Misalignment, debt accumulation and fundamental equilibrium exchange rates.
Artis, Michael J. ; Taylor, Mark P.
Introduction
Our objective in this article is to investigate the effects of
hysteresis - operating through shifting international net asset stocks
during periods of misalignment - on the fundamental equilibrium exchange
rate. Although our discussion relies in large part on analytical
arguments, our aim is to provide practical guidelines which are of use
in assessing situations of exchange-rate misalignment.
The concept of the equilibrium exchange rate is not unique. As noted
by Frenkel and Goldstein (1986), there are at least three approaches to
determining the equilibrium exchange rate - corresponding to structural
exchange rate models such as the monetary model or the portfolio balance
model of exchange rate determination, the purchasing power parity approach, and the 'underlying balance' approach.(1)
In this article, we are concerned with the underlying balance
approach. According to this approach, the equilibrium exchange rate is
defined as the real effective exchange rate that is consistent with
medium-term internal and external macroeconomic balance.
The condition of internal macroeconomic balance can be identified
with equilibrium employment and output, which would be typically taken
to be the non-accelerating inflation rate unemployment level or NAIRU.
External balance can be identified with current account balance or, in
the presence of sustainable medium-term capital inflow or outflow, a
corresponding deficit or surplus. In any case, the current account
should incorporate the flow of debt service payments or receipts (and
other investment income) corresponding to the underlying net foreign
asset position of the economy. These definitions are explored further
below.
The underlying balance approach to the equilibrium exchange rate was
largely developed by staff at the International Monetary Fund during the
early-1970s (see International Monetary Fund (1984)).(2) More recently,
the equilibrium rate associated with underlying balance has been labeled
the 'fundamental equilibrium exchange rate' (FEER) (Williamson
(1985)). The FEER has been used as an analytical device by a number of
authors to assess exchange rate misalignment (Williamson (1985, 1990),
Barrell and Wren-Lewis (1989)), as well as in the context of discussions
of 'blueprints' for international policy coordination
(Williamson and Miller (1987)), Frenkel and Goldstein (1986), Currie and
Wren-Lewis (1989), and in discussions of the 'appropriate
level' at which to join a pegged exchange-rate system such as the
European Monetary System (EMS) (Wren-Lewis, et al. (1991)).
This article addresses an issue concerning FEER computations which,
although it has not been entirely overlooked in the literature, has been
given relatively little attention, namely: how sensitive is the FEER to
the path chosen for convergence towards it? A given FEER trajectory has
associated with it a particular path for the current account and debt
service flows; a deviation of the actual rate from the FEER immediately
implies a different current account and correspondingly a change in debt
service flows compared to the original. The level of the real exchange
rate consistent with medium-term external balance must therefore change.
Thus, the final FEER arrived at will not be independent of the path
chosen towards it.
Where equilibrium values turn out to be dependent on the dynamic path
of adjustment, the situation is generally termed one of
'hysteresis' (Cross (1992)). Contemporary economic analysis is
turning up a number of instances in which it appears that hysteresis
effects may be important; for example, in the determination of the NAIRU
(Lindbeck and Snower (1986)), and in the analysis of trade responses to
exchange-rate variation, taking account of the sunk costs of setting up
in overseas markets (Baldwin and Krugman (1986)). For economists trained
in the neoclassical tradition, hysteresis is a troublesome feature since
its presence renders inapplicable the method of comparative statics upon
which much of modern economic analysis is founded.(3) The implicit use
of something at least approximating the comparative static method is
common in analyses involving the FEER.
In the remainder of this article we evaluate the importance of
hysteresis effects on the FEER as they arise through the debt service
consequences of misalignment.(4) That there are hysteresis effects of
this kind is not in dispute; our aim is to provide a sense of their
empirical significance. In particular, we provide broad rules of thumb
by which to judge the importance of such effects for any given degree of
perceived exchange-rate misalignment and desired period of monotonic adjustment towards the FEER.
We begin by discussing the issue of hysteresis in the FEER in more
detail and by showing analytically that the FEER is not independent of
the path chosen to achieve it. Then we derive our rules of thumb for
assessing the importance of hysteresis effects for a given path of
adjustment and set of initial conditions. In the following section we
take - for purely illustrative purposes - estimates of the FEER for each
of the G5 countries in 1990 provided by Williamson (1990), and analyse the importance of hysteresis effects assuming that the implied degree of
misalignment is reduced to zero over either a five- or a ten-year
period. A final section concludes.
Debt accumulation and misalignment
The FEER is defined as that value of the real exchange rate which
will reconcile internal and external equilibrium 'in the medium
term'. As already explained, external equilibrium is defined in
terms of a desired value of the current account balance; this value may
be non-zero if there is a presumption about a 'normal' rate of
capital inflow or outflow. Otherwise a zero value seems a plausible
objective, corresponding as it does to a constant level of net foreign
assets.(5) Internal balance is usually defined as potential full
employment output; in most computations (e.g., those of Williamson
(1985, 1990)) this appears to be assumed to be independently computed
and to be independent of the real exchange rate itself and we shall
follow that tradition here. This is illustrated in Figure 1, the NAIRU
schedule is drawn as a vertical line in real exchange rate (S) and
capacity utilisation (u) space. In a very open economy, the NAIRU may be
modelled as a function of the real exchange rate. An appreciation of the
real exchange rate allows a higher real wage (markup of wages over
prices) for a given rate of utilisation, since holding the current
account constant in volume terms, the improvement in the terms of trade implies an increase in real revenues which may be passed on to workers.
This view, which is represented analytically in the Layard-Nickell
(1985) 'Battle of the Markups' view of inflation is reflected
in the econometric modelling work of Wren-Lewis et al. (1991). In terms
of the diagram, the NAIRU schedule would be positively sloped from left
to right. The current account (CA) schedule is drawn for a given level
of the current account balance and slopes down from left to right for
well-known (net import propensity) reasons: as utilisation increases,
(net) imports tend to rise, requiring a devaluation of the real exchange
rate as an offset. The solution for [S.sup.*], [u.sup.*] gives the FEER
and the internal balance or utilisation rate.(6)
For given assumed values of the target current account and internal
balance, then, the corresponding 'fundamental equilibrium exchange
rate' (FEER) can be computed. It should be clear that the FEER
needs to be computed as a trajectory if there is evolution in the values
of the current account and internal balance targets, (or predictable
change in the structure of the economy for given values of those
targets), even if we set on one side all issues of hysteresis. (An
example of a step change in an otherwise flat FEER trajectory is
introduced below.)
It is easy to see from considering Figure 1 how hysteresis in the
FEER can arise. Suppose that the actual exchange rate happens to
correspond initially to its FEER value and that internal balance is at
the optimal level - in other words, that there is no problem of the
starting point or transition period. In terms of the figure, we are at
([u.sup.*],[S.sup.*]). Now suppose that in the next period the actual
real exchange rate departs from its FEER value - specifically that it
appreciates - whilst utilisation remains at [u.sup.*]. The appreciation
causes the current account to deteriorate relative to the initial
equilibrium target positions, which is assumed to be zero.(7) Then the
FEER calculation must be performed afresh. The deficit increases net
foreign indebtedness and creates an obligation to service debt interest.
Even disregarding any desire to rectify the increase in indebtedness,
the obligation to service more debt must cause the CA schedule to move
in to the left: the real exchange rate which would have been consistent
with the current account target in the absence of the increased
debt-service will now produce a deficit due to the increased
debt-service obligation. More precisely, the trade account target has
changed to provide a surplus sufficient to cover the increased debt
service obligation. The current account target remains the same since
debt service is incorporated in it, but the 'structure' of the
economy has changed, forcing CA to shift inward.
The departure of the actual exchange rate from its FEER value
(trajectory) thus forces a revision of the FEER. A 'hysteresis
loop' (Cross (1992)) would ensue if the previous FEER were to be
re-established. The exchange rate would need to
'overdepreciate' in order to reinstate the previous schedule
[ILLUSTRATION FOR FIGURE 2 OMITTED]. A displacement of the actual real
rate of exchange from its FEER value - say, to point A - involves a real
appreciation and a current account deficit (relative to the current
account balance underlying CA). This requires a re-evaluation of the CA
schedule, to CA', and a devaluation of the FEER from [S.sup.*] to
[S.sup.*]'. For the FEER to be re-established at [S.sup.*], an
overdepreciation would be needed to reduce the stock of debt to the
original level, resulting in the 'hysteresis loop' shown.(8)
How large a revision of the FEER is required as a result of
misalignment? To derive an answer to this question, imagine again that
starting from a favourable position, (i.e., where the current real
exchange rate is at its FEER value and internal balance is realised),
the current exchange rate departs from its FEER value by, say, x per
cent. For concreteness, suppose this is an appreciation. Then a deficit
in the current account will appear of x([Mu] + [Tau])X where [Mu] and
[Tau] are, respectively, the import and export elasticities and X is the
volume of exports (or imports - we suppose the two to be approximately
initially equal). If this is a one-off deviation of 'one-year'
duration, then the FEER will have to be devalued to the extent necessary
to service the additional debt incurred. It is convenient to assume that
the FEER adjustment depends on the same elasticities,(9) but the
adjustment need only be large enough to service the cost of the debt
incurred; then it is easy to see that, if the interest rate is r, the
adjustment required is [Delta] = rx. (The FEER devaluation, [Delta],
must yield rx([Mu] + [Tau])X to cover the debt service, or [Delta]([Mu]
+ [Tau])X = rx([Mu] + [Tau])X.) If the deviation is sustained for two
'years', the total adjustment required will be twice as large.
Thus, each initial x per cent deviation of the actual from the
fundamental equilibrium exchange rate will require a FEER adjustment of
rx per cent in the opposite direction if FEERs are adjusted
annually.(10)
Notice that this makes no allowance for what might logically be seen
as the need to reverse the increment in debt acquired in this example
through the appreciation of the current exchange rate over its FEER
value. The reason this might seem logical is that the FEER external
balance criterion is typically for a zero net foreign asset accumulation
(or for a particular baseline growth in net foreign assets). Thus, an
event that causes a departure from this initial desired condition should
lead to an action calculated to offset it. In this case every x per cent
appreciation of the actual rate over its FEER value should lead to a
reduction big enough to pay back the debt over a defined period of time.
The size of hysteresis effects will clearly be potentially much larger
if the FEER adjustment is required to be big enough to repay the debt
incurred rather than simply to service the additional interest
obligation. In what follows, however, we calculate FEER adjustments on
the more modest of the two possible criteria, looking therefore for a
FEER adjustment sufficient only to cover the cost of the additional
interest burdens arising from misalignment. This case is clearly the
most conservative one to take and sets a natural 'lower band'
to the size of the hysteresis problem. Had we chosen to assume that debt
repayment objectives were involved, we should also have been obliged to
specify - quite arbitrarily - the speed with which debt repayments were
to occur. We now proceed to derive a formula for the FEER adjustment
process. The result expresses formally the hysteresis effect - the
dependence of the FEER on the path of the actual exchange rate.
Suppose that initially, in year 0, the actual real exchange rate is
at its FEER value, which has a flat (stationary) trajectory at that
point in time. Internal balance is assumed to be maintained at its
optimal level throughout. Then any deviation of the actual rate from the
FEER value implies a deviation from current account balance and requires
a recomputation of the FEER on the lines indicated above.
Approximately, then:
[F.sub.n] = [F.sub.n-1] - r([S.sub.n-1] - [F.sub.n-1]) (1)
or
[F.sub.n] = (1 + r) [F.sub.n-1] - r[S.sub.n-1] (2)
where [F.sub.n] is the logarithmic value of the FEER in year n,
[S.sub.n] is the logarithm of the actual exchange rate in year n, and r
is the rate of interest.
Equation (2) implies that
[F.sub.n-1] = (1 + r)[F.sub.n-2] - r[s.sub.n-2] (3)
[F.sub.n-2] = (1 + r)[F.sub.n-3] - r[s.sub.n-3] (4)
Recursive substitution (of (4) and (3) into (2) etc.,) yields
[F.sub.n] = [(1+r).sup.n][F.sub.0] - r [summation of]
[(1+r).sup.i-1][S.sub.n-i] where i = 1 to n (5)
Equation (5) shows how the initial stationary trajectory for F,
[F.sub.0], will require updating in the light of the evolution of the
actual real exchange rate. Thus, the FEER is not independent of the
history of exchange-rate movements. In particular, if the authorities
wished to move the current exchange rate to the FEER, at the end of n
periods, they would need to choose a path for the real exchange rate
([S.sub.1], [S.sub.2] ... [S.sub.n]) such that [S.sub.n] = [F.sub.n]
with [F.sub.n] as defined in (5). Thus, given a deviation of the actual
rate from the FEER and a desire ultimately to equate the two, the FEER
arrived at when the actual rate again coincides with it will not be
independent of the path taken by the exchange rate towards this goal.
Indeed, as equation (1) makes clear, if S deviates from F, F will
actually move away from S at speed r per period. Intuitively, therefore,
we should expect eventual convergence of F and S to require a movement
of S towards F at a speed greater than r in the following period. In
Artis and Taylor (1995), we demonstrate that this intuition turns out to
be correct when we analyse the dynamics of adjustment more formally.(11)
Assessing the importance of hysteresis effects: rules of thumb
In Artis and Taylor (1995), we examine how important hysteresis
effects may have been in the past by performing some illustrative
exercises with respect to actual exchange rates over the period 1979-90.
Overall, the results of this exercise demonstrate that hysteresis
effects on the FEER, operating through the effects of debt accumulation
or decumulation, may have been significant historically, particularly
for countries whose real exchange rate has moved predominantly in one
direction over a sustained period of time. For the US dollar during the
1980s, for example, we estimate that hysteresis effects of the kind
outlined above may have generated a deviation of the actual real
effective exchange rate from the FEER of as much as 14 per cent.
In this section, we seek to answer the following question: given an
initial misalignment of the exchange rate, and a desire to correct the
misalignment over a certain finite period, by how much does the required
movement in the exchange rate differ from the initial misalignment? For
example, suppose that the exchange rate is undervalued according to its
value relative to the FEER, and that it is desired to correct this over
a period of, say, five years. Assuming that the desired adjustment is
monotonic (e.g., a constant percentage annual appreciation), then, by
our arguments, the FEER at the end of the fifth year, when the
misalignment is zero, will be higher than the initial calculated FEER.
Thus, the total required movement in the exchange rate will be greater
than the initial difference between the exchange rate and the FEER. The
additional movement in the exchange rate over the five-year period (over
the initial misalignment measure) is thus, in some sense, a measure of
the importance of hysteresis effects arising during misalignment.
If the rate of capacity utilisation is held constant at 100 per cent,
then the overall movement in the FEER will be equal to the cumulative
misalignment each period multiplied by the interest rate.
Tables 1 and 2 give some illustrative examples of movements in the
FEER, assuming an interest rate of 5 per cent, initial undervaluation or
overvaluation of 10 or 20 per cent, and a constant annual percentage
change in the exchange rate. These trajectories are essentially found by
fine-tuning the annual percentage change in the exchange rate to find
[S.sub.n] = [F.sub.n] (n = 5, 10) with [F.sub.n] as given in (5), for
given [F.sub.0] and [S.sub.0].(12)
Consider first the results assuming five-year convergence (Table 1).
These show that the effect of a changing net asset stock (due to
misalignment) is to increase the total amount of required exchange-rate
adjustment by some 1.5 percentage points for an initial 10 per cent
misalignment, and by about 3 percentage points for an [TABULAR DATA FOR
TABLE 1 OMITTED] initial 20 per cent misalignment. Note that the
revision due to debt accumulation or decumulation is greater in the case
of undervaluation, since the initial exchange rate on which the
percentage is calculated is at a depressed level.
If the desired period of convergence is increased to ten years (Table
2), then the revisions increase to approximately 3 percentage points for
an initial 10 per cent misalignment, to some 5 percentage points for an
initial 20 per cent overvaluation and to a sizeable 7 percentage points
for an initial 20 per cent undervaluation.
As a very rough rule of thumb, therefore, for economies operating
near full capacity utilisation, the results of this section suggest the
following: The initial measure of misalignment should be increased by
about 1.5 percentage points for each 10 per cent of misalignment if the
desired period of convergence is five years, and by some 3 percentage
points for each 10 per cent of misalignment if convergence over ten
years is desired. Thus, an initial misalignment of 15 per cent would
suggest a required [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE 2 OMITTED] exchange rate
movement of about 17 1/4 per cent over five years.
Adjusting FEER trajectories: how good are the rules of thumb?
Our final exercise involves investigating what adjustments should be
made to some actual FEER estimates, due to Williamson (1990), when a
certain convergence path is assumed and hysteresis effects are taken
into account. This allows an assessment of the rules of thumb derived in
the previous section.
Williamson (1990) presents a range of estimates of FEERs for the G7
countries in 1990.(13) To illustrate the effects of hysteresis, we
consider his base-case estimates obtained using the Global Econometric
Model (GEM) developed by the National Institute for Economic and Social
Research, since GEM appears to be Williamson's preferred model in
this context (1990, p. 70). These estimates (Williamson (1990, Tables
6-7)) suggest that, at the end of 1989, the US dollar was overvalued relative to the FEER by some 9 per cent, the yen was undervalued by 15
per cent, sterling was overvalued by 10 per cent, the franc was
overvalued by 8 per cent, and the D-mark was undervalued by about 18 per
cent.(14) These figures were applied to real exchange rates for the G5
in the fourth quarter of 1989 to obtain an estimate of the FEER in 1990
which could be compared with the average real exchange rate for that
year to gauge the initial degree of misalignment.(15) Given an initial
estimate of capacity utilisation in 1990, we then assume that, over a
five- or ten-year period, utilisation adjusts linearly to full capacity
and the exchange rate adjusts by a constant percentage annual change in
order to achieve convergence on the FEER at the end of the period.
Essentially, this involves setting the trajectory for capacity
utilisation exogenously, and fine-tuning the annual percentage change in
the real exchange rate so that [S.sub.n] = [F.sub.n] as defined in (5)
but with the exchange rate purged of changes due to movements in
capacity utilisation.(16)
In the previous exercises, we implicitly assumed a constant (full)
level of capacity utilisation. In turning to an analysis of actual real
exchange rates, albeit in a counterfactual exercise, we are however
obliged to take account of a feature of real world experience from which
we abstracted in the earlier sections. A glance at Figure 1, however,
serves as a reminder that deviations of actual exchange rates from FEER
values need not necessarily imply movement off the CA schedule. An
appreciation of the exchange rate and a simultaneous fall in
utilisation, for example, could imply that the economy has moved left
along the CA schedule, with no consequences for debt service or FEER
revision. When using historical data therefore it is necessary to purge movements in actual real exchange rates of that part which can be held
to reflect changes in utilisation. In essence, this involves estimating
the slope of the CA schedule. Empirically, one can use medium-term
elasticities derived from an econometric macro model to do this. In this
article, we employ elasticities derived from the IMF's
multi-country macroeconometric model, MULTIMOD (Masson, Symansky, and
Meredith (1990)).
A simple way of calculating the real exchange-rate changes due to
such movements is as follows. Given values for changes in the rate of
capacity utilisation, output elasticities yield the implied change in
the current account. The real exchange rate elasticities then yield the
change in the real exchange rate that would eliminate this. That is, if
[[Epsilon].sub.y] is the output elasticity of net imports and [Delta]u
the percentage change in utilisation, the corresponding real exchange
rate change, [Delta]S, can be found from
[[Epsilon].sub.y][Delta]u X = X([Mu] + [Tau]) [Delta]S (6)
[Delta]S = [[Epsilon].sub.y] [Delta]u/([Mu] + [Tau]) (7)
where [Mu] + [Tau] is the sum of import and export elasticities with
respect to the real exchange rate and X is the level of exports (or
imports).
The results are reported in Tables 3 and 4. They tend to confirm the
usefulness of the rules of thumb derived in the previous section. For
example, with an initial misalignment of 9.33 per cent, five-year
convergence on the FEER for the US dollar entails an extra 1.34
percentage point movement in the real exchange rate (over the initial
9.33 per cent), which corresponds closely to the '1.5 percentage
points per 10 per cent of misalignment corrected over five years'
rule. For convergence over ten years, an extra 2.5 percentage points of
adjustment in the dollar is required, compared to the '3 percentage
points per 10 per cent of misalignment corrected over ten years'
rule. Similar results are obtained for the remainder of the G5
countries.
Table 3. Hypothetical five-year FEER trajectories for the G5(a)
Year Exchange FEER Utilisation
rate rate
(a) United States
1990 62.53 56.69 100.29
1991 61.13 56.43 100.24
1992 59.77 56.21 100.18
1993 58.43 56.04 100.12
1994 57.13 55.92 100.06
1995 55.85 55.85 100.00
Initial misalignment = +9.33 per cent
Annual exchange rate movement = 2.23 per cent
Overall movement in the FEER = -1.48 per cent
Overall movement in the exchange rate = -10.68 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange
movement = 1.34 percentage points
(b) Japan
1990 115.00 141.11 100.96
1991 120.61 142.71 100.77
1992 126.50 144.00 100.58
1993 132.67 144.98 100.38
1994 139.15 145.63 100.19
1995 145.94 145.94 100.00
Initial misalignment = -22.70 per cent
Annual exchange rate movement = +4.88 per cent
Overall movement in the FEER = +3.43 per cent
Overall movement in the exchange rate = +26.91 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange
movement = 4.21 percentage points
(c) United Kingdom
1990 103.07 84.87 101.09
1991 98.57 84.12 100.87
1992 94.26 83.50 100.65
1993 90.15 83.00 100.43
1994 86.12 82.65 100.22
1995 82.44 82.44 100.00
Initial misalignment = +17.66 per cent
Annual exchange-rate movement = -4.37 per cent
Overall movement in the FEER = -2.86 per cent
Overall movement in the exchange rate = -20.01 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange
movement = 2.35 percentage points
(d) France
1990 96.72 86.30 101.16
1991 94.20 85.83 100.93
1992 91.75 85.44 100.70
1993 89.37 85.13 100.46
1994 87.04 84.91 100.23
1995 84.78 84.78 100.00
Initial misalignment = +10.78 per cent
Annual exchange-rate movement = -2.60 per cent
Overall movement in the FEER = -1.76 per cent
Overall movement in the exchange rate = -12.35 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange
movement = 1.57 percentage points
(e) Germany
1990 122.96 145.49 101.24
1991 127.86 146.83 100.99
1992 132.96 147.91 100.74
1993 138.26 148.72 100.50
1994 143.77 149.25 100.25
1995 149.50 149.50 100.00
Initial misalignment = -18.33 per cent
Annual exchange-rate movement = +3.99 per cent
Overall movement in the FEER = +2.76 per cent
Overall movement in the exchange rate = +21.59 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange
movement = 3.26 percentage points.
Notes:
(a) We assume an interest rate of 5 per cent per annum.
Conclusion
The efficient conduct of policy on matters relating to the
international monetary system requires some basis for the evaluation of
market-determined exchange rates. One such basis can be found in the
concept of the fundamental equilibrium exchange rate (FEER) to which
Williamson has appealed in his advocacy of exchange-rate target zones.
The fundamental rate appeals to the notion that in the medium term it is
desirable to obtain both internal balance and external balance. The FEER
is simply that rate of exchange which fulfills this condition. It is
reasonably straightforward, given estimates of the relevant
elasticities, to compute values for the fundamental rate on
'medium-term' assumptions, that is to say, ignoring the
dynamics of adjustment.
However, it appears that the true value of the FEER must depend on
the path taken towards it. The reason is that, while the actual exchange
rate deviates from its FEER value, so in general will the current
account realisations deviate from those implicit in the initial
calculation of the FEER trajectory. For this reason debt service
obligations will differ from those assumed in the initial computation of
the trajectory. The FEER will change and a recomputation is called for.
The FEER is thus not independent of the path taken towards it, and
suffers from hysteresis.
In this article we were able to show that this problem could be
formalised in a fairly straightforward manner, enabling us to obtain a
formal representation of the hysteresis effect on the FEER. As an
indication of the potential importance of such effects in actual
practice, we also derived rules of thumb for the updating of the FEER
for a given degree of initial misalignment and for particular horizons
and monotonic adjustment of the actual real exchange rate towards the
FEER. Finally, we calculated by how much FEERs would change if values
calculated in 1990 by Williamson were achieved by 1995 or by the year
2000. The results, which took account of the need to adjust capacity
utilisation levels at the same time, largely confirm the rules of thumb
suggested in the earlier exercise; just as important, the revisions
emerged as significant in size when compared with the initial degree of
misalignment.
Table 4. Hypothetical ten-year FEER trajectories for the G5(a)
Year Exchange FEER Utilisation
rate rate
(a) United States
1990 62.53 56.69 100.29
1991 61.74 56.43 100.26
1992 60.97 56.18 100.24
1993 60.20 55.96 100.21
1994 59.45 55.76 100.18
1995 58.70 55.59 100.15
1996 57.96 55.44 100.12
1997 57.23 55.31 100.09
1998 56.52 55.21 100.06
1999 55.81 55.14 100.03
2000 55.10 55.10 100.00
Initial misalignment = +9.33 per cent
Annual exchange rate movement = -1.26 per cent
Overall movement in FEER = -2.80 per cent
Overall movement in exchange rate = -11.88 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange rate
movement = 2.5 percentage points
(b) Japan
1990 115.00 141.11 100.96
1991 118.13 142.71 100.86
1992 121.35 144.19 100.77
1993 124.66 145.53 100.67
1994 128.06 146.74 100.58
1995 131.55 147.79 100.48
1996 135.13 148.68 100.38
1997 138.81 149.40 100.29
1998 142.60 149.95 100.19
1999 146.48 250.30 100.10
2000 150.47 150.47 100.00
Initial misalignment = -22.70 per cent
Annual exchange rate movement = +2.73 per cent
Overall movement in FEER = +6.64 per cent
Overall movement in exchange rate = +30.85 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange rate
movement = 8.15 percentage points
(c) United Kingdom
1990 103.07 84.87 101.09
1991 100.53 84.12 100.98
1992 98.05 83.43 100.87
1993 95.63 82.80 100.76
1994 93.27 82.24 100.65
1995 90.97 81.73 100.54
1996 88.73 81.30 100.43
1997 86.54 80.93 100.33
1998 84.40 80.64 100.22
1999 82.32 80.43 100.11
2000 80.29 80.29 100.00
Initial misalignment = +17.66 per cent
Annual exchange rate movement = -2.47 per cent
Overall movement in FEER = -5.39 per cent
Overall movement in exchange rate = -22.10 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange rate
movement = 4.44 percentage points
(d) France
1990 96.72 86.30 101.16
1991 95.30 85.83 101.04
1992 93.30 85.40 100.93
1993 92.52 85.01 100.81
1994 91.16 84.65 100.70
1995 89.82 84.34 100.58
1996 88.50 84.06 100.46
1997 87.20 83.83 100.35
1998 85.91 83.64 100.23
1999 84.65 83.50 100.12
2000 83.41 83.41 100.00
Initial misalignment = +10.78 per cent
Annual exchange rate movement = -1.47 per cent
Overall movement in FEER = -3.35 per cent
Overall movement in exchange rate = -13.76 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange rate
movement = 2.98 percentage points
(e) Germany
1990 122.96 145.49 101.24
1991 125.70 146.83 101.12
1992 128.49 148.06 100.99
1993 131.35 149.17 100.87
1994 134.27 150.17 100.74
1995 137.26 151.04 100.62
1996 140.31 151.77 100.50
1997 143.44 152.37 100.37
1998 146.63 152.81 100.25
1999 149.89 153.10 100.12
2000 153.22 153.22 100.00
Initial misalignment = -18.33 per cent
Annual exchange rate movement = +2.22 per cent
Overall movement in FEER = +5.31 per cent
Overall movement in exchange rate = +24.61 per cent
Difference between initial misalignment and overall exchange rate
movement = 6.29 percentage points
Notes:
(a) We assume an interest rate of 5 per cent per annum.
NOTES
(1) See Taylor (1995) for a recent survey relating, inter alia, to
the first two of these approaches. Frenkel and Goldstein (1986) discuss
the relative merits of the three approaches.
(2) See also Nurske (1945) and International Monetary Fund (1970) for
precursors of this approach.
(3) The locus classicus on the method of comparative statics is
Samuelson (1947). Cuthbertson and Taylor (1987, chapter 1) provide a
textbook discussion.
(4) Note that we specifically do not address hysteresis effects that
might arise in other ways, e.g., through shifts in the NAIRU or on
account of the presence of set-up costs in international trade.
(5) Although we follow standard practice in predicating the FEER on
an assumed desired current account flow, a referee has pointed out that
a more appropriate underlying target may be total or net external
wealth. On this view, what follows, in essence, assumes hysteresis in
implied wealth targets in the face of shocks.
(6) In some computations, a desired value of the fiscal deficit is
also involved, but the assumption here is that there is no additional
effect of fiscal policy to be allowed for on top of its effect on u -
i.e., that changes in fiscal policy will not shift the schedules. To a
good first approximation, this seems a reasonable assumption.
(7) Throughout this article, for analytical simplicity, we ignore
j-curve effects.
(8) To some extent, this problem may be mitigated by adjustment of
the market adjustment rate towards the equilibrium level brought about
by the effects on domestic absorption of changes in net foreign asset
holdings - see Masson, Kremers and Horne (1994).
(9) It might be objected that the short-run elasticities differ from
the medium-run elasticities used in constructing the FEER. A further
adjustment could be made for any such differences.
(10) It may be worthwhile noting in this connection that market
exchange rate instability may ensue when a country becomes a net foreign
debtor - see Masson (1981) and Buiter (1984).
(11) In particular, we derive the full set of dynamic solutions to
the problem when the real exchange rate adjusts by a proportion of its
deviation from the FEER, and derive restrictions on the partial
adjustment process which are necessary in order to ensure eventual
conergence on the FEER.
(12) In fact, the precise calculations were slightly different
because we used percentage differences rather than logarithmic
differences, as in equation (1). A spread sheet program was used to
perform the calculations.
(13) More exactly, end-1989.
(14) These estimates are used for purely illustrative purposes. They
are not endorsed either by the present authors or by the International
Monetary Fund.
(15) Real exchange rate data were taken from the IFS data tape.
(16) Again, the actual computations were slightly more complex since
actual percentage changes, rather than log-linear approximations, were
used.
REFERENCES
Artis, M.J., and M.P. Taylor, (1995), 'The effect of
misalignment on desired equilibrium exchange rates: some analytical and
applied results,' in C. Bordes, E. Girardin and J. Melitz (eds),
European Currency Crisis and After, Manchester University Press.
Baldwin, R., and P. Krugman, (1986) 'Persistent trade effects of
large exchange rate shocks', Working Paper no. 2167, National
Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass.
Barrell, R., and S. Wren-Lewis, (1989), 'Equilibrium exchange
rates for the G7', Discussion Paper no. 323, Centre for Economic
Policy Research, London.
Buiter, W.H., (1984), 'Exchange rate policy after a decade of
'floating': comment', in J.F.O. Bilson and R.C. Marston
(eds) Exchange Rate Theory and Practice, pp. 108-12, University of
Chicago Press.
Cross, R., (1992), 'On the foundations of hysteresis in economic
systems', International Centre for Macroeconomic Modelling,
University of Strathclyde, Discussion Paper no. 4.
Currie, D., and S. Wren-Lewis, (1989), 'Evaluating blueprints
for the conduct of international macropolicy', American Economic
Review, vol. 79, pp. 264-69.
Cuthbertson, K., and M.P. Taylor, (1987), Macroeconomic Systems,
Blackwell, Oxford.
Frenkel, J.A., and M. Goldstein, (1986), 'A guide to target
zones', International Monetary Fund, Staff Papers, vol. 33, pp.
633-73.
International Monetary Fund, (1970), The Role of Exchange Rates in
the Adjustment of International Payments: A Report by the Executive
Directors.
International Monetary Fund, (1984), 'Issues in the assessment
of the exchange rates of industrial countries', Occasional Paper
no. 29.
King, R., and S. Rebelo, (1989), 'Low-frequency filtering and
real business cycles', Working Paper no. 205, Rochester Center for
Economic Research.
Layard, R., and S. Nickell, (1985), 'The causes of British
unemployment', National Institute Economic Review, no. 111, pp.
62-85.
Lindbeck, A., and D. Snower, (1986), 'Wage setting, unemployment
and insider-outsider relations', American Economic Review, vol. 76
(1986), pp. 235-39.
Masson, P.R., (19??), 'Dynamic stability of portfolio balance
models of the exchange rate', Journal of International Economics,
vol. 11 pp. 467-77.
Masson, P.R., J. Kremers and J. Horne, (19??), 'Net foreign
assets and international adjustment: The United States, Japan and
Germany', Journal of International Money and Finance, vol. 13, pp.
27-40.
Masson, P.R., S. Symansky, and G. Meredith, (1990), 'MULTIMOD
Mark II: A revised and extended model', International Monetary
Fund, Occasional Paper no. 71.
Nurske, R., (1945), 'Conditions of international monetary
equilibrium', Essays in International Finance, no. 4, Princeton
University Press.
Prescott, E.C., (1986), 'Theory ahead of business cycle
measurement', Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review,
Fall, pp. 9-22.
Samuelson, P.A., (1947), Foundations of Economic Analysis, Cambridge,
Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.
Taylor, M.P. (1995), 'The economics of exchange rates',
Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 33, pp. 13-47.
Taylor, M.P., and H.L. Allen, (1992), 'The use of technical
analysis in the foreign exchange market', Journal of International
Money and Finance, vol. 11, pp. 304-14.
Williamson, J., (1985), 'The exchange rate system',
Institute for International Economics, Washington.
Williamson, J., (1990), 'Equilibrium exchange rates: an
update', mimeo, Institute for International Economics, Washington.
Williamson, J., and M. Miller, (1987), 'Target zones and
indicators: a blueprint for the international coordination of economic
policy', Institute for International Economics, Washington.
Wren-Lewis, S., P. Westaway, S. Soteri, and R. Barrell, (1991),
'Evaluating the United Kingdom's choice of entry rate into the
ERM', Manchester School, vol. 59, Supplement (1991), pp. 1-22.