Output gaps. Some evidence from the UK, France and Germany.
Barrell, Ray ; Sefton, James
As the UK economy recovers from the recent recession, there is again
widespread concern at the re-emergence of the spectre of inflation.
Recent increases in base rates were primarily aimed at reassuring
markets that inflation will be controlled. It is therefore of use to be
able to calculate whether or not inflationary pressures are liable to
re-emerge in the near future. Our macroeconomic, model based, forecast
on page 8 of this Review is one way that this could be done. This note
investigates a number of other approaches.
The output gap is one of the principal indicators of inflationary
pressures used in the current debate. The gap measures the amount of
production over and above that which could be expected if the economy
were operating at its sustainable level. When we experience above
potential output we would anticipate that prices would rise until
aggregate demand was reduced sufficiently. Many economists therefore
have taken, or are quickly taking, a stand on the size of the output
gap, so much so that Gavyn Davis (The Independent, January 9) compiled a
list of 'gapologists', the leading proponents of this science.
The output gap is also applied in the estimation of cyclically
adjusted budget deficits, and we have utilised them extensively in this
context in Barrell, Morgan, Sefton and in't Veld (1994). In order
to monitor deficits it is necessary to adjust the actual deficit to take
into account the stage of the business cycle. In a recession, government
tax income is always reduced and expenditure always increases because of
items such as unemployment benefits and social security payments. In
calculating the cyclically adjusted budget balance an attempt is made to
estimate the budget deficit that would have prevailed if there was no
output gap. Hence it may be possible to judge changes in the stance of
fiscal policy if we can estimate the size of the output gap.
Given its importance, it is unfortunate that the output gap cannot be
measured directly. A variety of techniques for estimating it are in
common use. In this note we attempt to review these methods and comment
on their merits and deficiencies. We review the different methods that
have been in use at different times by the IMF and the OECD. We will
also suggest a different approach which avoids most of the pitfalls of
the earlier methods, but is econometrically more difficult to implement.
Potential output and output gaps
Measuring potential output and output in relation to potential are
important in our analysis of the macroeconomic environment. When the gap
is zero there is neither excess demand nor excess supply, then the
economy can be seen as in equilibrium at its supply determined
potential. The equilibrium levels of unemployment and output are
obviously inextricably linked, as disequilibrium pressure in the labour
market will spill over into the market for output, and vice versa. Most
current theories of the labour market define the equilibrium, or
sustainable, level of unemployment as that which is consistent with
stable wage inflation. In this situation we would expect the expected
wage to equal the actual wage, and hence there should be no pressure for
it to depart from its expected trajectory.
The growth of potential output has often been seen as a constant,
driven by technology and labour force growth. Maddison (1982) estimated
the growth in output for most of the OECD countries over the last 150
years and his work supported this empirical observation. Events in the
1970s persuaded most economists that the growth in potential output
should be seen as a stochastic or random process around this historical
average. Shocks to the economy come in various forms, and some may
affect the supply potential of the economy, while others may cause the
economy to cycle around potential. It is reasonably clear that the 1974
oil price shock lowered potential output permanently in the OECD area,
but it may not have lowered the subsequent potential or average growth
rate. If this is the case then we should model it as a step decrease in
the level of potential output. However, the economy takes time to adjust
to such a supply-side shock, but when measuring potential output we are
interested in the long run or permanent effects of such a shock. Any
trend extraction technique we use should be able to deal with such
changes in the trend output level, Chart 1 illustrates the problem they
face. If we place a linear trend through the data it would suggest an
estimate of around 1.4 per cent for the growth in potential output in
the UK over the 1970s. This is well below the historical average of 2
per cent. This can be contrasted to the alternative estimate of a linear
trend with growth rate of 2 per cent plus a jump in 1974, caused by
adjustment to the oil price shock. Similarly the 1980s could be modelled
as a linear trend of 2 per cent plus some positive supply shocks due
perhaps to the fall in oil prices in 1985/86 and to labour market
restructuring.
The identification of potential output allows us to separate the
causes of fluctuations in output into those coming from the supply-side,
causing equilibrium output to change, and those coming from variations
in demand. Most Keynesian economists have associated output fluctuations
with changes in demand, but this view was challenged in the late-1970s
and the 1980s by the development of theories of Real Business Cycles. At
first these analyses seemed to suggest that all the observed variation
in output could be put down to supply shocks and their consequences,
with output closely following potential. However, as McCallum (1990)
suggests, these models should now be seen as a reminder that a
'portion of the output and employment variability that is observed
in actual economies is probably not generated by erratic monetary and
fiscal policy makers'. It is now generally considered that we can
make a distinction between supply shocks that permanently change the
level, but not the growth rate, of potential output, and demand shocks
that only have a temporary effect on the level of output. The existence
of these two types of shocks, and their implications for the measurement
of potential output, are discussed in Blanchard and Quah (1989). The
prevailing consensus is that any approach to estimating potential output
must first decompose fluctuations into those due to supply-side and
those due to demand-side shocks. Blanchard and Fisher (1989) stress that
the co-movement of economic time series can contain valuable information
on this decomposition. For example, a demand-side shock to output would
be reflected in or correlated with changes in consumption, whereas a
supply-side shock would be expected to cause a change to the level of
investment, and hence output. Methods for estimating gaps can be
designed which utilise this information.
Given the theoretical importance of the output gap, it is unfortunate
that its measurement is so problematic. This will always be the case
however when we are trying to separate out 'high frequency'
events such as the business cycle from 'low frequency' events
or persistent phenomena such as the trend in potential output. As Watson
(1986) points out, a time series of 30 years could contain a significant
number of examples of cycles of periods of less than 5 years, yet only a
few examples of cycles of 10 years or more. Therefore we have more
information in a finite sample on the shorter cycles, and
correspondingly less information on longer cycles and the permanent
shocks (which can be regarded as infinitely long cycles). Techniques for
trend extraction have to address this problem directly, and filters for
trend extraction are designed to remove specific frequencies and, in
particular, cycles from the data under consideration.
This note examines a number of ways of extracting trends, and uses
them to produce output gaps for the UK, France and Germany. We look at
the broken deterministic trend approach developed by the NBER, and used
until recently by the OECD, as well as at the simple symmetric filter
advocated by Hodrick and Prescott (1980). Both these methods use only
information contained in the output series and assume that the average
growth rate of potential GDP varies over time. We suggest estimating
trend output using a VAR based multivariate filter which utilises and
extends the techniques suggested by Beveridge and Nelson (1981). This
method models the co-movement between the selected time series to help
differentiate between demand and supply-side shocks, and then extracts
the long-run component of the supply-side shocks. It implicitly assumes
that the average long-run growth of GDP remains constant over time. We
also look at the commonly used, and economically justifiable,
application of the aggregate production function to the calculation of
potential output. This approach is now in use by both the OECD and the
IMF.
Methods For estimating output gaps
We wish to investigate methods that allow us to extract from output
those events that had a persistent but ultimately transitory effect on
the equilibrium level of output. The 1970s, for instance, may have seen
rather low growth of potential, in part because of worsening labour
market conditions in a number of countries, while the 1980s may have
produced higher potential growth, in part because of high levels of
investment. We would want all our trend extraction methods to take
account of local variations in trend growth, at least in as far as they
are relevant for policy purposes. Each method implicitly contains a
model of potential output growth and we will discuss them. Output gap
estimates are frequently used in the policy debate, and we consider it a
failing that some estimates suffer from an end of sample bias. A method
might produce very plausible and robust estimates of the output gap in
the middle of the data period, but might also be particularly sensitive
to small changes in the implementation of the method at the end of the
sample, and we will point out where this is the case.
The NBER benchmark method
The traditional analysis of Burns and Mitchell (1946) has been widely
applied, for instance by Friedman and Schwartz (1963), and it was used
for some time by the OECD, whose method is set out in Chouraqui et al.
(1990). The method requires that the observer can identify the timing of
peaks (or troughs) in the economic cycle. Once this is done it is
relatively easy to estimate the trend. For instance the OECD benchmark
scenario was based on a measure of mid-cycle trend output. Estimation of
trend growth is based on a simple semi-log model:
ln(y) = [a.sub.0] + [summation over i] [a.sub.i] T[D.sub.i] + e (1)
where ln(y) is the natural logarithm of real GDP, [a.sub.i] the ith
trend growth coefficient and T[D.sub.i] the ith segment of the broken
time trend, while T is a time trend and [D.sub.i] takes the value one in
the ith segment but is zero elsewhere. Business cycles are assumed to
start on the first year following a peak, when the growth rate displays
a local maximum, and to end in the year of the next observed peak.
Equation (1) also contains a constant term because it is necessary to
estimate the initial level of the trend at the start of the sample. This
technique has the advantage that it is simple and mechanical, but it
does depend on a rather arbitrary or subjective choice of the timing of
the cycle, and it appears that in many applications a large amount of
judgement has been used.
The log linear trend approach is based on rather strong assumptions,
and in particular it assumes that trend output growth is constant
between structural break points, but can vary radically between cycles.
Actual output cycles around this trend because demand shocks push the
economy away from equilibrium. At the peak the supply determined trend
suddenly breaks, giving a new underlying growth rate for the economy.
However despite the improbability of this scenario, Campbell and Mankiw
(1987) do demonstrate that this specification can have as much
explanatory power as a more believable stochastic model. The approach
also has the advantage that it allows the user to specify the points at
which supply shocks change the level of potential output.
There are two problems with the practical implementation of this
approach, especially if we are interested in evaluating the current
situation. Unfortunately if a break point is placed near the end of the
sample, then there is little data to estimate the trend growth
coefficient over the last period. This is a particularly serious problem
at the present conjuncture as most economies in Europe are just
recovering from a recession. If a structural break was placed at the
previous peak, around 1987 for most of these economies, this model would
predict almost negative growth in potential output over the period since
1987. There are two possible solutions to this end point problem,
neither of them particularly satisfactory. We could use our
macro-forecast of output over the future in order to locate the next
cyclical peak, or we could avoid the problem and not place a break point
near the end of the sample. In the former case our estimate of the
current level of potential output would be very heavily influenced by
our forecast for potential output, while in the latter case we could be
ignoring useful information on the evolution of output. It is also
necessary to estimate the initial level of trend output, [a.sub.0]. This
will cause similar problems at the beginning of the period but of course
this is less critical in the analysis of current policy problems.
Hodrick-Prescott filter
The Hodrick-Prescott filter has been commonly used, in part because
it is easy to apply. The trend is defined as the time series which
minimises the size of the output fluctuations centred on it, subject to
a constraint limiting the maximum allowable change in the growth rate of
trend output. If the maximum allowable change in the rate of growth is
zero, then the trend must be a straight line. As the maximum allowable
change increases so the trend line is allowed to bend to achieve a
better fit. The trend is defined as the solution to the problem,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Epsilon] is an arbitrarily chosen small number.
As King and Rebelo (1989) and Harvey and Jaegar (1993) demonstrate,
the solution to this problem is equivalent to applying a linear filter
to the original GDP time series. The choice of the parameter [Epsilon]
should depend on one's views on the variance of trend relative to
that of output, and hence it should be varied from application to
application. However this is seldom done, and the most commonly used
values in the application of the Hodrick-Prescott filter tend to
completely remove all stochastic or deterministic cycles shorter than
three years, and pass through to the trend all cycles longer than 20
years. In between the filter only reduces the magnitude of the observed
cycle in proportion to the cycle length. Over the 1980s the major cycle
in GDP lasted for around 8-10 years for most major economies, which was
rather longer than the average of the post-war period. As a result the
standard application of the Hodrick-Prescott filter would interpret this
movement in GDP as a change in potential output and not a business
cycle. Although this might be a correct deduction, it is simply the
result of an arbitrary choice for [Epsilon] and is not based on
statistical or economic inference. The filter also has the property that
it can induce fake cycles into the data by taking a moving average of a
random process. This so-called 'Yule-Slutsky' effect is
difficult to avoid if the output series is very noisy.
The Hodrick-Prescott filter has a major flaw when used for the
analysis of current economic events. At the end of the sample, the
optimal trend will always follow the actual series more closely than
elsewhere. At the end of the sample there is only a small reduction in
the sum of squares from following the actual series into a supposed
trough. There is no requirement for the trend to then change direction
suddenly into the next peak outside the sample. By contrast, in mid
sample, if the trend followed the cycle into a trough, there would be a
large cost to closely following the series into the next peak as this
would require a considerable change in direction. The optimal path in
this case would lie along an average line somewhere between the peak and
trough. This feature also makes it difficult to pick up sudden changes
in the level of potential output, and supply-side driven shifts in
potential output are smoothed out over a number of years either side of
the shock that causes them. Unfortunately there is very little one can
do to minimise these failings. In order to avoid end point biases one
could use forecasts so that the trend distortion takes place beyond the
period of interest and therefore is no longer at the end of the sample.
However, the consequent estimate of the gap is very dependent on the
subjective forecast.
Potential output and the production function
Potential output is defined to be level of output that would have
prevailed if the economy had been experiencing equilibrium employment
with normal utilisation of capacity. In this situation we would observe
equilibrium in the goods and labour markets. The equilibrium level of
employment is often defined as equal to measured supply of labour minus
the non accelerating wage inflation rate of unemployment (NAWRU), the
maximum sustainable level of employment that is consistent with stable
wage inflation. It is therefore necessary to estimate the underlying
aggregate production function and the equilibrium level of employment in
order to estimate potential output directly. This method is currently in
use by both the IMF (1993) and the OECD (1994). They both assume a two
factor input Cobb-Douglas production function,
Y = A(t)[K.sup.a][L.sup.(l - a)], (4)
where Y is output, K is capital in use, L is labour in use, and A(t)
is an exogenous times series describing the rate of technical progress.
By taking logs, this can also be written as
log Y = log A + a log K + (l - a) log L (4[prime])
Potential output is then calculated as the level of output that is
consistent with normal capacity utilisation and an estimate of the
NAWRU. Potential output can be written as
log [Y.sup.*] = [Alpha] + gt + alog[K.sup.*] + (l - a)log[L.sup.*]
where [K.sup.*] = [K.sub.*]CU, where CU is capacity utilisation, and
[L.sup.*] is sustainable employment.
These estimates of trend output have an advantage over those based on
trends and filters because they depend on a more theoretical model with
less immediate reliance on econometric techniques. If the capital stock
is known, and the labour market equilibrium can be calculated, then the
levels of factor inputs available in equilibrium (or on trend) can be
input into the production function to enable the calculation of trend
output. A production function can allow for (a considerable degree of)
factor substitution, and a change in relative factor prices could affect
the estimate of trend output.
The application of this technique by the IMF and the OECD is somewhat
more problematic than it might at first appear. The use of a
Cobb-Douglas production function, with the labour shares based on the
national accounts, fixes the substitution elasticity. Within this rather
restricted framework there are still serious measurement problems. Even
if it is possible to make an adequate measure of the capital stock.
(i.e. one that covaries strongly with the actual stock with no trend in
the measurement error), changes in management techniques may alter the
feasible level of utilisation.
More problems are encountered in measuring the rate of technical
progress A(t). The method most commonly used, for instance by the IMF
and the OECD, is to assume that log A(t) is the residual from equation
(4[prime]). This estimate is very noisy and therefore needs to be
smoothed. The IMF use a split-trend method to fit this series, while the
OECD chose to smooth A(t) using a Hodrick-Prescott filter.
More severe problems are encountered in the estimation of the level
of sustainable employment, in part because the evaluation of labour
market equilibrium is problematic. Minford and Riley (1994) argue that
in the UK sustainable unemployment (i.e. the NAWRU) is now around 2 1/2
per cent, or well under a million. In the same volume Barrell, Pain and
Young (1994) calculate that the NAWRU in the UK varied over the 1980s
but by the early-1990s it was no lower than 7-8 per cent. If labour has
a 66 per cent share in output, then this difference alone would cause
the implied output gap estimates to differ by 3 to 4 per cent of GDP. In
Giorno et al. (1995) the OECD produces a similar estimate of the NAWRU
than Barrell, Pain and Young (1994) by first adjusting the actual level
of unemployment by the degree of wage inflation before detrending using
the Hodrick-Prescott filter. Once again this estimate will affect the
evaluation of potential output.
Large-scale macro-models that incorporate estimated production
functions can also be used to evaluate potential, much as they can be
useful in understanding the current conjuncture. They often have
production functions for individual sectors, and hence they could be
preferable to estimating a single aggregate production function. They
also often include a fully coherent model of the labour market, and the
NAWRU for each sector is embedded and easily calculated. It is then only
necessary to calculate the average level of capacity utilisation in each
sector before the potential output of each sector can be aggregated to
an estimate of total potential output. Setting up such a model is a huge
task but, given that large-scale macro models exist in nearly all the
developed economies, it does provide a theoretically coherent and
practical way of estimating potential output. However, applications are
rare, although the approach currently used by the OECD can be described
in this way.
A new approach: Beveridge-Nelson trend cycle decomposition
Most methods for trend extraction in current use have statistical
failings, the most important being the end of sample bias. It is also
possible to introduce more ancillary information in order shed some
light on the evolution of trends. We would advocate an approach that
should recognise the stochastic nature of the business cycle, and be
able to distinguish between shocks that permanently affect the level of
output and those shocks which only have a transitory effect on the level
of output. In order to be able to determine the long-run effects of any
shock, we should be able to use the information contained in the
co-movements of a number of economic time series such as capacity
utilisation, sales or employment. If, for instance, a change in output
is correlated with a change in employment, then this would suggest a
supply-side shock, whereas if it is correlated with consumption then it
is more likely to suggest a demand-side shock.
Blanchard and Quah (1989) and King, Plosser, Stock and Watson (1991)
suggested estimating a Vector Autoregression (VAR) model subject to some
long-run restrictions. These restrictions impose the condition that only
supply-side shocks can have a permanent effect on output in the long
run. Changes in output could then be decomposed into the changes due to
the supply-side shock and changes due to the demand-side shock. The gain
from imposing this property and including more a priori knowledge of the
economy within the model could outweigh the loss of flexibility,
especially when we are using very limited data sets. As King et al.
note, this decomposition allows one to estimate changes to potential
output as the long-run effects of the supply-side shock. A refinement
was made to this technique by Evans and Reichlin (1994). They suggested
using a multivariate generalisation of the Beveridge and Nelson (1981)
decomposition, and we describe this technique in our Annex. Instead of
effectively imposing the decomposition into supply-side and demand-side
shocks, they proposed estimating the long-run relations that describe
the evolution of potential output. This can be done by estimating the
cointegrating vectors contained in the VAR. However, if the data sample
is short it is sometimes difficult to find estimates of these long-run
relations that are robust to minor specification changes. Despite this
problem, this method has the major advantage that it does not require
the estimation of any initial conditions and therefore there are no end
of sample biases.
The technique is not a simple mechanical one, unlike the
Hodrick-Prescott filter. It requires considerable econometric expertise
to first estimate the long-run relationships by cointegration
techniques. Care is also required in estimation of the short-run dynamic
model to ensure that this model is correctly specified. The choice of
the set of variables to include in the VAR is an important step in the
decomposition. Some of the variables that are included should share a
common trend with income, but have different amplitudes in the cycle. In
general we attempted to choose conditioning variables so that we might
have a 'production' cointegrating vector with output and
employment, and a 'demand' cointegrating vector with
consumption and investment. Output and consumption, for instance, share
a common trend, but output tends to have greater cyclical variation.
Other variables should have a common trend with output but be good
forward indicators. If output is expected to rise (and expectations are
on average correct) then investment will be a useful forward looking
common trending variable because we can expect investment now to respond
to expected future output. It is also useful to include some
non-trending (integrated of order zero) series in the set of
conditioning variables. Some such conditioning variable may contain
forward looking information, while others may give a good indication of
the potential speed of acceleration of output. Capacity utilisation and
confidence measures could be included in the former set, while (the
change in) unemployment may be a good indicator for the rate of change
in output.
Estimates of output gaps
In this section we will compare the output gaps that result from the
different methods outlined above. We will also compare our estimates to
those of the IMF and the OECD. Table 1 presents estimates from the IMF
World Economic Outlook, October 1994, and compares them to estimates
produced by the OECD in Giorno et al. (1995). In general these
organisations believed output gaps in 1993 were large, at least in the
UK and France. If we took account of new data available since the
calculation of these figures they would indicate that the output gap in
the UK was around 3 per cent at the end of 1994, suggesting that it
would be some time before inflationary pressures might emerge. Our own
calculations suggest that the output gap in the UK may be considerably
lower than this. Table 1 also includes our own estimates of gaps using
four methods and more recent data on 1994 than was available to the OECD
or the IMF.
Our output gaps for the UK are plotted in Chart 2. All four methods
that we employ suggest that the gap had shrunk to less than 2 per cent,
and it could be around zero in 1994. The production function based
indicator embodies an estimate of sustainable unemployment, and Barrell,
Pain and Young (1994) suggest that sustainable unemployment is around 8
per cent, and this is likely to [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 1 OMITTED] be
reached some time in 1995. Charts 3 and 4 plot output gaps for France
and Germany. Our output gaps in the early 1990s suggest that the
recession in France was mild and that only around 1 or 2 per cent of
spare capacity exists. The production function based approach is
particularly problematic for France, as inertia in the labour market is
very severe, and it is possible that unemployment could have been above
the NAWRU for most of the 1980s (see Barrell, Pain and Young (1994) for
a discussion of France). Three of our four methods of trend extraction
suggest that there is little spare capacity in (west) Germany, but a
production function based approach indicates that it may be
considerable. This may reflect the historically high level of
unemployment that has been caused by migration into west Germany, a
factor that is not picked up by our other filters. Migration may well
have changed past relations, and in the future output may grow more
rapidly than it has done in he past. Only a production function based
approach (or a model based forecast) can pick up recent structural
changes of this sort.
Our trend estimation also provides some indications or estimates of
the rate of growth of potential output. We have found that all our
filters produce an estimate for the UK in the range 2-2.1 per cent
growth a year, although temporary factors may raise this. Our estimates
for France, at 2.5-2.6 per cent, and for Germany, at 2.3-2.6, are
slightly higher, with the larger estimate for Germany coming from the
production function. Our calculations for the HP and production function
approaches are based on developments over the last five years. These
estimates should, of course be treated with caution, and in particular
they depend upon the assumption that the trend rate of growth of the
labour force will be unchanged. This may be questionable for several
reasons. Our forecast for Germany suggests that migration will continue
to raise the rate of growth of the workforce above its average in the
1980s, and that this will raise sustainable growth by at least a quarter
of a per cent. Our forecasts for the UK and France in this Review are
predicated on a belief that government policies to reduce equilibrium
unemployment will be effective, albeit slow acting, and we assume that
this will add a quarter to a half a per cent to sustainable growth over
the next decade.
Conclusions
Extracting evidence on trend output is difficult, and estimates
should always be treated as uncertain. Indeed, it is clear that an
element of judgement must always enter the calculation of the output
gap. However, our estimates suggest that gaps are not particularly large
in Europe at present, and hence that caution should be observed in the
setting of policy. This conclusion supports that in the forecast section
in the Review that was published in May 1994, where it was suggested
that capacity utilisation levels indicated an output gap of no more than
3 per cent at that time. Given that growth in 1994 has exceeded most
estimates of potential the gap is likely to have shrunk since then.
ANNEX 1. THE MULTIVARIATE TREND EXTRACTION
Our technique is based on that in Evans and Reichlin (1994).
There are three stages to the construction of the trend estimates:
1. The first stage is to estimate any long-run relationships between
the selected time series, using for instance the Johansen
maximum-likelihood method. This assumes that the times series are all
integrated of order one and can be modelled by a finite order VAR. If
[X.sub.t] is the vector of the times series at time t, then given the
OLS estimates for the following regression,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
the number and direction of the long-run relations can be estimated
from the long-run matrix [A.sub.p]. We would normally expect to find
fewer significant eigenvectors than we have time series in the model.
2. These long-run relationships are then imposed on the structure
described above and then it is possible to reestimate the short-run
relationships conditional on the set of trends. As there are fewer
eigenvectors than there are time series the parameters estimated in the
second stage will differ from those in the first stage.
3. The resulting model can then be simulated to run forward in time.
The further into the future we take the run the more damped become the
dynamic elements, and eventually the cyclical components disappear
leaving only the permanent supply-side effects on trend output. This
procedure has to be repeated for each time period. The trend value is
the estimate of trend output under the assumption that the trend output
growth is a constant plus a linear or stochastic component. Further
details of methods and datasets used are available from the authors.
REFERENCES
Barrell, R., J. Morgan, J. Sefton and J. in't Veld, J. (1994),
'The cyclical adjustment of budget balances', National
Institute of Economic and Social Research, Report Series No. 8.
Barrell, R., N. Pain, and G. Young (1994), 'Structural
differences in European labour markets', in R. Barrell (ed.), The
UK Labour Market: Comparative Aspects and Institutional Developments,
Cambridge University Press.
Beveridge, S. and C. Nelson (1981), 'A new approach to the
decomposition of economic time series, into permanent and transitory
components with particular attention to the business cycle',
Journal of Monetary Economics, 7, pp. 151-174.
Blanchard, O. and S. Fischer (1989), Lectures on Macroeconomics, MIT Press, Cambridge, US.
Blanchard, O. and D. Quah (1989), 'The dynamic effects of
aggregate supply and demand disturbances', American Economic
Review, 79, pp. 655-73.
Burns A. and W. Mitchell (1946), Measuring Business Cycles, New York:
National Bureau of Economic Research.
Campbell, J. and N. Mankiw (1987), 'Are output fluctuations
transitory?', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, pp. 857-880.
Chouraqui, J.C., R.P. Hagermann and N. Sartor (1990),
'Indicators of fiscal policy: a re-examination', OECD Working
Paper 70.
Evans, G. and Reichlin, L. (1994), 'Information, forecasts, and
measurement of the business cycle', Journal of Monetary Economics,
April 33(2), pp. 233-54.
Freidman, M. and A. Schwartz (1963), A Monetary History of the United
States, 1867-1960, Princeton University Press.
Giorno, C. P. Richardson, D. Roseveare and P. van den Noord (1995),
'Estimating potential output, output gaps and structural budget
balances', Economics Department Working Paper No. 152, OECD.
Harvey, A.C. and A. Jaeger (1993), 'Detrending, stylised facts
and the business cycle' Journal of Applied Econometrics, 8, pp.
231-47.
Hodrick, R. and E. Prescott (1980), 'Post-war US business
cycles: an empirical investigation', Carnegie-Mellon University,
PA., Working Paper.
International Monetary Fund (1993), World Economic Outlook: October
1993, Washington D.C.
International Monetary Fund (1994), World Economic Outlook: October
1994, Washington D.C.
King, R.G., C.I. Plosser, J. Stock and M. Watson (1991),
'Stochastic trends and economic fluctuations', American
Economic Review, 81, pp. 819-839.
King, R.G. and S. Rebelo (1993), 'Low frequency filtering and
real business cycles', Journal of Economics Dynamics and Control,
17, pp. 207-31.
Maddison, A. (1982), Phases of Capitalist Development, Oxford
University Press.
McCallum, B. (1990), 'Real business cycle models', In R.
Barro (ed.) Modern Business Cycle Theory, Basil Blackwell, 1990.
Minford P., and J. Riley (1994), 'The UK labour market: micro
rigidities and macro obstructions', in Barrell R (ed.), The UK
Labour Market: Comparative Aspects and Institutional Developments,
Cambridge University Press.
OECD (1994), Economic Outlook, OECD, December 1994.
Romer P. (1990), 'Capital accumulation in the theory of long-run
growth', in R. Barro (ed.) Modern Business Cycle Theory, Basil
Blackwell, 1990.
Watson, M.W. (1986), 'Univariate detrending methods with
stochastic trends', Journal of Monetary Economics, 19, pp. 49-75.