aston (1993), Certification Officer
Annual Reports, (various). Data for 1971-75 are unavailable because of
non-registration under the Industrial Relations Act (1971).
An important factor lying behind the depletion of union finances
was that, with the gradual emergence of enterprise-based bargaining in
the 1970s and 1980s, unions became increasingly reliant upon employers
for resources. It became accepted in many industries that employers
provided shop stewards with paid time for their union duties, deducted
union dues for them, and gave them access to office facilities. By 1990,
in the diminishing number of establishments where workplace
representation continued to be recognised, such support still continued
(Millward et al, 1992). This increased dependence of workplace union
organisations upon resources under management control has made them
potentially more malleable to the employer's will and increasingly
vulnerable to the withdrawal of bargaining rights.
Thus, while legal change may have restored some authority to union
leaderships, it is on the basis of considerably reduced resources.
Furthermore, for reasons largely unconnected with legislation, the
decentralised organisations into which their unions are increasingly, in
effect, fragmenting have become heavily dependent upon the employers
with whom they negotiate, and consequently more compliant in
accommodating to change and accepting job losses.
7. Outcomes--industrial disputes
The steady decline in strikes of the 1980s continued into the 1990s
(Table 5) as has the tendency towards smaller and shorter disputes. The
decline in collective action has not, however, been matched by
individual disputes. The early 1990s saw a sharp rise in cases going to
ACAS conciliation. This did not reflect increasing claims against unfair
dismissal, which have remained surprisingly constant at around 40,000
per year for the past twenty years, but against discrimination, breach
of contract (by either side) and incorrect payment of wages. The rise
suggests that the steadily widening jurisdiction of ACAS and the
Industrial Tribunals is substituting to some extent for needs previously
met by trade unions, and also that unions are increasingly resorting to
ACAS as a means of supporting their members.
Table 5. Strikes and individual grievance conciliation in Britain:
average annual statistics, 1990-96
Stoppages Working days Per cent Individual
reported lost per of stoppages concilia-
1000 lasting not tion cases
employees more than received by
3 days ACAS (000s)
1960-64 2512 139 74 n.a.
1965-69 2380 168 65 n.a.
1970-74 2917 629 49 n.a.
1975-79 2345 509 43 43.5(*)
1980-84 1363 484 54 44.8
1985-89 895 180 58 45.7
1990-94 334 37 65 67.8
1995-96 240 39 67 96.0
Source: Employment Gazette, Labour Market Trends (various), ACAS
Annual Report (various); (*)data for 1976-79.
Survey evidence suggests that legal changes have shaped but not
eliminated the particular forms of industrial action against which they
were targeted. Legal requirements notwithstanding, secret ballots were
reported not to have been held in over a third of instances of strike
action and in the majority of instances of non-strike action during
1989-90. While political strikes had all but gone, the equally unlawful
sympathy strike and secondary picketing were still in evidence in 1990.
Mass picketing had largely gone, but picketing in numbers greater than
the recommended `six per entrance' was still common, though less so
than in 1980 (Millward et al, 1992).
It is helpful to discuss the implications of the legislation in a
theoretical context. Hicks/Nash bargaining theory suggests that the
outcome of negotiations depends on the relative vulnerability of the two
parties during a dispute. The legislation increased strike costs to
labour, both to the individual employee faced with greater threat of
dismissal, and to the trade union faced with increased costs of
procedural compliance and larger penalties for noncompliance. Theory
predicts that higher strike costs to unions lead to lower pay
settlements. The incentive to avoid strikes, viewed as bargaining
mishaps, will increase when joint strike costs increase. Bargaining
theory also implies that disputes arise from informational asymmetries,
concerning either the costs of a dispute to either party or the amount
of surplus available to be shared by the union.
It is often argued that the balloting legislation may have reduced
the incidence of disputes by providing clearer evidence of membership
willingness to strike. The high proportion of ballots for industrial
action that are carried suggests that union leaders choose their
balloting occasions carefully. The proportion of strike ballots notified
to ACAS which went in favour of industrial action has remained high at
92 per cent in both 1987-89 and 1994-95. Moreover, industrial action did
not follow in the majority of cases where a ballot went in favour. Of
the more intractable cases of majority support for action on which ACAS
was asked to conciliate over the period 1994-96, only 20 per cent were
followed by a strike, and only a further 16 per cent by action short of
a strike (ACAS, unpublished data).
It is, however, not clear how a majority vote will be interpreted,
unless it is for rejection. There is anecdotal evidence that strike
ballots are used as cheap substitutes for action, with an element of
bluff. It costs a union member little to vote for industrial action,
especially as the enhanced anonymity of the ballot makes it possible to
vote for action without such strong consequential obligation to join it.
The costs to the individual of non-compliance in collective action were
further reduced by the removal in 1988 of any formal union powers to
discipline non-strikers. The information provided by ballots is thus of
limited value.
Union officers consider that ballots provide a valuable source of
credibility, although later legislative changes have made them more
legally hazardous (Elgar and Simpson, 1996). The study by Undy et al
(1996) concluded that strike ballots did make a minor contribution to
preventing strikes because they signalled resolve without recourse to
action and they encouraged the option of action short of a strike.
Another factor was the fear of legal action if ballots were not properly
conducted, a point underlined by employers' relatively heavy use of
injunctions over their conduct.
As was the case with union membership, this cautious view of the
effect of the legislation upon British strikes is reinforced by
international comparison (Table 6). There has been a world-wide decline
in strike incidence, suggesting economic and political influences common
to many advanced economies. The British decline has been greater than
average, moving the country from a middling to a low rank, and
suggesting a distinctive role for influences specific to Britain, of
which one might be legislation. However, the implications of the change
in rank are limited at these low incidence levels. Had Britain merely
maintained its 1986-90 rank, its strike incidence would still have had
to fall from 137 to below 55 working days lost per 1,000 employees as
opposed to the 24 recorded. The implications for any distinctive effect
of British legislation are accordingly muted.
Table 6. International comparison of working days lost per 1000
employees, 1981-95
Country 1981-85 1986-90 1991-95
United Kingdom 440[15th] 137[11th] 24[5th]
Australia 386 224 130
Austria 2 2 6
Belgium n.a. (48) 32
Canada 532 429 159
Denmark 306 41 45
Finland 326 410 218
France 78 111 94
Germany 52 5 17
Greece 516 6316 1148
Ireland 474 242 109
Italy 774 315 183
Japan 10 5 (3)
Netherlands 24 13 33
New Zealand 408 425 55
Norway 58 142 62
Portugal 176 82 34
Spain 584 602 469
Sweden 40 134 50
Switzerland n.s. n.s. 1
United States 128 82 42
Notes: Data from Employment Gazette, June 1989 and Labour Market
Trends, April 1997. () Brackets indicate averages based on incomplete
rank order of lowness of days lost excludes Belgium data. n.a. = not
available, n.s. = less than five days lost per thousand. UK
8. Economic outcomes--pay
Other studies have attempted to trace economic outcomes of the
legislation with regard to pay, productivity, employment and
profitability. Here we focus on the first two, as being more immediately
open to legislative influence. We also focus on the microeconomic evidence, because causal links are even harder to trace at aggregate
level. Space constraints prevent our referring to more than a selection
of the relevant recent research. So far as pay is concerned, increases
in the costs of union organisation and of industrial action might be
expected to lower the wage which unions achieve. This would be expected
to lead, first, to a fall in the pay differential between employees in
unions (or covered by agreements) and others and, second, to a decline
in inflationary wage pressure. The evidence for these is discussed in
turn.
Union pay differentials
Econometric research into the union differential in pay is impeded by
the inadequacy of the controls for other relevant characteristics,
whether of individuals or workplaces. It also neglects the common
practice of nonunion employers in paying higher wages specifically to
exclude unions. With these serious reservations, the research of the
last decade has painted a reasonably coherent but modest picture. It
suggests that trade unions typically achieve only moderately higher pay
for their members relative to comparable non-members. In the early 19805
the union differential is estimated from establishment data to have been
no more than 10 per cent for any category of manual employee, and
insignificant for skilled workers (Stewart, 1987; 1990). The results
from individual employee data were very similar (Blanchflower, 1996;
Main, 1996).
The effect of unions on pay suggested by the evidence from
establishment data is varied (Table 7). The low water mark is associated
with highly competitive product markets, where the differential is
estimated at zero. The high water mark is where there is a pre-entry
closed shop, where the union pay differential is variously estimated
during the early 19805 as between 7 and 23 per cent, according to skill
level. Only a pre-entry closed shop was associated with a positive
differential in competitive product markets (Stewart, 1990). It was also
associated with a wage gain additional to that linked to high membership
density at the workplace, leading to the conclusion that it was `the one
institutional form of trade unionism which really bit in terms of
pay' (Metcalf and Stewart, 1992: 514).
Table 7. Estimated trade union net pay mark-up over nonunion pay in
the UK, by occupation, 1980, 1984 and 1990
Union Occupational 1980 1984 1990
category category
All(a) skilled .030 .034 .015
semi-skilled .075(*) .100(*) .063(*)
unskilled n.a. .102(*) .072(*)
Pre-entry closed skilled .073 .174(*) .074
shop only(b) semi-skilled .139(*) .226(*) .080
unskilled n.a. .191(*) .118(*)
Source: Stewart (1987), Table 2, (1995), Tables 3,4. (*) indicates
significance at 5 per cent level.
Note: estimates refer to mean difference in log of weekly earnings of
typical employee in each category in workplaces where (a) unions are
recognised for bargaining purposes for manual workers and (b) at least
some employees are covered by a pre-entry closed shop, relative to
workplaces without union recognition for manual workers, after
controlling for available workplace attributes, including sector,
ownership, and workforce composition. The percentage union pay premium
is approximately 100 times the coefficient.
From that starting point, the overall union pay differential is
estimated to have fallen moderately, after 1984 and through to 1990 at
least; and the differential associated with the pre-entry closed shop,
to have fallen substantially (Gregg and Machin, 1991; 1992). By 1990 the
wage effect attributable to the pre-entry closed shop, which was about
to become legally indefensible, had become indistinguishable from that
attributable to the post-entry variant, and both from that attributable
for the de facto closed shops by then allowed by law (Stewart, 1995).
The heterogeneity of union wage effects therefore fell during the 1980s.
There are difficulties of disentangling the effects of legal
changes from those of increased competition in labour and product
markets. The fact that the average union pay differential fell so little
during the 1980s may reflect its low level at the outset, but it means
that there is little for legal changes to explain (Stewart, 1991). Pay
structures were shaped in the 1980s primarily by changes in product
markets, which broadly affected union and non-union firms alike, tending
to intensify non-union causes of segmentation in labour markets (Ingram,
1991; Blanchflower, 1991; Blanchflower and Freeman, 1994).
The decline of union-related pay was most marked under the
pre-entry closed shop. Moreover, the coverage of pre-entry closed shops
contracted sharply during the 1980s. These two changes accounted for 60
per cent of the fall in the overall union pay differential during
1984-90 (Stewart, 1995). It is here that legal changes can perhaps be
most plausibly linked to the institutional changes, even after allowing
for differences in timing, and the primacy of changes in technology and
product markets. It is not possible yet to give an account of
developments in the 1990s, but it appears likely that increasing
derecognition of unions has taken over from the decline of the closed
shop as the main factor eroding union pay differentials, though the
influence of union recognition on pay appears to be weaker than that of
the closed shop (Gregg and Machin, 1991).
Wage pressure and pay inequalities
At aggregate level, weakened trade unions might be expected to exert
less of the wage pressure to which Britain's inflationary problems
have in part been attributed, thereby reducing the unemployment rate at
which inflation accelerates (Layard et al, 1991). The prospects for such
an interpretation are, however, greatly impaired by the weakness of
estimated declines in union mark-ups since 1979 and by the smallness of
the average mark-up, and also by the lack of consensus on the existence,
let alone the size, of equilibrium unemployment (Main, 1996; Henry and
Lee, 1997). The continuation of wage pressure after 1979 has been widely
attributed to employer pay strategies and insider power, in non-union
and union companies alike, rather than to any crude effect of unionism
per se (Blanchflower and Freeman, 1994; Brown et al, 1995; Brown et al,
1997). The downward trend in the share of employment income in national
and household incomes since the 1970s may, however have been generated
partly by the, weakening of trade unions (Ryan, 1996). Otherwise the.,
legislation appears to have been tangential to wage setting and
macroeconomic performance.
Pay inequality has since the 1970s grown more rapidly in the UK
than in any other advanced economy except the USA. While the general
tendency for pay inequalities to rise in most advanced economies has
been attributed to technical change and international trade, marked
differences in trends between countries have been attributed primarily
to changes in national institutions, with the deregulation of the UK
economy as an outstanding instance (Freeman and Katz, 1995; OECD, 1996;
Nickell and Bell, 1996). Between one-eighth and one quarter of the
growth of earnings inequality in the UK during the 1980s has been
attributed to the decline in bargaining coverage (Gosling and Machin,
1995; Schmitt, 1995).
Although we have judged legal changes to have been a secondary
cause of declining unionisation in Britain, statutory wage protection
constitutes an important area of influence upon economic outcomes. The
weakening and eventual removal of wages councils was associated with
increased pay dispersion in low wage sectors and, to a lesser extent,
declining relative pay for, and growing pay inequality amongst, young
workers, who were the first to be removed from coverage (Machin and
Manning, 1994; Garonna and Ryan, 1991). In that respect at least,
legislative change has contributed directly to the widening of pay
inequalities in contemporary Britain.
9. Economic outcomes--productivity
Stronger effects might be anticipated for industrial relations
legislation in relation to economic performance. It is widely accepted
that Britain's system of industrial relations constrained
productivity growth in the post-war period, albeit with disagreement
over whether the prime responsibility lay with trade unions or
employers, or both. To the extent that trade unionism was responsible,
legislation since 1979, with its anti-union orientation, should have
improved economic performance. As with pay, outcomes have moved in the
intended direction. Although Britain's investment and employment
record continues to cause concern, at least the post-war gap between
productivity growth in Britain and other European economies has not
re-emerged since 1979 (Crafts, 1997). The difficulty is to distinguish
the contribution of anti-union policies in general, and the legislation
in particular, from a wider recasting of British industrial relations
(Metcalf, 1993; Nolan, 1996).
The productivity effects of trade unions are complex and the
theoretical debates cannot be explored here. Their influence depends,
inter alia, upon product market characteristics, occupational
specificity, the nature of technological change, and the employer's
response. No general prediction emerges concerning union effects on
productivity. The matter is for any open-minded economist an empirical
one, dependent on both the quality of management and the competitiveness
of the product market.
Strong traditions of craft control and workplace bargaining have
long implied adverse productivity effects in a range of industries.
There is evidence that the end of the 1970s marked a turning point. The
extent to which nonpay issues were negotiated at the workplace declined
between 1980 and 1984 (Millward et al, 1992). A linking of productivity
with pay negotiations become more frequent in the early 1980s (Marsden
and Thompson, 1990). Productivity growth in unionised employment
increased relative to that in its non-union counterpart between the
1970s and the early 1980s, by when, by most accounts, it had become
absolutely higher (Wadhwani, 1990; Oulton, 1990; Nickell et al, 1992).
The picture which emerges is the retreat of restrictions on working
practices, and an association with higher productivity growth not of
unionism per se, but of unionism at that juncture.
There is mixed evidence on the investment and innovation aspects
of the union-productivity nexus. That suggestive of an adverse
association between unionism and productivity includes a tendency for
firms which derecognised unions to achieve higher than average
productivity growth during the mid-1980s (Gregg et al, 1993); and a
lower rate of investment, ceteris paribus, at unionised than at other
manufacturing establishments in 1984 (Denny and Nickell, 1992). By
contrast, Machin (1995) found that the extreme disinvestment of plant
closure was no more common in union than at non-union workplaces during
1984-90; Daniel (1987) found widespread support amongst employees and
union representatives for the introduction of technical change; and,
applying multivariate analysis to the same data, Machin and Wadhwani
(1991) found that union recognition was associated positively, albeit
weakly, with the introduction of technical change. Similarly, the
introduction of human resource management techniques appears if anything
more extensive where unions are present (Millward, 1994; Guest and
Hoque, 1996).
When the net is cast wider to consider particular attributes of
economic performance, positive associations with trade union presence
have been found in econometric studies of training (Green, 1993;),
labour turnover (Elias, 1994) and health and safety at work (Sandy and
Elliott, 1996). The dual importance of, first, market failure in the
provision of training (Stevens, 1995) and, second, training for
productivity (Steedman and Wagner 1988) point to a
productivity-enhancing role for trade unions. Similar considerations
apply to health and safety at work where the weakening of union
influence since 1979 has encouraged the erosion of pre-1980 successes
(OECD, 1989; Dawson et al, 1988).
These findings rule out any simple association between unionism
and productivity and point to the other factors which mediate between
the two. The potentially important factors are the characteristics of
employers and product markets. The role of the employer is difficult to
investigate because few data sets offer good measures of employer
attributes, with the result that the tendency of economists to study the
`effects of unions' rather than the `effects of industrial
relations' is encouraged. There is ample evidence that management,
under pressure to raise efficiency, has reshaped pay structures and
greatly increased control over the internal organisation of the firm.
Sometimes this has been done by marginalising trade unions. But in other
cases, such as the steel and car industries, remarkable improvements in
productivity have been achieved by employers working with unions,
linking the interests of unions' workplace organisations to the
interests of the enterprise.
In sum, the legislation appears to have contributed substantially
to economic performance only in the few, highly publicised cases in
which extensive pre-entry closed shops and associated union controls
were removed after intense conflict. Elsewhere, the key factors have
been heightened product market competition and more coherent management
strategy, which have radically reshaped British industrial relations and
removed many of the constraints on economic performance with which it
was previously associated.
10. Conclusions
Since about 1980 there have been fundamental changes in the way
labour is managed throughout the industrialised world. Collective
bargaining and trade union membership have retreated under the combined
pressures of intensified competition in product markets and sustained
high unemployment. The British experience of these changes coincided
with the adoption by successive Conservative governments of a policy of
hostility towards collective bargaining. In many ways this represented a
reversion from collective to individual laissez faire, although the
Conservative laws went further in applying a deregulatory competition
policy to the labour market. In this review we have attempted to
identify how far these legal interventions had an effect upon the
industrial relations system over and above the changes which would have
been expected to follow from the wider transformation of the economic
environment.
For trade unions, the legislation has undoubtedly produced new
financial and procedural burdens, and obstacles to the recruitment and
retention of members. It also provided employers with powerful new
sanctions at both the collective and individual levels, and in this way
helped to shift power further away from organised labour. It is,
however, doubtful whether even these sanctions could have been deployed
so effectively under different economic conditions. The apparent success
of the Conservative laws cannot be seen in isolation from the rise in
unemployment and from wider changes to the structure of labour and
product markets which occurred during this period.
So far as the wider economic effects of the legislation have been
concerned, the difficulty has been one of disentangling any distinctive
consequences in circumstances where employers already had powerful
competitive reasons to reduce the scope of collective bargaining. The
impact of the legal change has certainly been very uneven across
industries, with most effect in those industries which were both
confronted by an unprecedented competitive shock and where uncompetitive
employment practices had been allowed to build up in the past. But while
a legislative attack on collective bargaining may have served its
purpose in these cases, in many others competitive shocks were met
equally effectively by maintaining collective bargaining, albeit in
somewhat different forms from before. In judging between these
strategies in the longer term, a crucial question is whether productive
efficiency can be maintained without employees having some expression of
collective voice on such matters as health and safety, training, and
employment flexibility.
From a comparative perspective, the Conservative years mark a less
dramatic point of departure than it seemed at the time. The declines in
union density and in the incidence of industrial action were broadly in
line with the experience of other countries. Moreover, certain
distinctive features of the British system--most notably the weakness of
centralised bargaining mechanisms and the absence of a comprehensive
statutory floor of rights--were reinforced by the policies of the 1980s
and 1990s. The new laws also confirmed an underlying assumption of
adversarialism and separation of interests in British labour-management
relations. New forms of co-operation in the workplace emerged, but this
was not because the old assumptions of adversarialism were rejected. If
anything, they were strengthened by the draconian new legal sanctions
made available to employers and the courts. Rather, it was because
unions were weakened by high unemployment and falling membership. The
true test of the new laws will only come at a point if, under changed
economic circumstances, there is some revival in the bargaining power of
organised labour.
During the period of Conservative government in Britain, a quite
different route for industrial relations law, involving
institutionalised support for labour-management co-operation, was being
mapped out within the systems of mainland Europe and by the emerging
body of EC labour law. A central issue now is whether Britain will
continue to drift towards a system of individualised employment
relations within a largely union-free environment, as in the United
States, or will join the European mainstream in acknowledging a role for
collective employee representation and statutory support for minimum
employment standards. The arrival of a Labour government committed to
the Social Chapter may provide the answer.
References
Addison J.T. and W.S. Siebert (1997), `Union security in
Britain', forthcoming in Journal of Labour Research.
Beaumont, P.B. and R.I.D. Harris (1995), `Union de-recognition and
declining union density in Britain', Industrial and Labour
Relations Review, vol. 48, no. 3.
Blanchflower, D. (1991), `Fear, unemployment and pay
flexibility', Economic Journal, no. 101.
Blanchflower, D. and R.E Freeman (1994), `Did the Thatcher revolution
change the British labour market? in R. Barrell (ed.), The United
Kingdom Labour Market, Cambridge University Press.
Blanchflower, D. (1996), `The role and influence of trade unions in
the OECD', Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper no.
310.
Brown D., P. Ingrain and J. Wadsworth (1997), `Free to choose'.
Centre Piece, vol. 2, no. 1.
Brown, W.A. and S. Wadhwani (1990), `The economic effects of
industrial relations legislation since 1979', National Institute
Economic Review, no. 131.
Brown, W.A. and J. Walsh, `Corporate pay policies and the
internationalisation of markets', in J. Niland, R. Lansbury and C.
Verevis (eds), The Future of Industrial Relations, Thousand Oaks: Sage.
Brown, W.A., P. Marginson and J. Walsh (1995), `Management: pay
determination and collective bargaining' in P. K. Edwards (ed.),
Industrial Relations: Theory and Practice in Britain, Blackwell.
Bullock Committee of Inquiry (1977), Report on Industrial Democracy,
Cmnd.6706, HMSO.
Claydon, T. (1996), Union derecognition: a re-examination, in I.
Beardwell (ed.), Contemporary Industrial Relations, Oxford University
Press.
Commissioner for the Rights of Trade Union Members and Commissioner
for Protection Against Unlawful Industrial Action (1996), Annual Reports
1995-96, Commissioners' Office.
Crafts, N. (1997), Britain's Relative Economic Decline,
1870-1995, London, Social Market Foundation. Cully, M. and S. Woodland
(1997), `Trade union membership and recognition: an analysis of data
from the 1996 Labour Force Survey', Labour Market Trends, June.
Daniel, W.W. (1987), Workplace Industrial Relations and Technical
Change, Pinter. Dawson, S., P. Willman, M. Bamford and A. Clinton
(1988), Safety at Work: the Limits of Self-Regulation, Cambridge
University Press.
Deakin, S. (1991), `Legal change and labour market restructuring in
Western Europe and the US', New Zealand Journal of Industrial
Relations, no. 16.
Deakin, S. (1997), `Integration through law?', in J.T. Addison
and W.S. Siebert (eds.), Labour Markets in Europe. Dryden.
Deakin, S. and G. Morris (1995), Labour Law, Butterworths.
Denny, K. and S. Nickell (1992), `Unions and investment in British
industry', Economic Journal, no. 102.
Disney, R., A. Gosling and S. Machin (1996), `What has happened to
union recognition in Britain?', Economica, no. 63.
Donovan (1968), Royal Commission on Trade Unions and Employers'
Associations, Report, Cmnd 3623, HMSO.
Dunn, S. and D. Metcalf (1996), Trade union law since 1979, in
Beardwell, op cit.
Ebbinghaus B. and J. Visser (forthcoming), The Development of Trade
Unions in Western Europe, 1945-95, Campus.
Elgar, J. and R. Simpson (1993), The impact of the law on industrial
disputes in the 1980s', in D. Metcalf and S. Milner,(eds), New
Perspectives on Industrial Disputes, Routledge.
Elgar, J. and R. Simpson (1996), Industrial Action Ballots and the
Law, IER.
Elias, P. (1994), `Job-related training, trade union membership and
labour mobility, Oxford Economic Papers, vol. 46, no. 4.
Ewing, K. and B. Napier (1986), `The Wapping dispute and labour
law', Cambridge Law Journal, no. 45.
European Works Councils Bulletin, various.
Ferner, A. and R. Hyman (forthcoming), Industrial Relations in the
New Europe, second edition, Blackwell.
Freeman, R.B. and J. Pelletier (1990), `The impact of industrial
relations legislation on British union density, British Journal of
Industrial Relations, vol. 28, no. 2.
Freeman, R.B. and L.E Katz (1995), Differences and Changes in Wage
Structures, University of Chicago Press.
Gall, G. and S. McKay (1996), `Injunctions as a legal weapon in
industrial disputes', British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol.
34, no. 4.
Geroski, P., P. Gregg and T. Desjonqueres (1995), `Did the retreat of
UK trade unionism accelerate during the 1990-1993 recession?',
British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 33, no. 1.
Gosling, A. and S. Machin (1995), Trade unions and the dispersion of
earnings in British establishments, 1980-90', Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, vol. 57, no. 2.
Green, E (1993), `The impact of trade union membership on training in
Britain', Applied Economics, no. 25.
Gregg, P. and S. Machin (1991), `Changes in union status, increased
competition and wage growth in the 1980s', British Journal of
Industrial Relations, vol. 29, no. 4.
Gregg, P. and S. Machin (1992), `Unions, the demise of the closed
shop and wage growth in the 1980s', Oxford Bulletin of Economics
and Statistics, vol. 54, no. 1.
Gregg, P., S. Machin and D. Metcalf (1993), `Signals and cycles:
productivity growth and changes in union status in British
companies', Economic Journal, no. 103.
Gregory, M. and V. Sandoval (1994), `Low pay and minimum wage
protection in Britain and the EC', in Barrell (ed.) op cit. Guest
D. and K. Hoque (1996), Human resource management and the new industrial
relations', in Beardwell op cit.
Hayek, E (1973), Rules and Order, Routledge.
Heery E. (1996), `The new new unionism' in Beardwell, op cit.
Henry, B. and K. Lee (1997), `Unemployment, wage dispersion and
labour market flexibility', in J. Michie and J. Grieve-Smith (eds),
Employment and Economic Performance, Oxford University Press.
Ingrain, P. (1991), `Ten years of manufacturing wage settlements:
1979-89', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 7, no. 1.
Kahn-Freund, O. (1959), `Labour law', in M. Ginsberg (ed.), Law
and Public Opinion in Britain in the Twentieth Century, Stevens.
Layard, R., S. Nickell and R. Jackman (1991), Unemployment:
Macroeconomic Performance and Labour Markets, Oxford University Press.
Leopold, J.W. (1997), `Trade unions, political fund ballots and the
Labour Party', British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 35,
no. 1.
Machin, S. and A. Manning (1993), `The effects of minimum wages on
wage dispersion: evidence from UK Wages Councils', Industrial and
Labour Relations Review, vol. 47, no. 2.
Machin, S. (1995), `Plant closures and unionisation in British
establishments', British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 33,
no. 1.
Machin, S. and S. Wadhwani (1991) `The effects of unions on
investment and innovation', Economic Journal, no. 101. Main, B.
(1996), `The union relative wage gap', in D. Gallie, R. Penn and M.
Rose (eds), Trade Unionism in Recession, Oxford University Press.
Marginson, P., P. Armstrong, P. Edwards and J. Purcell (1996),
`Facing the multinational challenge', in P. Leisink, J. Van
Leemput, and J. Vilrokx (eds), The Challenges to Trade Unions in Europe,
Elgar.
Marsden, D. and M. Thompson (1990), `Flexibility agreements and their
significance in the increase in productivity in British manufacturing
since 1980', Work, Employment and Society,, vol. 4, no. 1.
Metcalf, D. (1993), `Industrial relations and economic performance,
British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 31, no. 2.
Metcalf, D. and M. Stewart (1992), `Closed shops and relative
pay', Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, vol. 54, no. 4.
Millward, N., M. Stevens, D. Smart and W.R. Hawes (1992), Workplace
Industrial Relations in Transition, Dartmouth.
Millward, N. (1994), The New Industrial Relations?, Policy Studies
Institute.
Milner, S. (1995), `The coverage of collective pay-setting
institutions in Britain, 1895-1990', British Journal of Industrial
Relations, vol. 33, no. 1.
Nickell, S. and B. Bell (1996), `Changes in the distribution of wages
and unemployment in OECD countries', American Economic Review, no.
86.
Nickell, S., S. Wadhwani and M. Wall (1992), `Productivity growth in
UK companies, 1975-86', European Economic Review, no. 36.
Nolan, P. (1996), `Industrial relations and performance since
1945', in Beardwell, op cit OECD (1989), Employment Outlook, OECD.
OECD (1994), Employment Outlook, OECD.
OECD (1996), Employment Outlook, OECD.
Oulton, N. (1990), `Labour productivity in UK manufacturing in the
1970s and in the 1980s', National Institute Economic Review, no.
132.
Ryan, P. (1996), `Factor shares and inequality in the UK',
Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 12, no. 1.
Sandy, R. and R.E Elliott (1996), `Unions and risk', Economica,
no. 63.
Schmitt, J. (1996), `The changing structure of male earnings in
Britain, 1,974-88, in Freeman and Katz (eds) op cit.
Steedman, H. and K. Wagner (1989), Productivity, machinery and
skills, National Institute Economic Review, no. 128.
Stevens, M. (1996), `Transferable training and poaching externalities' in A. Booth and D. Snower (eds), Acquiring Skills,
Cambridge University Press.
Stewart, M.B. (1987), `Collective bargaining arrangements, closed
shops and relative pay', Economic Journal, no. 97.
Stewart, M.B. (1990), `Union wage differentials, product markets and
the division of rents', Economic Journal, no. 100.
Stewart, M.B. (1991), `Union wage differentials in the face of
changes in the economic and legal environment', Economica, no. 58.
Stewart, M.B. (1995), `Union wage differentials in an era of
declining unionisation', Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, vol. 57, no. 2.
Undy R., P. Fosh, H. Morris, P. Smith, and R. Martin (1996), Managing
the Unions, Clarendon.
Wadhwani, S. (1990), `The effects of unions on productivity, growth,
investment and employment', British Journal of Industrial
Relations, vol. 28, no. 3.
Willman, P., T. Morris and B. Aston (1993), Union Business, Cambridge
University Press.
Willman, P. and T. Morris (1995), `Financial management and financial
performance in British trade unions', British Journal of Industrial
Relations, vol. 33, no. 2.
Wright, M. (1996), `The collapse of compulsory unionism?',
British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 34, no. 4.
William Brown, Simon Deakin and Paul Ryan, Correspondence should be
addressed to the authors at the Faculty of Economics and Politics,
University of Cambridge, Austin Robinson Building, Sidgwick Avenue,
Cambridge, CB3 9DD. The authors wish to thank Maria Hudson and Cliff
Pratten, with whom they are currently engaged in fieldwork on the
individualisation of employment contracts. Thanks also to members of the
CLARE Group for helpful comments, and to Greg Bamber, Bill Callaghan,
Bernard Ebbinghaus, Anthony Ferner, Simon Goldstone, Mark Hall, Bob
Hepple, Richard Hyman, Bente Ingebrigtsen, Steve Jefferys, Ian McAndrew,
Paul Marginson, John Monks, Graham Osborne, Jim Scoville, Priya Sharma,
Steen Sheuer, Tony Smith, Bob Simpson, Mike Terry, and Paul Willman for
miscellaneous help.